Skip to main content

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Economics ((BRIEFSECONOMICS))

  • 706 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter addresses the issue of money essentiality using Brock’s (1975) model. We present an argument which casts doubt on the conclusion reached by Obstfeld and Rogoff (1983), henceforth called O–R, based on the same theoretical framework. According to O–R, speculative hyperinflation—under a pure fiat money regime—can be ruled out only when severe restrictions are placed on individual preferences, e.g., agents must have infinitely negative utility when their real balances are zero. We argue that this restriction can be tested with data from hyperinflation experiments by looking at the behavior of the inflation tax, as real balances approach zero.

(With Alexandre B. Cunha)

Originally published in Economics Letters vol 78 (2003), pp. 187–195.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 59.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This point was made before (see Scheinkman 1980, p. 96 and Brock 1978) but it has been overlooked in the literature. For example, Ljungqvist and Sargent (2000) present an up-to-date discussion of inflation tax revenue in monetary models. However, they do not address the issue of money essentiality and its implication for the inflation tax revenue and speculative hyperinflation steady state equilibrium.

  2. 2.

    Appendix provides sufficient conditions on v(m) for the limit mv′(m) to remain bounded away from zero as m approaches zero from right.

  3. 3.

    Several textbooks (Blanchard and Fischer 1989; Obstfeld and Rogoff 1996; Walsh 1998) have presented wrong arguments for this case. For example, Walsh (1998, p. 59), states that: ‘When lim m → 0 A(m) < 0, paths originating to the left of m converge to m < 0; but this result is clearly not possible, since real balances cannot be negative’. A similar statement can be found in Gray (1984, p. 100).

  4. 4.

    For a survey of currency substitution in developing countries, as well as the difference between currency and asset substitution, see Calvo and Végh (1996).

  5. 5.

    It is interesting to note that when the elasticity of substitution is less than or equal to one, the domestic currency inflation tax Laffer curve yields less revenue than otherwise.

References

  • Bartle, R. (1976). The elements of real analysis (2nd ed). New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A. (1975). A simple perfect foresight monetary model. Journal of Monetary Economics, 1, 133–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brock, W. A. (1978). A note on hyper-inflationary equilibria in long run perfect foresight monetary models: A correction. Manuscript.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cagan, P. (1956). The monetary dynamics of hyperinflation. In M. Friedman (Ed.), Studies in quantity theory of money. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Calvo, G., & Végh, C. (1996). From currency substitution and beyond. In G. Calvo (Ed.), Analytical and policy issues. money, exchange rates, and output. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gray, J. A. (1984). Dynamic instability in rational expectations models: An attempt to clarify. International Economic Review, 25, 93–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ljungqvist, L., & Sargent, T. (2000). Recursive macroeconomic theory. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1983). Speculative hyperinflations in maximizing models: Can we rule them out? Journal of Political Economy, 91, 675–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld, M., & Rogoff, K. (1996). Foundations of international macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scheinkman, J. (1980). Discussion. In J. Kareken, & N. Wallace (Eds.), Models of monetary economics. Minneapolis: Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C. E. (1998). Monetary theory and policy. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

Consider the following statements:

  1. A:

    υ displays ‘high’ degree of risk aversion on a neighborhood of zero:

    $$\displaystyle{\exists \epsilon > 0: \left [m \in \left (0,\epsilon \right ) \Rightarrow \frac{-m\upsilon ''(m)} {\upsilon '(m)} \geq 1\right ]}$$
  2. B:

    The limit \(\lim _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon '(m)\) exists: \(\lim \inf _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon 'm =\lim \sup _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon '(m)\)

  3. C:

    Money is always valued: \(\lim \inf _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon '(m) > 0\)

  4. D;

    Inada condition: \(\lim _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}\upsilon '(m) = \infty \)

Proposition 1.

condition A implies conditions B, C and D.

Proof.

Concerning [A ⇒ B], it is enough to show that [−B ⇒ −A]. so, assume that there are two numbers l and L satisfying

$$\displaystyle{ -\infty \leq l =\lim \inf _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}f(m) <\lim \sup _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}f(m) = L \leq \infty }$$
(5.21)

where we use the notation: f(m) = ′(m).

Let ε be any positive number. It must be shown that there exists some positive number \(\bar{m} <\epsilon\) such that \(-\bar{m}\upsilon ''(\bar{m})/\upsilon '(\bar{m}) < 1\). From (5.21), there exist two sequences {x n } n = 1 and {y n } n = 1 of positive numbers that satisfy x n  → 0, y n  → 0, f(x n ) → l and f(y n ) → L. By taking N and K large enough, we can find numbers x N+K and y N with the properties

$$\displaystyle{ 0 < x_{N+K} < y_{N} < \epsilon \ \mbox{ and}\ f\left (x_{N+K}\right ) < f\left (y_{N}\right ) }$$
(5.22)

From the Mean Value Theorem Bartle (1976, p. 196), there exists a number \(\bar{m} \in (x_{N+K},y_{N})\) satisfying

$$\displaystyle{f'(\bar{m}) = \frac{f\left (y_{N}\right ) - f\left (x_{N+K}\right )} {y_{N} - x_{N+K}} \Rightarrow f'(\bar{m}) > 0}$$

But

$$\displaystyle{f'(\bar{m}) > 0 \Rightarrow \bar{ m}\upsilon ''(\bar{m}) +\upsilon '(\bar{m}) > 0 \rightarrow 1 > \frac{-\bar{m}\upsilon ''(\bar{m})} {\upsilon '(\bar{m})},}$$

as required. To prove that [A ⇒ C] is true, observe that condition A implies that f is a non-increasing function on (0, ε]. Hence, if m belongs to (0, ε], then ′(m) ≥ ε υ′(ε) > 0. Thus, \(\lim \inf _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon '(m) \geq \epsilon \upsilon '(\epsilon ) > 0\). Finally, since A implies both B and C, A also implies that \(\lim _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon '(m) > 0\). Hence, as m approaches zero from the right.

It should be pointed out that neither B, C or D implies A. Consider the function υ(m) = m 0. 5. It satisfies both B and D but it does not satisfy A. Thus, both statements [B ⇒ A] and [D ⇒ A] are false. To show that C does not imply A a more sophisticated example is required. Define υ according to

$$\displaystyle{ \upsilon (m) = \left \{\begin{array}{c} -\int _{m}^{0.5} \frac{1} {x}e^{x}dx\ \mbox{ if}\ m \leq 0.5 \\ \int _{0.5}^{m}2e^{1-x}dx\ \mbox{ if}\ m > 0.5 \end{array} \right. }$$
(5.23)

Note that υ is increasing, strictly concave and twice continuously differentiable. For m ≤ 0. 5, ′(m) = e m. Thus, \(\lim \inf _{m\rightarrow 0^{+}}m\upsilon (m) = 1 > 0\). So, the function defined in (5.23) satisfies C. For all m < 0. 5, −″(m)∕υ′(m) = 1 − m < 1. Therefore, this utility function does not satisfy A. It should be emphasized that the υ defined in (5.23) also satisfies conditions B and D.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Barbosa, F.d. (2017). Inflation Tax and Money Essentiality. In: Exploring the Mechanics of Chronic Inflation and Hyperinflation. SpringerBriefs in Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-44512-0_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics