Skip to main content

The Impact of Supply Chain Structures on Corporate Social Responsibility

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Environmentally Responsible Supply Chains

Part of the book series: Springer Series in Supply Chain Management ((SSSCM,volume 3))

  • 2237 Accesses

Abstract

Markets are paying increasing attention to the social and environmental impacts of business. As a consequence, the problem of incentivizing upstream firms in a supply chain (i.e., suppliers) to engage in Corporate Social Responsibility (CSR) activities has become of pivotal importance. Formal contracts may not serve the purpose, as CSR activities are not necessarily verifiable. In this chapter, we posit that incentives for CSR can be provided through the supply chain structure, which consists of the distribution of ownership rights over the assets of production, and involves horizontal and/or vertical alliances among supply chain members. To this end, this chapter illustrates the effects of supply chain structure on CSR adoption using three case studies. For each case, the chapter highlights the interplay of forces that arises as a result of the supply chain structure, such as pooling, free-riding, and countervailing power, and discusses their impact on incentivizing supply chain parties to invest in CSR.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Several surveys have reported that consumers do value CSR activities and are willing to pay a higher price for the corresponding products. Ferreira et al. (2010) states that “consumers perceived greater benefit and value in the offer of the socially responsible firm, and were showed to be willing to pay 10 % more for its product, judging this price differential as being fair”. In a similar vein, Grimmer and Bingham (2013) finds that consumers are more willing to purchase products from companies perceived to have a higher environmental performance at each stage of the product value chain.

  2. 2.

    Empirical support for the idea that noncontractible investments are influenced by asset ownership can be found in a number of papers, including Woodruff (2002) and Acemoglu et al. (2010).

  3. 3.

    This example is adapted from Mahoney (2005).

  4. 4.

    See Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya and Bartholdi (2011) about the Shapley value being a fair mechanism of expected excess profit allocations when retailers agree to pool their inventory.

  5. 5.

    See Letizia and Hendrikse (2016) for a full comparison between the two structures.

  6. 6.

    See Starbucks Global Responsibility Report—Goals and Progress 2013, available at http://globalassets.starbucks.com/assets/98e5a8e6c7b1435ab67f2368b1c7447a.pdf.

  7. 7.

    See Starbucks website http://www.starbucks.com/responsibility/sourcing/coffee.

References

  • Acemoglu D, Griffith R, Aghion P, Zilibotti F (2010) Vertical integration and technology: theory and evidence. J Eur Economic Assoc 8(5):989–1033

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli M, Watts SG (2003) Selling to socially responsible consumers: competition and the private provision of public goods. J Econ Manag Strateg 12(3):419–445

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen L, Lee HL (2014) Mitigate supplier responsibility risk in emerging economies: an ethical sourcing framework. Working paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira DA, Avila MG, de Faria MD (2010) Corporate social responsibility and consumers’ perception of price. Soc Responsib J 6(2):208–221

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grimmer M, Bingham T (2013) Company environmental performance and consumer purchase intentions. J Bus Res 66(10):1945–1953

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grossman SJ, Hart O (1986) The costs and benefits of ownership: a theory of vertical and lateral integration. J Polit Econ 94(4):691–719

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hart O, Moore J (1990) Property rights and the nature of the firm. J Polit Econ 98(6):1119–1158

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemahlıoğlu-Ziya E, Bartholdi III JJ (2011) Centralizing inventory in supply chains by using Shapley value to allocate the profits. Manuf Serv Oper Manag 13(2):146–162

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim SH (2014) Time to come clean? Disclosure and inspection policies for green production. Working paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Letizia P, Hendrikse G (2016) Supply chain structure incentives for corporate social responsibility: An incomplete contracting analysis. Working paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Mahoney JT (2005) Economic foundations of strategy. Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza AJ, Clemen RT (2013) Outsourcing sustainability: a game-theoretic modeling approach. Environ Syst Decis 33(2):224–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Norman W, MacDonald C (2004) Getting to the bottom of “triple bottom line.” Bus Ethics Q 14(2):243–262

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Novak S, Eppinger SD (2001) Sourcing by design: product complexity and the supply chain. Manag Sci 47(1):189–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck EL, Taylor TA (2007a) Implications of breach remedy and renegotiation design for innovation and capacity. Manag Sci 53(12):1859–1871

    Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck EL, Taylor TA (2007b) Implications of renegotiation for optimal contract flexibility and investment. Manag Sci 53(12):1872–1886

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Heijden T (2013) Elk ei kost de boer drie cent. NRC Handelsblad 25

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Riel M, Ederer P (2011) FrieslandCampina create, care, change together. EFAS business case for IFAMA forum. http://www.innovationgrowth.com/fileadmin/innovationgrowth/publications/{}88055FrieslandCampinaCreateCareChangeTogetherIFAMA2011PeerEderer.pdf

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams T, Maull R, Ellis B (2002) Demand chain management theory: constraints and development from global aerospace supply webs. J Oper Manag 20(6):691–706

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1979) Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations. J Law Econ 22(2):233–261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodruff C (2002) Noncontractible investments and vertical integration in the Mexican footwear industry. Int J Ind Organ 20(8):1197–1224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Xu Y, Cho SH, Tayur S (2014) Combating child labor: incentives and information transparency in supply chains. Working paper

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I thank George Hendrikse for introducing me to the area of incomplete contracts. I am grateful to Atalay Atasu for his invitation to write this chapter, and for his insights and comments that have improved its exposition.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paolo Letizia .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The Use of the Shapley Value in Cooperative Game Theory

The Shapley value is one of the main solution concepts in cooperative game theory. A cooperative game consists of two ingredients: players and payoffs. An n-person game in characteristic function form is defined by a pair (N, v(⋅ )), where N is the set of players and v(⋅ ) is the characteristic function. The characteristic function assigns a value to every nonempty subset (or coalition) of the set of players. This value has to be interpreted as the benefit or cost that will be established when the players in the coalition cooperate. The characteristic function form describes the strategic situation. Consider the following three-players shoe game:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & v(\{1,2,3\}) = 1,\quad v(\{1,3\}) = v(\{2,3\}) = 1,\quad v(\{1,2\}) = 0,& {}\\ & v(\{1\}) = v(\{2\}) = v(\{3\}) = 0, & {}\\ \end{array}$$

which describes a scenario where player 1 and 2 own one right-hand shoe each, while player 3 owns a left-hand shoe. The game then is such that the value of a matched pair of shoes is 1, while an unmatched pair is worth 0. The Shapley value for player i can be computed as the average of the marginal contribution of player i to its predecessors for all the possible orderings of players. In the shoe game there are six possible orderings of the players: {1, 2, 3}, {1, 3, 2} {2, 1, 3}, {2, 3, 1}, {3, 1, 2}, and {3, 2, 1}. The marginal contributions of player 1 to the predecessors in each of the orderings is, respectively: 0, 0, 0, 0, 1, 0 as player 1 brings a worthy contribution only when he is preceded by player 3 and the left-hand shoe had not already been matched by player 2. The Shapley value for player 1 then is 1∕6. Following a similar procedure, one can determine the Shapley value of players 2 and 3, equal to 1∕6 and 2∕3, respectively.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Letizia, P. (2016). The Impact of Supply Chain Structures on Corporate Social Responsibility. In: Atasu, A. (eds) Environmentally Responsible Supply Chains. Springer Series in Supply Chain Management, vol 3. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-30094-8_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics