Skip to main content

The Coordination Problem

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 794 Accesses

Abstract

Economists have sometimes claimed that communism could never work well because it is impossible to coordinate a complex society through central planning. This is looked at from two somewhat different viewpoints, both deriving from the critiques of F.A. Hayek. Could central coordination ever be efficient because of the enormous amount of information involved? Can a government ever come close to satisfying the very different aims that individual people have? It is clear that communist governments in practice did not operate very efficiently, but whether this is really an impossible task or not remains to some extent open. If one looks at the ability of elected governments in market societies to satisfy their citizenry with the range of services they currently provide, then one has to question whether a central authority that tried to provide a much greater range of goods and services could ever succeed.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Hayek, Road to serfdom; Hayek (1945).

  2. 2.

    Overy, The morbid age, especially Chaps. 2 and 7. For the views of economists, see Walker, Theory of the firm, pp. 112–115.

  3. 3.

    Hayek, Road to serfdom, p. 11.

  4. 4.

    Ibid., p. 11.

  5. 5.

    Ibid., Chap. 2.

  6. 6.

    Ibid., p. 26. Hayek (1945), pp. 520–521.

  7. 7.

    Hayek, Road to serfdom, p. 37.

  8. 8.

    Ibid., p. 58.

  9. 9.

    Ibid., Chaps. 6, 7, 8 and 9.

  10. 10.

    Ibid., pp. 100–109.

  11. 11.

    Ibid., p. 151.

  12. 12.

    Ibid., p. 174.

  13. 13.

    For example, Yeagar and Leland (1994).

  14. 14.

    Hayek (1945), p. 524.

  15. 15.

    Hayek (1945), p. 530.

  16. 16.

    Coase (1937).

  17. 17.

    Hill, Extreme engineering.

  18. 18.

    For example, Kemp (1999).

  19. 19.

    Kahneman et al. (1986), Kemp (1996), Olmstead and Rhode (1985).

  20. 20.

    Walker, Theory of the firm, p. 3.

  21. 21.

    Ibid., pp. 21–25.

  22. 22.

    Ibid., pp. 66–95.

  23. 23.

    Heath and Staudenmayer (2000).

  24. 24.

    Ibid., p. 157.

  25. 25.

    Ibid., pp. 161–166.

  26. 26.

    Ibid., pp. 173–182.

  27. 27.

    For example, Camerer, Behavioural game theory. Cooper, Coordination games.

  28. 28.

    Van Huyck et al. (1990).

  29. 29.

    Chaudhuri et al. (2009).

  30. 30.

    Brandts and Cooper (2007). If the groups are not fixed, then performance bonuses may become more important: Chaudhuri and Paichayontvijit (2010).

  31. 31.

    Riedl et al., Efficient coordination in weakest-link games.

  32. 32.

    Weber et al. (2001).

  33. 33.

    Weber et al. (2001).

  34. 34.

    Ibid., p. 529.

  35. 35.

    Lenin, The state and revolution, p. 473.

  36. 36.

    For example, Ellman, Socialist planning; Kornai, Socialist system.

  37. 37.

    Kantorovich, Best use of economic resources.

  38. 38.

    Ellman, Planning problems in the USSR; Ward (1960).

  39. 39.

    This is a simplified version of the problem outlined in Kantorovich, Best use of economic resources, Chap. 1, pp. 1–5.

  40. 40.

    Kantorovich, Best use of economic resources, for example, p. 148.

  41. 41.

    Ibid., Sect. 3.

  42. 42.

    For example, Kantorovich, Best use of economic resources, pp. 8–9, 138. It would perhaps have been unproductive and unwise to advocate this.

  43. 43.

    Ibid., pp. 151–152.

  44. 44.

    Kornai, Socialist system, Chap. 17. Hanson, Rise and fall of the Soviet economy, pp. 92–96. Ellman, Planning problems in the USSR, writing in 1973, expected the use to increase, although noting (e.g. p. 118, 127) that its use had been limited to date.

  45. 45.

    Kantorovich, Best use of economic resources, p. 149.

  46. 46.

    Gerovich (2008).

  47. 47.

    Gerovich (2008).

  48. 48.

    Keizer (1994). For similar views, see Yeagar and Leland (1994), p. 93, or Kornai, Socialist system, especially Chaps. 21, 22 and 23.

  49. 49.

    Caldwell (1997).

  50. 50.

    For example, Cottrell and Cockshott, Information and economics.

  51. 51.

    Grossman and Stiglitz (1980).

  52. 52.

    See, for example, Turner, Between debt and the devil, Chaps. 2 and 6.

  53. 53.

    For example, Herman, Freedom’s forge.

  54. 54.

    Hayek, Road to serfdom, pp. 152–153.

  55. 55.

    Ford, My life and work, p. 72.

  56. 56.

    Nove, Economics of feasible socialism.

  57. 57.

    Ellman, Socialist planning, pp. 201–207.

  58. 58.

    Kornai, Socialist system, Chaps. 11, 12 and 13.

  59. 59.

    For example, 2015 Index of economic freedom.

  60. 60.

    Kemp, Public goods and private wants, Chap. 3; Samuelson (1954).

  61. 61.

    Mahoney et al. (2005), Thompson and Elling (2000).

  62. 62.

    Kemp and Bolle (1999).

  63. 63.

    Ferris (1983); Kemp, Public goods and private wants, Chaps. 5, 6, 7 and 8.

  64. 64.

    For example, Chanley et al. (2000), Van de Walle and Bouckaert (2003).

  65. 65.

    Harris and Seldon, Over-ruled on welfare; Kemp and Burt (2001).

  66. 66.

    Kemp ( 2003 ).

  67. 67.

    Kemp, Public goods and private wants, Chap. 8.

  68. 68.

    Kemp (1998), Kemp et al. (1995).

  69. 69.

    De Groot and Pommer (1989).

  70. 70.

    For example, Alvarez et al. (2000).

  71. 71.

    Feld and Kirchgässner (2000), Frey (1994), Pommerehne (1978).

  72. 72.

    De Groot and Pommer (1989), Kemp and Willetts (1995).

  73. 73.

    Mahoney et al. (2005).

  74. 74.

    Hanson, Rise and fall of the Soviet economy, pp. 147–148. A state of Pareto efficiency is reached when a group of individuals or economic entities has completed all possible free trades, and other exchanges are possible only if someone loses.

  75. 75.

    For example, Bateman (2010), Skidelsky, Keynes.

  76. 76.

    Kornai, Socialist system, p. 117.

  77. 77.

    Marx’s views on how the development of productive capacity in capitalism was accompanied by impoverishment of the proletariat suggest he might have argued on the other side. Marx, Capital, Vol. 1, Part 7.

  78. 78.

    The question of whether SOEs can attain the efficiency level of privately owned firms remains a tricky one. For the most part, they seem not to (Walker, Theory of the firm, pp. 109–127). A common problem is that governments may feel obliged to support failing SOEs (Kornai, Socialist system, ch. 21; Walker, Theory of the firm, pp. 109–127, 157–158). But then, governments sometimes do this for privately owned firms as well. And governments do not always bail out SOEs: For example, in 2015 the New Zealand government refused a financial bailout for the coal-mining SOE, Solid Energy.

  79. 79.

    Kornai, Socialist system, Part 3.

References

  • Alvarez, R. M., Nagler, J., & Willette, J. R. (2000). Measuring the relative impact of issues and the economy in democratic elections. Electoral Studies, 19, 237–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bateman, B. W. (2010). Keynes returns to America. In B. W. Bateman, T. Hirai, & M. C. Marcuzzo (Eds.), The return to Keynes (pp. 13–29). Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brandts, J., & Cooper, D. (2007). It’s what you say and not what you pay: An experimental study of manager-employee relationships in overcoming coordination failure. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5, 1223–1268.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caldwell, B. (1997). Hayek and socialism. Journal of Economic Literature, 35, 1856–1890.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chanley, V. A., Rudolph, T. J., & Ryan, W. M. (2000). The origins and consequences of public trust in government: A time series analysis. Public Opinion Quarterly, 64, 239–256.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, A., & Paichayontvijit, T. (2010). Recommended play and performance bonuses in the minimum effort coordination game. Experimental Economics, 13, 346–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaudhuri, A., Schotter, A., & Sopher, B. (2009). Talking ourselves to efficiency: Coordination in intergenerational minimum games with private, almost common and common knowledge of advice. Economic Journal, 119, 91–122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. H. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Groot, H., & Pommer, E. (1989). The stability of stated preferences for public goods: Evidence from recent budget games. Public Choice, 60, 123–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feld, L. P., & Kirchgässner, G. (2000). Direct democracy, political culture, and the outcome of economic policy: A report on the Swiss experience. European Journal of Political Economy, 16, 287–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferris, J. M. (1983). Demands for public spending: An attitudinal approach. Public Choice, 40, 135–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S. (1994). Direct democracy: Politico-economic lessons from Swiss experience. American Economic Review (Papers and Proceedings), 84, 338–342.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerovich, S. (2008). InterNyet: Why the Soviet Union did not build a nationwide computer network. History and Technology: An International Journal, 24, 335–350.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, S. J., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). On the impossibility of informationally efficient markets. American Economic Review, 70, 393–408.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heath, C., & Staudenmayer, N. (2000). Coordination neglect: How lay theories of organizing complicate coordination in organizations. Research in Organizational Behavior, 22, 155–193.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1986). Fairness as a constraint on profit seeking: Entitlements in the market. American Economic Review, 76, 728–741.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kantorovich, L. V. (1965). The best use of economic resources (Ed. Morton, G., trans: Knightsfield, P. F. Oxford: Pergamon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keizer, W. (1994). Hayek’s critique of socialism. In J. Birner & R. van Zijp (Eds.), Hayek, coordination and evolution: His legacy in philosophy, politics, economics and the history of ideas (pp. 207–231). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S. (1996). Preferences for distributing goods in times of shortage. Journal of Economic Psychology, 17, 615–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S. (1998). Rating the values of government and market supplied goods. Journal of Economic Psychology, 19, 447–461.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S. (1999). Inflation. In P. E. Earl & S. Kemp (Eds.), The Elgar companion to consumer research and economic psychology (pp. 333–336). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S. (2003). The effect of providing misleading cost information on the perceived value of government services. Journal of Economic Psychology, 24, 117–128.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S., & Bolle, F. (1999). Preferences in distributing scarce goods. Journal of Economic Psychology, 20, 105–120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S., & Burt, C. D. B. (2001). Estimation of the value and cost of government and market supplied goods. Public Choice, 107, 235–252.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S., & Willetts, K. (1995). The value of services supplied by the New Zealand government. Journal of Economic Psychology, 16, 23–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp, S., Lea, S. E. G., & Fussell, S. (1995). Experiments on rating the utility of consumer goods: Evidence supporting microeconomic theory. Journal of Economic Psychology, 16, 543–561.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney, M. S., Kemp, S., & Webley, P. (2005). Factors in lay preferences for government or private supply of services. Journal of Economic Psychology, 26, 73–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olmstead, A. L., & Rhode, P. (1985). Rationing without government: The West Coast gas famine of 1920. American Economic Review, 75, 1044–1055.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pommerehne, W. W. (1978). Institutional approaches to public expenditure: Empirical evidence from Swiss municipalities. Journal of Public Economics, 9, 255–280.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1954). The pure theory of public expenditure. Review of Economics and Statistics, 36, 387–389.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thompson, L., & Elling, R. C. (2000). Mapping patterns of support for privatization in the mass public: The case of Michigan. Public Administration Review, 60, 338–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van de Walle, S., & Bouckaert, G. (2003). Public service performance and trust in government: The problem of causality. International Journal of Public Administration, 29, 891–913.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Huyck, J. B., Battalio, R. C., & Beil, R. O. (1990). Tacit coordination games, strategic uncertainty and coordination failure. American Economic Review, 80, 234–248.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ward, B. (1960). Kantorovich on economic calculation. Journal of Political Economy, 68, 545–555.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, R., Camerer, C., Rottenstreich, Y., & Knez, M. (2001). The illusion of leadership: Misattribution of cause in coordination games. Organization Science, 12, 582–588.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yeagar, L. B., & Leland, B. (1994). Mises and Hayek on calculation and knowledge. The Review of Austrian Economics, 7, 93–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kemp, S. (2016). The Coordination Problem. In: Was Communism Doomed?. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32780-8_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics