Skip to main content

System of Accounts for Global Entropy-Production (SAGE-P): The Accounting in the Topological Domain Space (TDS) of the Econosphere, Sociosphere, and the Ecosphere

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Green Economy Reader

Part of the book series: Studies in Ecological Economics ((SEEC,volume 6))

Abstract

This chapter describes the accounts of the Econosphere, Sociosphere and Ecosphere governed by the Second Law of thermodynamics. Applied symmetries of ‘production’ (i.e., neg-entropy), ‘consumption’ (i.e., entropy) and capital accumulation (i.e., net-valued low entropy fund available for human consumption). These entropy production accounts permits holistic assessment of sustainability in the following state condition: (a) steady-state, (neg-entropy = entropy), (b) surplus-state, (neg-entropy > entropy) and (c) deficit-state (neg-entropy < entropy). Examined are the root of entropy accounting in the labour theory of values and the Ricardian (long-term) production equations of distribution of wages, profits and rent. This is contrasted to the neoclassical general equilibrium hypothesis of unlimited productivity per unit of consumption and where distributions are determined by state conditions of the supply and demand curve governed by consumer choice and/or preference functions. We introduce the equations of the entropic process described by G-R Flow-Fund Model whereby quantitative (material) production functions are transcribed into qualitative (immaterial) consumption functions, (i.e., enjoyment of Product). This powerful logic of entropy production as a limit function of Production, Consumption and Capital Accumulation, reinstates the Ricardian hypothesis of the longterm end result of Capitalism: Wages fall to subsistence, Profits fall to zero, and Rents rise to a maximum. The SAGE-P provides the accounts of entropy production essential for redirecting the trajectories of unsustainable growth, towards a sustainable economy reduced to maintaining the stock (i.e., wealth) of any well-defined Low Entropy Fund (LEF) available for human consumption, (see Fig. 6.4). The object of policy is thus redefined as the minimum socially acceptable rate of entropy production per unit of consumption. The Appendices provides a window on the formalism underpinning the accounting concepts of SAGE-P.

We have chosen the concept of Topological Domain Space (TDS) because of its generalisation of a mathematical object defined as any set of points that satisfy a set of postulates. These are postulates applied here are those expounded in the G-R Flow Fund Model, see Appendix I.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The products of the immaterial economy, (i.e., abstract objects like financial services), are not directly subject to the Entropy Law. Abstract objects are nonetheless agents, like investment decisions, for either increasing or decreasing the rate of entropy production in the system. Abstract objects acting on other abstract objects have no discernible rate of entropy production.

  2. 2.

    Intrinsic values are in principle infinite. For the purpose of accounting it seems more rationale to convert intrinsic to to human-calculated existential values. What is the value of existence of rare and endangered species? Or the cost of conservation of ecosystem functions? Existence-values converge into cultural values and may thus be considered as equivalences.

  3. 3.

    Public goods imply free access to the LEF but are frequently privileged to income, as in airports and/or national parks. Public goods also include military expenditure to protect the Nation, but are the locus of destruction of capital and wealth.

  4. 4.

    Centrally-planned economies Ke represents the public good, but like market economy, the access to economic LEF is privileged to apparatchiks who run the economy and the state.

  5. 5.

    Intrinsic values are either infinite or zero. While this may hold true for the individual, the society may express through culture, myth, memory etc., a value for objects and function unrelated to usefulness or economic gain. This value is best summed up as existential value which must be conserved for its own sake. There is no direct matrix for existential value, the society nonetheless expresses these values indirectly through allocation of funds, such as conservation of assets (i.e., low entropy fund), like establishment of a system of national parks, protection of historical monuments, museums etc., and through mass protests and politics. In the case of the latter wars have been fought to protect the Nation’s abstract values like integrity, honour and freedom.

  6. 6.

    NNP = solar energy captured by plants and other photosynthetic organism minus that used by the organisms themselves for respiration.

  7. 7.

    In the Fisher analysis, abstract objects in SAGE-P, like bank accounts, assume a material object of ‘concrete wealth’. What this really means is that wealth is an instrumental means to produce more wealth (i.e., capital) or an instrumental means to sustain or enjoy life (i.e., consumption). For this condition to hold, economic instruments must have attached property rights, which are owned either by an individual or a collective, such as a community. Note that in SAGE-P ‘property rights’ represent the higher order (abstract) institutional objects of the sociosphere.

  8. 8.

    Nonrenewable resources like fossil fuels and minerals are not circulating capital, other than recycling, and treated as appropriated in distributional relationship of the wage-profit cycle.

  9. 9.

    Theodore Roosevelt (1906) said: ‘We have become great because of the lavish use of our resources. But the time has come to inquire seriously what will happen when our forests are gone, when the coal, the iron, the oil, and the gas are exhausted, when the soils have still further impoverished and washed into the streams, polluting the rivers, denuding the fields and obstructing navigation.’

  10. 10.

    Georges Betaille’s philosophical concern is the logic that ‘surplus product’ must ultimately ‘destruct’. This led to the examination of the human experience with respect to the distribution (power) and destruction (choice) of the ‘economic surplus’. The annual flood of the Nile River aquatic ecosystem (i.e., a low entropy Fund) created the ‘surplus funds’ to construct the tombs of the Pharaohs – a useless object. In the more literal sense of destruction, the economic surplus provides the capacity for nation’s to wage wars or to build-up arms for the politically-motivated (imaginary) pseudo-wars, like the Cold-War.

  11. 11.

    Economists have often pointed to the contradiction between ‘annual labour’, a flow concept, and a ‘Fund’, a stock concept. This can be resolved by replacing the word ‘annual’ with the word ‘potential’. The labour force is thus a stock (a quantitative value) representing qualities of the potential work, in conjunction with nature, to supply the nation ‘…with all the necessaries and conveniences of life which it annually consumes.’

  12. 12.

    Primary production is the synthesis of organic compounds from atmospheric or aqueous carbon dioxide. It principally occurs through the process of photosynthesis, which uses light as its source of energy.

  13. 13.

    The quote is from M. Garnier who wrote a introductory essay entitled “A Short View of the Doctrine of Smith with that of the French Economists” included in the 1809 edition of “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations.”

  14. 14.

    We may regard the present state of the universe as the effect of its past and the cause of its future. An intellect which at a certain moment would know all forces that set nature in motion, and all positions of all items of which nature is composed, if this intellect were also vast enough to submit these data to analysis, it would embrace in a single formula the movements of the greatest bodies of the universe and those of the tiniest atom; for such an intellect nothing would be uncertain and the future just like the past would be present before its eyes. (translated from French), – Pierre Simon Laplace, A Philosophical Essay on Probabilities.

  15. 15.

    Von Böhm-Bawerk was a student of Karl Menger, who, along with Stanley Jevons and Leon Walrus, are considered the founders of the Neo-classical School.

  16. 16.

    For instance the 2008 financial meltdown may be viewed as lag effect of deregulation of the Banking sector in the 1980s and the subsequent explosion of financial products created by traders in the 1990s, like derivatives, hedge-funds, credit/default swaps etc. The secondary lag effect of the 2008 financial market are reverberating in the debt crises of sovereign States.

  17. 17.

    This means that abstract objects do not obey the superposition principle which states that, for all linear systems, the net response at a given place and time caused by two or more stimuli is the sum of the responses which would have been caused by each stimulus individually.

  18. 18.

    A ‘quantum’ is a quantity of something, a very specific amount. ‘Mechanics’ is a study of motion. Therefore, quantum mechanics is the study of motion in quantities. Quantum theory says that nature comes in bits and pieces (quanta), and quantum mechanics is the study of this phenomena (Zukav 1979, p. 45).

  19. 19.

    Fichtean/Hegelian Dialectics postulate that: (i) everything is transient and finite, existing in the medium of time; (ii) everything is made out of opposing forces/opposing sides (contradictions); (iii) gradual changes lead to turning points, where one force overcomes the other (quantitative change leads to qualitative change); and (iv) change moves in spirals (or helices), not circles (sometimes referred to as ‘negation of the negation’).

  20. 20.

    For instance administrative boundaries are abstract space and can be changed from one instant to the next by decree. Geographical space require that the boundary conditions be specified by observed differences in the qualities of the biome or in hydrological/geological formation, river basins, mountain ranges etc.

  21. 21.

    Alfred Marshall similarly rejected the notion of a general equilibrium system. While the individual markets may tend towards equilibrium, (i.e., supply = demand), the relationship among markets may tends towards disequilibrium states, like the world oil market, international trade, and any market with political interference, subsidies, rationing, currency, etc.

  22. 22.

    The Stern Report (2007) present-value discount of income flows, albeit at 2–3% of global GDP, in order to avoid an even greater loss of income in the future, is an example of the neoclassical arithomorphism applied to the wellbeing of future generation of unknowable values.

  23. 23.

    The non-market valuations drop out of the System of National Accounts, as these data are represented in the money-valued elements in the social and environmental accounts. Thus, the System of National Accounts is freed from imputations of equivalences between market and non-market objects.

  24. 24.

    Administrative boundaries can sometimes be clearly observed from air by observing the patterns of land-use. The US-Mexican border is observed sharply in contiguous urban and agricultural zones, but not in with the wild desert zone.

  25. 25.

    Entropy production functions in complex systems need not be identified in the strict sense of causal relationships, but rather in the weaker sense of probabilities. The precautionary principle is based on uncertainty, and the risk factor is merely a probability function assumed by a priori knowledge. See the discussion on Bayesian statistical methods.

  26. 26.

    In information theory, entropy is a measure of the uncertainty associated with a random variable. In this context, the term usually refers to Shannon entropy, which quantifies the expected value of the information contained in a message, usually in units such as bits. Equivalently, the Shannon entropy is a measure of the average information content one is missing when one does not know the value of the random variable. The concept was introduced by Claude E. Shannon in his 1948 paper, ‘A Mathematical Theory of Communication’.

  27. 27.

    These are state conditions where the object, while replenished, changes properties. In economic analysis, substitution assumes qualitative change of objects for equivalent values. In SAGE-P analysis, substitution reflects the human acceptance of inferior qualities of objects in the consumption function, because the superior quality object is unavailable or unaffordable.

  28. 28.

    That does not mean that the abstract objects do not have spatial identifiers, like the enjoyment of scenery in the Alps, or the enjoyment of the ballet in the Bolshoi Theatre in Moscow. The essential idea is that of mapping abstract objects on abstract objects, like financial flows and balances, or the mapping of abstract objects on physical objects, like prices on goods, but not services. Indeed, GDP may be viewed as a mapping of prices on all the (final) goods (physical objects) and services (abstract objects) produced in the economy in one year. It should be noted that the System of National Accounts is a method to reduce physical objects (material economy) and abstract objects (immaterial economy) into the single denominator of market prices. In other words, it is a method to reduce complex physical processes into a pure abstract value-object disconnected from the physical universe.

  29. 29.

    There is some ambiguity of what actually is being observed in statistical databases. Economic and social statistical databases are largely constructed from surveys, with pre-defined categories. Demographic data is a direct observation of the population and can be counted in numbers of people with specific time and location. Environmental data is perhaps the least ambiguous observation if taken from satellite imagery, the location and time of the data are exact. The data on spot checks and sampling of physical objects run into the same degree of uncertainty as those of socio-economic surveys.

  30. 30.

    This was clearly recognized by the UN Statistical Office by permitting the social value bias to enter the System of National Accounts. Here, the Marxist versus the capitalist bias entered the valuation of the ‘National Product.’ The latter valued the annual goods and services at ‘willingness-to-pay’ basis, or market prices, while the former valued at the cost of production of the material product – thus, assuming a labour theory of value. However, the UN Statistical maintained its own bias with respect to the non-monetised sector of the national economies and thus the ‘product’ of the household and the non-monetised ‘natural product’ was left out of the accounts. This can be corrected by a ‘service-flow’ income accounting.

  31. 31.

    Wikipedia entry on Bayesian Statistics.

References

  • Arrow K, Dasgupta P, Goulder I, Daily G, Ehrlich P, Heal G, Levin S, Maler K, Schneider S, Starrett D, Walker B (2004) Are we consuming too much? J Econ Perspect 18(3):147–172

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bataille G (1988) The accursed share: an essay on general economy, vol. I. Consumption (trans: from French by Hurley R). Zone Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Berlinski D (1999) The advent of the algorithm: the idea that rules the world. Harcourt, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Boulding K (1949) Income or wealth. Rev Econ Stud 17:77–86

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Daly H (1977) Steady-State economics. W.H. Freeman, San Francisco

    Google Scholar 

  • Daly H, Cobb J (1989) For the common good: redirecting the economy toward community, the environment, and a sustainable future. Beacon, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Ellul J (1964) The technological society, (trans: from French by Wilkinson J). Vintage Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1906) The nature of capital and income. Macmillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1965) ‘The nature of capital and income’, in Reprints of Economic Classics, Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend A (1993) Towards pluralism in national accounting systems. In: Franz A, Stahmer C (eds) Approaches to environmental accounting. Physica Verlag, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend A (2005) Unearthing ecoprices in conservation accounts. In: Sahu N, Choudary A (eds) Dimensions of environmental and ecological economics. Hyderabad University Press, Hyderabad

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend A (2009) The ergodic hypothesis and its relationship with the Clausius and the Blotzmann formulation of the Entropy Law: Discussion Paper I. unpublished manuscript

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend A, Friend M (2009) Non-linear accounting methods and adaptive logic: an exploration of the meta-language of the Georgescu-Roegen Flow-Fund Model. Paper presented at the European society for ecological economics conference, Ljubljana, Slovenia, 30 July-2 August 2009

    Google Scholar 

  • Friend A, Rapport D (1991) Evolution of macro-information systems for sustainable development. Ecol Econ 3:59–76

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Funtowicz SO, Ravetz JR (1991) Uncertainty and quality in science policy. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Dordrecht

    Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu-Roegen N (1971) The entropy law and the economic process. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gunderson L, Holling C (eds) (2002) Panarchy: understanding transformations in human and natural systems. Press, Islands

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardin G (1968) Tragedy of the commons. Science 162(3859):1243–1248

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  • Holling C (1994) What barriers? What bridges? In: Gunderson L, Holling C, Light S (eds) Barriers and bridges in renewing ecosystems and institutions. Columbia University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons WS (1965) The coal question: an inquiry concerning the progress of the nation and the probable exhaustion of our coal-mines, (1865), 3rd edn. rev. by Flux AW, New York, Augustus M. Kelly

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1960) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Koestler A (1967) The ghost in the machine. Hutchinson, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuaffman S (1995) At home in the universe: the search for laws of self-organization and complexity. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawvere F, Schanuel S (1997) Conceptual mathematics: a first introduction to categories. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Malte F, Proops J (1992) Evolution, time, production and the environment. Springer, Heidelberg

    Google Scholar 

  • Malte F, Proops J, Speck S, Jöst F (1999) Capital and time in ecological economics: neo-austrian modeling. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

  • Malthus T (1959) Population: the first essay. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A (1947) Principles of economics, 8th edn. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Alier J (1987) Ecological economics: energy, environment, and society. Basil Blackwell, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Maslow AH (1968) Toward a psychology of being. D. Van Nostrand Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayumi K (2001) The origins of ecological economics: the bioeconomics of Georgescu-Roegen. Routledge, London/New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mill JS (1985) Principles of political economy: books 1V & V. Penguin, London (org. pub. 1848)

    Google Scholar 

  • Mirowski P (1989) More heat than light: economics as social physics: physics as nature’s economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Morel R, Fleck G (2006) A fourth law of thermodynamics. Chemistry 15(4)

    Google Scholar 

  • Norgaard R (1989) The case for methodological pluralism. Ecol Econ 1:37–57

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Polimeni J, Mayumi K, Giampeetro M, Alcott B (2008) Jevons’ Paradox and the Myth of resource efficiency improvements. Earthscan Publications, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Prigogine I (1997) The end of certainty: time, chaos, and the new laws of nature. Free Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Prigogine I, Glandorf P (1971) Thermodynamic theory of structure, stability, and fluctuations. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Prigogine I, Stengers I (1984) Order out of chaos: man’s new dialogue with nature. Bantam Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rapport D, Friend A (1979) Towards a comprehensive framework for environmental statistics: A stress-response approach, Catalogue #11-510. Statistics Canada, Ottawa

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1973) The principles of political economy and taxation. Everyman’s Library, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Rio de Janerio (1992) UN world conference on the environment

    Google Scholar 

  • Robinson J (1980) Further contributions to modern economics. Basil Black Well, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen R (1985) Anticipatory systems: philosophical, mathematical and methodological foundations. Pergomon Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, R. 1991. Life Itself: A Comprehensive Inquiry into the Nature, Origin, and Fabrication of Life, New York, Columbia Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Schrödinger E (1967) What is life and mind and matter? Cambridge University Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumacher EF (1973) Small is beautiful: economics as if people mattered. Harper and Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1934) The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Shannon CE (1948) A mathematical theory of communication. Bell Syst Tech J 27(3):379–423

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon J (1981) The ultimate resource. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1809) An Inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth on nations, vol I. Mundell, Doig, and Stevenson, Edinburgh

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A (1994) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. The Modern Library, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Solo R (1974) Arithmorphism and entropy, book review, Georgescu-Roegen, “The Entropy Law and the Economic Process”. Econ Dev Cult Chang 22(3):510–517

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa P (1960) Production of commodities by means of commodities. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Stern N (2007) Review report on the economics of climate change. UK Government Press, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Stockholm (1972) UN world conference on the ‘human environment.’ Theodore Roosevelt refers to speech made to congress “lessons from China”

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone R (1968) A system of national accounts: studies in methods, Series F, 2(3), United Nations, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Vitousek P, Ehrlich P, Ehrlich A, Matson P (1986) Human appropriation of the products of photosynthesis. Bio-science 36:368–373

    Google Scholar 

  • von Böhm-Bawerk E (1891) The positive theory of capital. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • World Commission on Environment and Development (WCED) (1987) Our common future. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Zukav G (1979) The dancing Wu Lim masters: an overview of the new physics. William Morrow, New York

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Anthony Friend .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix I

1.1.1 Georgescu-Roegen’s Flow-Fund Model

Factors of production are divided into two categories: the Fund elements, which represent the agents of the process, and the flow elements, which are used or acted upon. Each flow element is represented by one coordinate E i (t). The fund element enters and leaves the process with its efficiency intact. Specifically, we can represent the participation of a Fund C σ by a single function S σ(t) showing the amount of services of C σ up to the time t, where 0 ≤ tT.

The analytical presentation of a Process can thus be written [[E t t0 (t), S t0 (t)]], where the i subscript represents input or output and σ represents both input s and outputs.

As for the analytical coordinates of a partial process, analysis must renounce the idea of including in the description of a process, either inside or outside it, the problem associated with the happenings with a process reducing to recording only what crosses the boundary. For convenience, we may refer to any element crossing the boundary from the environment into the process as an input, and to any element crossing it from the opposite direction as an output. At this juncture, analysis must make some additional heroic steps all aimed at assuming away dialectical quality.

Discretely distinct qualities are still admitted into the picture as long as their number is finite and each one is cardinally measurable. If we denote the elements that may cross the t boundary of a given process by C 1, C 2, C 3, … C n, the analytical description is complete if, for every C i , we have determined two non-decreasing functions F i (t) and G i (t), the first showing the cumulative input, the second, the cumulative output of C i up to the time (t). Naturally, these functions must be defined over the entire duration of the process which may be always represented by a closed time interval such as [0, T]. The question of whether this analytical model is operational, outside paper-and-pencil operations, cannot be decided without an examination of the nature of the elements usually found in actual processes. Such an examination reveals that there exists numerous elements for which either F i (t) or G i (t) is identically null for the entire duration of the process. Solar energy is a typical example, which is only an input for any terrestrial process. The various materials ordinarily covered by the term ‘waste’ are clear examples of elements which are only outputs. In all these cases, we may simplify the analytical picture by representing each element by one coordinate only – namely, by:

$$ {E}_i(t)={G}_i(t)-{F}_i(t) $$

For an output element, E i (t) = G i (t) ≥ 0; for an input element, E i (t) = -F i (t) ≤ 0. The sign of the suffices indicate which is actually the case (Georgescu-Roegen 1971, p. 215).

Georgescu-Roegen further distinguishes E i (t), which are (basic) elements necessary to maintain the production cycle at a steady-state (e.g., seeds → crops) and E i (t), which are (non-basic) elements that are surplus available for consumption, E i (t) = G i (t) – F i (t) ≥ 0.

1.2 Appendix II

1.2.1 Bayesian Statistical Methods

Thomas Bayes addressed both the case of discrete probability distribution of data and the more complicated case of continuous probability distribution . In the discrete case, Bayes’ theorem relates the conditional and marginal probabilities of events A and B, provided that the probability of B does not equal zero. Thus: P(A|B) = P(B|A) P(A)/P(B)

In Bayes’ theorem, each probability has a conventional name:

  • P(A) is the prior probability (or ‘unconditional’ or ‘marginal’ probability) of A. It is ‘prior’ in the sense that it does not take into account any information about B; however, the event B need not occur after event A. In the nineteenth century, the unconditional probability P(A) in Bayes’ rule was called the ‘antecedent’ probability; in deductive logic, the antecedent set of propositions and the inference rule imply consequences. The unconditional probability P(A) is called ‘a priori’.

  • P(A|B) is the conditional probability of A given B. It is also called the posterior probability because it is derived from or depends upon the specified value of B.

  • P(B|A) is the conditional probability of B given A. It is also called the likelihood.

  • P(B) is the prior or marginal probability of B, and acts as a normalising constant.

Bayes’ theorem, in this form, gives a mathematical representation of how the conditional probability of event A given B, is related to the converse conditional probability of B given A.

1.2.1.1 Bayes’ Theorem With Continuous Prior and Posterior Distribution s

Suppose a continuous probability distribution with probability density function ƒΘ is assigned to an uncertain quantity Θ. In the conventional language of mathematical probability theory, Θ would be a ‘random variable’. The probability that the event B will be the outcome of an experiment depends on Θ; it is P(B | Θ). As a function of Θ, this is the following likelihood function:

$$ L\left(\theta \right) = P\left(B\Big|\varTheta =\theta \right) $$

The posterior probability distribution of Θ (i.e., the conditional probability distribution of Θ, given the observed data B), has the probability density function:

$$ {f}_{\varTheta}\left(\theta \Big|B\right) = \mathrm{constant}\cdotp {f}_{\varTheta}\left(\theta \right)L\left(B\Big|\theta \right) $$

where the ‘constant’ is a normalising constant so chosen as to make the integral of the function equal to one, so that it is indeed a probability density function. This is the form of Bayes’ theorem actually considered by Thomas Bayes. In other words, Bayes’ theorem says: ‘To get the posterior probability distribution , multiply the prior probability distribution by the likelihood function and then normalise.’ More generally, still, the new data B maybe the value of an observed continuously distributed random variable X. The probability that it has any particular value is therefore zero. In such a case, the likelihood function is the value of a probability density function of X given Θ, rather than a probability of B given Θ:

$$ L\left(\theta \right) = {f}_x\left(x\Big|\varTheta =\theta \right) $$
1.2.1.2 Notation and Definitions

In the notation P(A|B), the symbol P is used only as a reference to the original probability. It should not be read as the probability P of some event A|B. Sometimes the more accurate notation P B (A) is used, but the use of complex events as index of the symbol P is cumbersome. Notice that the line separating the two events A and B is a vertical line.

Conditional probability is the probability of some event A, given the occurrence of some other event B. Conditional probability is written P(A|B), and is read ‘the (conditional) probability of A, given B’ or ‘the probability of A under the condition B’. When in a random experiment, and the event B is known to have occurred, the possible outcomes of the experiment are reduced to B, and hence the probability of the occurrence of A is changed from the unconditional probability into the conditional probability given B.

Joint probability is the probability of two events in conjunction. That is, it is the probability of both events occurring together. The joint probability of A and B is written as P(A|B), P(AB), or P(A, B). Marginal probability is then the unconditional probability P(A) of the event A; that is, the probability of A, regardless of whether event B did or did not occur. If B can be thought of as the event of a random variable X having a given outcome, the marginal probability of A can be obtained by summing (or integrating, more generally) the joint probabilities over all outcomes for X.

The conditioning of probabilities (i.e., updating them to take account of (possibly new) information), may be achieved through Bayes’ theorem. In such conditioning, the probability of A given only initial information I, P(A|I), is known as the prior probability. The updated conditional probability of A, given I and the outcome of the event B, is known as the posterior probability, P(A|B, I).

A continuous probability distribution is a probability distribution which possesses a probability density function. Mathematicians also call such a distribution absolutely continuous, since its cumulative distribution is absolutely continuous with respect to the Lebesgue measure λ. If the distribution of X is continuous, then X is called a continuous random variable. There are many examples of continuous probability distribution s: normal, uniform, chi-squared, and others.

The probability density function, or density of a continuous random variable, is a function that describes the relative likelihood for this random variable to occur at a given point. The probability for the random variable to fall within a particular region is given by the integral of this variable’s density over the region. The probability density function is non-negative everywhere, and its integral over the entire space is equal to one.

1.3 Appendix III

1.3.1 SAGE-P Datasets on the State and Change of State of the Econosphere, Sociosphere, and the Ecosphere

1.3.1.1 Propositions

Proposition I: An entropic Process in SAGE-P is an algorithm to map the transformation of (statistical) objects from lower into higher entropic states (i.e., consumption ), and its inverse from higher into lower entropic states (i.e., production).

The proposed methods to construct the algorithm are prescribed Bayesian Rules for scalar operators in any well-defined, hierarchical-structured, complex adaptive system in Topological Domain Space (TDS), defined as:

Econopshere (E ) ⊆ Sociosphere (E ) ⊆ 0 (E ”’)

where ⊆ = subset.

Scalar operators of the ecological flow-fund are a slow moving, but much larger scale to the socio-demographic Fund, which, in turn, is larger, but slower moving to the economic Fund (i.e., E ”’ > E > E ).

  • The elements of the E dataset belonging to the Econosphere TDS are characterised by fast moving state, and change of state, variables described by emergent properties of dissipative economic structures far from equilibrium: (i.e., domain properties of the low entropy economic fund);

  • The elements of the E dataset belonging to the Sociosphere TDS are characterised by slow moving state, and change of state, variables described by emergent properties of dissipative social-institution al structures near equilibrium (i.e., domain properties of the low entropy socio-demographic Fund);

  • The elements of the E ”’ dataset belonging to the Ecosphere TDS are characterised by very slow moving state, and change of state, variables described by emergent properties of dissipative ecosystem structures very near equilibrium (i.e., domain properties of the low entropy global ecosystem Fund).

Proposition II: The homomorphism of SAGE-P datasets are conserved value mappings of objects → objects; objects → functions; functions → objects; and functions → functions among any well-defined TDS:

  • Econosphere: the homomorphism of economic objects/functions are the values conserved-in-exchange;

  • Sociosphere: the homomorphism of socio-demographic objects/functions are the values conserved-in-use;

  • Ecosphere: the homomorphism of socio-demographic objects/functions are the values conserved-in-themselves (i.e., intrinsic value).

Proposition III: SAGE-P functions are defined by the boundary conditions of processes unique to any well-defined TDS. Objects are defined by the boundary conditions of the objects-in-themselves, but change values with respect to function:

  • Objects where values are conserved-in-exchange ∈ Econosphere

  • Objects where values are conserved-in-use ∈ Sociosphere

  • Objects where values are conserved-in-themselves ∈ Ecosphere

Proposition IV: SAGE-P qualitative properties of Objects change with Function:

  • Social and ecological objects where qualities are values conserved-in-exchange ∈ Econosphere;

  • Economic and ecological objects where qualities are values conserved-in-use ∈ Sociosphere;

  • Economic and social objects where qualities are values conserved-in-themselves ∈ Ecosphere.

1.3.1.2 Structure of Datasets

SAGE-P material datasets are observed phenomena (i.e., statistical database); all other datasets are constructed from correspondence mappings of:

  1. (i)

    objects → objects;

  2. (ii)

    objects → functions;

  3. (iii)

    functions → objects;

  4. (iv)

    functions → functions.

1.3.1.3 Working Definitions

Objects are a collection of statistical elements of the dataset, (E 1-n = Θ), and represent numerical cardinal/ordinal values of the quantitative/qualitative properties of physical/abstract objects.

Functions are a collection of algorithmic operators where the elements of the set are the instructions, [f (E 1-n ) = π Θ], (i.e., vector mapping of objects on object, objects on functions, functions on objects, and function on functions).

SAGE-P algorithmic operators are formalisms expressed in terms of entailment properties of objects and functions. These may be classified to Aristotelean hierarchical structure of causes, viz: material cause (π1) → efficient cause (π2) → formal cause (π3) ← final cause (π4). The reverse arrow of π4 reflects the (abstract) socio-cultural values mapped on sustainable development policy in terms of an intensity value measure of the socially acceptable rate of entropy production.

Homomorphism is a structure preserving algorithm permitting one-to-one correspondence mapping of the elements in the SAGE-P datasets – an example being the mapping of prices (values conserved-in-exchange) on economic objects to construct the System of National Accounting dataset (Note the symmetries conserved in linear datasets: inputs = outputs, and broken in nonlinear datasets, inputs ≠ outputs).

SAGE-P datasets are hierarchically-structured matrices of entropic processes representing the notion of:

  • Production (P e ) (i.e., negentropic processes);

  • Consumption (C e ) (i.e., entropic processes);

  • Capital Accumulation (K e ) (i.e., the low entropy Fund available for future consumption , or K e(t)= P e(t-n)C e(t-n).

1.3.1.4 Category Sets of the Statistical Database

SAGE-P datasets are divided into two separate and distinct categories, viz:

  • Physical Objects/Function (Category I): material statistics subject to the Second Law of Thermodynamics, where Category I = (Θ p) and;

  • Abstract Objects/Function (Category II): immaterial statistics not subject to the Second Law of Thermodynamic s, where Category II = (Θ a).

Category I: Quantitative values of inflow/outflow of Physical Objects in any well-defined entropic process and a parallel set of balance sheet accounts of the low entropy (physical) Fund:

  • E I Econosphere Θp’

  • E I Sociosphere Θp”

  • E ”’ I Ecosphere Θp”’

Category II: Quantitative values of inflow/outflow of Abstract Objects in any well-defined entropic process and a parallel set of balance sheet accounts of the low entropy (abstract) Fund:

  • E II Econosphere Θa’

  • E II Sociosphere Θa”

  • E ”’ II Ecosphere Θa”’

Category III: Mapping of Qualitative Values Algorithms (π) on Category I and II, π = exchange, π = use, π”’ = intrinsic

  • E III (EI, EII) π Θ

  • E III (EI, EII) π Θ

  • E III (EI, EII) π”’ Θ

Category IV: Mapping of Spatial Co-ordinate Algorithms (πs) on Category I (Note: Category II objects, by definition, have no geographical co-ordinates), πs’ = economic co-ordinate space, πs” = social coordinate space, πs”’ = ecosystem coordinate space.

  • E IV Econosphere TDS πs Θp’

  • E IV Sociosphere πs”’ Θp”

  • E IV Ecosphere πs”’ Θp”’

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Friend, A. (2017). System of Accounts for Global Entropy-Production (SAGE-P): The Accounting in the Topological Domain Space (TDS) of the Econosphere, Sociosphere, and the Ecosphere. In: Shmelev, S. (eds) Green Economy Reader. Studies in Ecological Economics, vol 6. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-38919-6_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics