Advertisement

Revolutionising Economic and Democratic Systems

  • Kenneth Nordberg
Chapter
  • 290 Downloads
Part of the Palgrave Studies in Democracy, Innovation, and Entrepreneurship for Growth book series (DIG)

Abstract

Over the last three decades, two major waves of reform have established a system of governance popularly labelled the New Governance. This concept refers to one of the megatrends in industrial societies, the shift from government to governance. Generally, this shift entails a relaxation of the authority of the bureaucratic and hierarchic nation-state for the benefit of “the creation of a structure or an order which cannot be externally imposed but is the result of the interaction of a multiplicity of governing and each other influencing actors” (Stoker 1998: 17). The first wave emerged in the 1980s, when neoliberalism and rational economic theories were introduced in public service through the concept of New Public Management (NPM). The second wave of reform was largely a response to the first wave, whereby system and network theorists tried to make sense of the network society that had emerged. Both politicians and the government saw a tool in these theories for managing and steering the plurality of institutions and networks that were involved in public management following NPM (see e.g. Bevir 2010: 12). In other words, the first wave aimed at achieving efficiency, while the second wave sought improved steering. Consequently, the shift from government to governance has brought about a room for manoeuvre at the local level, i.e. bottom-up processes, that was not present earlier, at the same time as new kinds of steering processes restrict actions in ways that are difficult to interpret or predict in advance. In what ways is this new concept of governance influencing, for instance, democracy, legitimacy and efficiency? The assumption for this chapter is that New Governance and governance networks have been constructed as a consequence of changes in both the economic and political systems, and that New Governance accordingly has become the centrepiece of economic and democratic theory development. As mentioned, benefits for both democracy and economy of increased bottom-up processes are found in the academic literature, and when combined, suggest that an increased room for manoeuvre for these kinds of processes may offer both economic and democratic gains. Let us now take a look at these theories.

Keywords

European Union Liberal Democracy Rational Choice Theory Representative Democracy Party Democracy 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. Adcock, R., Bevir, M., & Stimson, S. C. (2007). Historicizing the new institutionalism(s). In R. Adcock, M. Bevir, & S. C. Stimson (Eds.), Modern political science: Anglo-American exchanges since 1880. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Amin, A., & Thrift, N. (1994). Living in the global. In A. Amin & N. Thrift (Eds.), Globalisation, institutions and regional development in Europe. Oxford/New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  3. Amin, A., & Thrift, N. (1995). Globalisation, institutional “thickness” and the local economy. In P. Healey, S. Cameron, S. Davoudi, S. Graham, & A. Madani-Pour (Eds.), Managing cities – The new urban context. Newcastle upon Tyne: University of Newcastle upon Tyne.Google Scholar
  4. Asheim, B. T. (1996). Industrial districts as “learning regions”: A con dition for prosperity? European Planning Studies, 4,4, 379-400.Google Scholar
  5. Asheim, B. (2001). Learning regions as development coalitions: Partnership as governance in European workfare states? Concepts and Transformation: International Journal of Action Research and Organizational Renewal, 6, 73–101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Asheim, B., Boschma, R., & Cooke, P. (2011a). Constructing regional advantage: Platform policies based on related variety and differentiated knowledge bases. Regional Studies Special Issue: Regional Innovation Systems: Theory, Empirics and Policy, 45(7).Google Scholar
  7. Asheim, B., Moodysson, J., & Tödtling, F. (2011b). Constructing regional advantage: Towards state-of-the-art regional innovation system policies in Europe? European Planning Studies 19(7).Google Scholar
  8. Becattini, G. (1990): The Marshallian industrial district as a socio-economic notion. In F. Pyke et al. (eds): Industrial districts and inter-firm co-operationin Italy. International Institute for labour studies, Geneva, 37-51.Google Scholar
  9. Beck, U., Giddens, A., & Lash, S. (1994). Reflexive modernization. Politics, tradition and aesthetics in the modern social order. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  10. Bevir, M. (2010). Democratic governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Brusco, S. (1990): The idea of the industrial district: Its genesis. In F. Pyke et al. (eds): Industrial districts and interfirm co-operation in Italy. International Institute for Labour Stu dies, Geneva, 10-19.Google Scholar
  12. Camagni, R. (1991) Introduction: from the local ‘milieu’ to innovation through cooperation networks, in R. Camagni (Ed.) Innovation Mtworks: Spatial Perspectives, pp. 1-9. London: Belhaven Press.Google Scholar
  13. Callahan, J., & Lasry, E. (2004). The importance of customer input in the development of very new products. R&D Management, 34(2), 107–120. Blackwell Publishing Ltd.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  14. Carayannis, Elias G., David F. J. Campbell (2006), “Mode 3“: Meaning and Implications from a Knowledge Systems Perspective, 1–25, in: Elias G. Carayannis, David F. J. Campbell (eds.): Knowledge Creation, Diffusion, and Use in Innovation Networks and Knowledge Clusters. A Comparative Systems Approach across the United States, Europe and Asia. Westport, Connecticut: Praeger.Google Scholar
  15. Carayannis, Elias G., David F. J. Campbell (2009), “Mode 3” and “Quadruple Helix”: Toward a 21st Century Fractal Innovation Ecosystem. International Journal of Technology Management 46 (3/4), 201–234.Google Scholar
  16. Carayannis, Elias G., David F. J. Campbell (2012), Mode 3 Knowledge Production in Quadruple Helix Innovation Systems. Twenty-first-Century Democracy, Innovation, and Entrepreneurship for Development. SpringerBriefs in Business 2012, VI, 63 p. 13 illus.Google Scholar
  17. Cord, D. J. (2014). The decline and fall of Nokia. Helsinki: Schildts & Söderströms.Google Scholar
  18. Crouch, C. (2011 [2005]). Post-democracy, Gius, Laterza, Rome, Swedish Edition in 2011: Postdemokrati, Bokförlaget Daidalos AB, Göteborg.Google Scholar
  19. Damgaard, B., & Torfing, J. (2011). The impact of meta-governance on local governance networks: Lessons from Danish employment policy. Local Government Studies, 37, 291–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. de Beus, J. (2011). Audience democracy: An emerging pattern in postmodern political communication. In K. Brants & K. Voltmer (Eds.), Political communication in postmodern democracy. Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  21. Dryzek, J. S. (2000). Deliberative democracy and beyond. Liberals, critics, contestations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  22. Etzioni-Halevy, Eva. (1993). The elite connection: Problems and Potentials of Western democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  23. Florida, R. (1995). Toward the learning region. Futures, 27(5), 527–536.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Florida, R. (2002). The rise of the creative class: And how it’s transforming work, leisure, community, and everyday life. Cambridge, MA: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  25. Freeman, C., & Louca, F. (2001). As time goes by: From the industrial revolutions to the information revolution. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  26. Frenken Koen, van Oort Frank, Verburg Thijs (2007). Related Variety, Unrelated Variety and Regional Economic Growth, Regional Studies, Vol. 41.5, pp. 685–697.Google Scholar
  27. Fung, A., & Wright, E. O. (Eds.). (2003). Deepening democracy. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  28. Goggin Gerard (2009). Adapting the mobile phone: The iPhone and its consumption, Continuum: Journal of Media & Cultural Studies, 23:2, 231-244.Google Scholar
  29. Johnson Björn, Lorenz Edward and Lundvall Bengt-Åke (2002). Why all this fuss about codified and tacit knowledge? Industrial and Corporate Change, Volume 11, Number 2, pp. 245–262.Google Scholar
  30. Habermas, J. (1984). Theory of communicative action (Reason and the rationalization of society, Vol. 1). Cambridge: Beacon Press.Google Scholar
  31. Halkier, H. (2012, November). Knowledge dynamics and policies for regional development: towards a new governance paradigm. European Planning Studies, 20(11).Google Scholar
  32. Halkier, H., James, L., Dahlström, M., & Manniche, J. (2012, November). Knowledge dynamics, regions and public policy. European Planning Studies, 20(11).Google Scholar
  33. Hassink, R. (1998). The paradox of interregional institutional learning. Seoul: Science and Technology Policy Institute.Google Scholar
  34. Heywood Andrew (2013). Politics (fourth edition). Hampshire: Palgrave McMillan.Google Scholar
  35. Hirsch. (1991). From the Fordist to the post-Fordist state. In B. Jessop, H. Kastendiek, K. Nielsen, & O. K. Pedersen (Eds.), The politics of flexibility. Aldershot: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.Google Scholar
  36. Hirst, P. (1994). Associative democracy: New forms of economic and social governance. Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  37. Hirst, P. (2000). Globalisering, Demokrati og det civile samfund. Copenhagen: Hans Reitzel Publishers.Google Scholar
  38. Hood, C., James, O., & Scott, C. (2000). Regulation of government: Has it increased, is it increasing, should it be diminishes? Public Administration, 78, 283–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Hudson, R. (1999). The learning economy, the learning firm and the learning region: A sympathetic critique of the limits to learning. European Urban and Regional Studies, 6(1), 59–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Jensen, M. B., Johnson, B., Lorenz, E., & Lundvall, B.-Å. (2007). Forms of knowledge and modes of innovation. Research Policy, 36, 680–693.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Jessop, B. (1991). The welfare state in the transition from Fordism to post-Fordism. In B. Jessop, H. Kastendiek, K. Nielsen, & K. O. Pedersen (Eds.), The politics of flexibility. Aldershot: Edward Elgar Publishing Limited.Google Scholar
  42. Jessop, B. (1993). Towards a Schumpeterian workfare state – Preliminary remarks on post-Fordist political economy. Studies in Political Economy, Vol. 40: Post-Fordist States and Regional Blocs.Google Scholar
  43. Jessop, B. (1994). Post-Fordism and the state. In A. Amin (Ed.), Post-Fordism. A reader (pp. 251–279). Oxford: Blackwell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Jessop, B. (1997). Capitalism and its future: Remarks on regulation, government and governance. Review of International Political Economy, 4(3).Google Scholar
  45. Kahila, P., Lakso, T., & Suutari, T. (2006). The role of policy and governance in European peripheral regions. Seinäjoki: Ruralia Institute, University of Helsinki.Google Scholar
  46. Kondriatev, N. (1926). About the question of the major cycles of the conjuncture. Planovoe Khoziaistvo, 8, 167–181.Google Scholar
  47. Levi-Feur, D., & Jordana, J. (2005, March). The rise of regulatory capitalism: The global diffusion of a new order. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, Vol. 598. Thousand Oaks/London: SAGE Publications.Google Scholar
  48. Lundvall, B.-Å. (1996). The social dimension of the learning economy (DRUID Working Papers, No 96-1). Aalborg: Aalborg University.Google Scholar
  49. Madison, J. (1787-8). Federalist 10. The Federalist Papers.Google Scholar
  50. Malmberg, A., & Maskell, P. (2006). Localized learning revisited. Growth and Change, 37(1), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Manin, B. (2002). Den representativa demokratins principer. Stockholm: SNS Förlag.Google Scholar
  52. March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1989). Rediscovering institutions. The organizational basis of politics. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
  53. March, J. G., & Olsen, J. P. (1995). Democratic governance. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
  54. Mariussen, Å., & Virkkala, S. (2013). Learning transnational learning. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  55. Michels, Robert (2001). Political parties: a sociological study of the oligarchical tendencies of modern democracy, Ontario: Batoche Books.Google Scholar
  56. Mouffe, C. (2000). The democratic paradox. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  57. Mouffe, C. (2005). On the political. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  58. Mouffe, C. (2013). Agonism. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  59. Nalebuff, B., & Brandenburger, A. (1996). Co-opetition. New York: Doubleday/Currency.Google Scholar
  60. National Institute for Working Life. (1997). Stronger partnership for learning region. Stockholm.Google Scholar
  61. Nie, N. H., Verba, S., & Petrocik, J. R. (1979). The changing American voter. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  62. Nonaka, I., & Takeuchi, H. (1995). The knowledge-creating company: How Japanese companies create the dynamics of innovation. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  63. North, D. C. (1994). Economic performance through time. American Economic Review, 84(3), 359–368.Google Scholar
  64. Laugesen John, Yuan Yufei (2010). What factors contributed to the success of Apple’s iPhone? Working paper, 2010 Ninth International Conference on Mobile Business / 2010 Ninth Global Mobility Roundtable.Google Scholar
  65. Osborne, D., & Gaebler, T. (1992). Reinventing government: How the entrepreneurial spirit is transforming the public sector. Reading: Addison-Wesley.Google Scholar
  66. Perez, C. (1983). Structural change and the assimilation of new technologies in the economic and social system. Futures, 15, 357–375. (1985).Google Scholar
  67. Peters, G. (2010). Meta-governance and public management. In S. Osborne (Ed.), The new public governance? Emerging perspectives on the theory and practice of public governance. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  68. Phillips, Kevin (1975). Mediacracy: American Parties and Politics in the Communications AgeNew York: Doubleday & Company, inc.Google Scholar
  69. Pierre, J. (2000). Debating governance – Authority, steering and democracy. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  70. Porter, M. (1990): The competitive advantage of nations. Macmillan, London.Google Scholar
  71. Porter, M. E. (1998). Clusters and competition: New agendas for companies, governments, and institutions. In M. E. Porter (Ed.), On competition (pp. 197–287). Boston: Harvard Business School Press.Google Scholar
  72. Powell, W. W., & Snellman, K. (2004). The knowledge economy. Annual Review of Sociology, 30, 199–220. Published by: Annual Reviews.Google Scholar
  73. Rhodes, R. A. W. (1997). Understanding governance: Policy networks, governance, reflexivity and accountability (Public policy and management). Buckingham: Open University Press.Google Scholar
  74. Room, G. (2005). The European challenge: Innovation, policy learning, and social cohesion in the new knowledge economy. Bristol: Policy Press.Google Scholar
  75. Sandel, M. J. (1996). Democracy’s discontent: America in search of a public philosophy. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  76. Schumpeter, J. (1939). Business cycles: A theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  77. Sørensen, Eva & Torfing, Jakob (2005) Network Governance and Post-liberal Democracy, Administrative Theory & Praxis, 27 (2): 197–237.Google Scholar
  78. Sørensen, Eva (2006) Metagovernance: The Changing Role of Politicians in Processes of Democratic Governance, The American Review of Public Administration 2006 36: 98-114.Google Scholar
  79. Sørensen, Eva & Torfing, Jakob (2009) The Politics of Self-Governance of the Self and Others in Sørensen, Eva and Triantafillou Peter (Eds) The Politics of Self-Governance, Ashgate.Google Scholar
  80. Sørensen, E. (2012). Governance networks as a frame for inter-demoi participation and deliberation. Administrative Theory & Praxis, 34(4).Google Scholar
  81. Sørensen, E., & Torfing, J. (2007). Theories of democratic network governance. Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  82. Stoker, G. (1998). Public private partnerships and urban governance. In J. Pierre (Ed.), Partnerships in urban governance: European and American experience. London: McMillan.Google Scholar
  83. Tödtling, F., Asheim, B., & Boschma, R. (2013). Knowledge sourcing, innovation and constructing advantage in regions of Europe. European Urban and Regional Studies, 20, 161. Sage Publications.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Vigoda, E. (2002). From responsiveness to collaboration: Governance, citizens, and the next generation of public administration. Public Administration Review, 62, 527–540.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2017

Authors and Affiliations

  • Kenneth Nordberg
    • 1
  1. 1.Åbo Akademi UniversityVasaFinland

Personalised recommendations