Skip to main content

Risk-Based Approaches to Asset Allocation: The Case for Risk Parity

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Risk-Based Approaches to Asset Allocation

Part of the book series: SpringerBriefs in Finance ((BRIEFSFINANCE))

Abstract

This chapter initially underlines the distinguishing features of the so called risk-based strategies for asset allocation in comparison with the Mean-Variance Analysis and proposes two criteria which highlight possible discrepancies among risk-based strategies. This is followed by a detailed illustration and interpretation of the theoretical concepts and tools of risk budgeting literature used to set up or analyse risk-based portfolios. We take into consideration the marginal risk, the total risk contribution and the percentage total risk contribution. The rest of the chapter offers an in depth discussion of the risk parity strategy, starting from the rudimental version, also known as naïve risk parity or inverse volatility strategy, to the optimal one which can really build a portfolio such that risk contributions from the different asset classes to the portfolio overall risk are equalized. We explore the use of leverage combined with a risk parity strategy. The chapter concludes giving attention to the potential evolutions of the risk parity strategy. In particular, we look at points of attractiveness and shortcomings of a potential new version of risk parity strategy that considers “risk factors” rather than asset classes as the building blocks of a portfolio construction approach.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The assumption of cash funding in calculating the marginal risk seems strong. However, we have to admit it is more acceptable in the context of finding a policy portfolio that is a strategic asset allocation solution than it would be in the context of tactical asset allocation or active portfolio management. On the issue, see Scherer (2015).

  2. 2.

    The concepts and measurements of marginal risks and total risk contributions can also be referred to different measures for portfolio risk, for example Value at Risk (VaR) and Expected Shortfall (ES). Assuming a Gaussian context and a parametric estimation approach, such risk measures are strongly related to volatility and so the extension is simple. For clarity on this point, we note that marginal risks for position i in case VaR or ES measures are used with a confidence level α (for example 95 % or 99 %) can be written under the zero-mean hypothesis as follows, respectively:

    $$ MR_{VaR\_i} = N_{1 - \alpha }^{ - 1} \cdot \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{N} {w_{j} \sigma_{ij} } }}{{\sigma_{P} }} $$
    $$ MR_{ES\_i} = \frac{1}{1 - \alpha } \cdot \frac{{\sum\nolimits_{j = 1}^{N} {w_{j} \sigma_{ij} } }}{{\sigma_{P} }} \cdot \phi \left( {N_{1 - \alpha }^{ - 1} } \right) $$

    where \( N_{\alpha }^{ - 1} \) is the inverse of the standard normal cumulative distribution function and ϕ indicates the probability density function of a Normal distribution. Moving from marginal risks to risk contributions, as usual, just requires the product with w i . We observe that both marginal risks and risk contributions are different from the ones obtained in the decomposition of portfolio volatility, but what remains unchanged are the percentage total risk contributions. Considering our notation, we assume VaR and ES are expressed as losses keeping their natural sign.

  3. 3.

    We note that in the classic Mean-Variance Optimization the portfolio weights are the main outputs and risk contributions are a secondary output determined by the first.

  4. 4.

    Risk budgets (BD i ) are indicated in relative terms (that is they are expressed in %), not as nominal values.

  5. 5.

    From Sect. 3.2, we remember that a general TRC i corresponds to \( w_{i}\,\cdot\,\frac{\partial RM}{{\partial w_{i} }} \).

  6. 6.

    In spite of the general form of the mathematical system we have adopted, we observe that with reference to the constraint on the risk budgets, Roncalli (2014) considers not very reasonable to set one risk budget to zero, it would be better to reduce the investment universe excluding the corresponding asset in that case. For this reason, he suggests a strict positivity constraint on the BD i .

  7. 7.

    Explicit solutions are admissible just in the bivariate case and in the case of constant correlation. See Sect. 3.3.

  8. 8.

    It is useful to keep in mind that try to model a constrained nonlinear optimization problem as a quadratic programming subproblem means write the second-order Taylor expansion of f(w). Since it is an N-dimensional function, the expansion involves the gradient and the hessian of the function. In particular, the quadratic subproblem at the current approximation w s has the form:

    $$ \begin{aligned} & \mathop {Min}\limits_{{{\mathbf{d}}_{w}^{*} }} \nabla f\left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right) {\mathbf{d}}_{{\mathbf{w}}} + \frac{1}{2}{\mathbf{d}}_{{{\mathbf{w}}_{{}} }}^{{\mathbf{'}}} \nabla_{{}}^{2} f\left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right)^{{}} {\mathbf{d}}_{{\mathbf{w}}} \\ & s.t. \\ & \nabla h_{f} \left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right){\mathbf{d}}_{{\mathbf{w}}} + h_{f} \left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right) = 0\,\,with\,\,f = 1, \ldots ,F \\ & \nabla y_{g} \left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right){\mathbf{d}}_{{\mathbf{w}}} + y_{g} \left( {{\mathbf{w}}_{{\mathbf{s}}} } \right) \ge 0\,\,with\,\,g = 1, \ldots ,G \\ \end{aligned} $$

    where d w  = w – w s .

    The solution of the subproblem is used as a search direction to determine the next iterate. The final solution must satisfy the so called Karush-Kuhn–Tucker conditions that, in this case, are referred to a Lagrangian function that takes into account the constraints.

  9. 9.

    See Anderson et al. (2014).

  10. 10.

    Similarly to the standard CAPM, Fig. 3.1 accepts the assumption that investors can lend and borrow money at the same rate, that is the risk-free rate.

  11. 11.

    Evidently, this real experience contrasts with the predictions of Modern Portfolio Theory that would expect the higher risk-adjusted performance from the market and not from a portfolio that is largely exposed to “safer” asset classes. However, some years ago, Frazzini and Pedersen (2013) and Asness et al. (2012) have proposed the leverage aversion argument as a theoretical explanation for this real case. According to this argument, the significant pressure in the market coming from leverage averse investors (by choice or by regulation) implies that they prefer to select a portfolio with risky assets rather than levering low-risk positions in the search for more interesting return targets. As a consequence of their pressure on the demand for riskier assets, the expected return of such assets is reduced while disregarded low-risk assets can trade at lower prices thus offering higher returns with a consequent improvement of their risk-adjusted performance. Those investors who are less leverage averse and apply leverage can benefit from the overweighting of “safer” assets in their portfolio.

  12. 12.

    If borrowing is added exclusively to the low-risk component, the amount of leverage (LEV) that is necessary can be written, according to Ruban and Meles (2011), as follows:

    $$ LEV = \frac{{\sigma_{Equity} \cdot w_{Equity} }}{{\sigma_{Bond} \cdot \left( {1 - w_{Equity} } \right)}} $$

    In our example, where the equity component is 3.10 times more volatile than the fixed income component and has a 40 % original allocation, the fixed income component must accordingly be levered 2.07 times. The resulting portfolio would reach the equalization between risk contributions and would have a higher volatility. It would include a 124.08 % exposure in the fixed income component and a 40 % exposure in equity.

  13. 13.

    The reason is that we are ignoring specific risks.

  14. 14.

    These difficulties have been highlighted and explained in details by Roncalli and Weisang (2012) and by Deguest et al. (2013).

  15. 15.

    The author who established the original concept of risk parity as a portfolio construction process, Qian, declared a preference for macroeconomic risk factors. He has argued that “…a portfolio with true risk parity should have balanced risk exposure to the economic risks of growth and inflation. As a consequence, it should have balanced (but not necessarily equal) risk contribution from three risk sources: equity, interest rates, and inflation”. See Qian (2013).

References

  • Anderson RM, Bianchi SW, Goldberg LR (2012) Will my risk parity outperform? Fin Anal J 68:75–93

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Anderson RM, Bianchi SW, Goldberg LR (2014) Determinants of levered portfolio performance. Fin Anal J 70:53–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asness CS, Frazzini A, Pedersen LH (2012) Leverage aversion and risk parity. Fin Anal J 68:47–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bender J, Briand R, Nielsen F, Stefek D (2010) Portfolio of risk premia: a new approach to diversification. J Portfolio Manage 36:17–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhansali V (2011) Beyond risk parity. J Investing 20:137–147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braga MD (2015) Risk parity versus other μ-free strategies: a comparison in a triple view. Investment Manage Fin Innovations 12:277–289

    Google Scholar 

  • Carhart M (1997) On persistence in mutual fund performance. J Finance 52:57–82

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaves D, Hsu J, Li F, Shakernia O (2012) Efficient algorithms for computing risk parity portfolio weights. J Investing 21:150–163

    Google Scholar 

  • Chow T, Hsu JC, Kuo L, Li AF (2014) A study of low-volatility portfolio construction methods. J Portfolio Manage 40:89–105

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deguest R, Martellini L, Meucci A (2013) Risk parity and beyond—from asset allocation to risk allocation decisions. Working paper. www.ssrn.com

  • Denault M (2001) Coherent allocation of risk capital. J Risk 4:1–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fabozzi FJ, Kolm PN, Pachamanova DA, Focardi SM (2007) Robust portfolio optimization and management. Wiley, Hoboken

    Google Scholar 

  • Fama E, French KR (1992) The cross-section of expected stock returns. J Finance 47:427–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frazzini A, Pedersen LH (2013) Betting against beta. J Fin Econ 111:1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee W (2011) Risk-based asset allocation: a new answer to an old question. J Portfolio Manage 37:11–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levell C (2010) Risk parity: in the spotlight after 50 years. NEPC. General Research

    Google Scholar 

  • Lhore H, Opfer H, Orszag G (2014) Diversifying risk parity. J Risk 16:53–79

    Google Scholar 

  • Maillard S, Roncalli T, Teïletche J (2010) The properties of equally weighted risk contribution portfolios. J Portfolio Manage 36:60–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martellini L (2008) Toward the design of better equity benchmarks: rehabilitating the tangency portfolio from modern portfolio theory. J Portfolio Manage 34:34–41

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Page S, Taborsky M (2011) The myth of diversification: risk factors versus asset classes. J Portfolio Manage 37:1–2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian E (2005) Risk parity portfolios. PanAgora Research Paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian E (2006) On the financial interpretation of risk contributions: risk budget do add up. J Investment Manage 4:1–11

    Google Scholar 

  • Qian E (2011) Risk parity and diversification. J Investing 20:119–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Qian E (2013) Are risk-parity managers at risk parity? J Portfolio Manage 40:20–26

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roncalli T (2014) Introduction to risk parity and budgeting. Chapman & Hall, Boca Raton

    Google Scholar 

  • Roncalli T, Weisang G (2012) Risk parity portfolios with risk factors. Centre d’Etudes des Politiques Economiques et de l’Emploi and Clark University—Graduate School of Management. Working paper

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross S (1976) The arbitrage theory of Capital asset pricing. J Econ Theor 13:341–360

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruban O, Melas D (2011) Constructing risk parity portfolios: rebalance, leverage, or both? J Investing 20:99–107

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scherer B (2015) Portfolio construction and risk budgeting. Risk Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Tasche D (2008) Capital allocation to business units and sub-portfolios: the Euler principle. In Resti A (ed) Pillar II in the new Basel accord: the challenge of economic capital, Risk Books, pp 423–453

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Maria Debora Braga .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Braga, M.D. (2016). Risk-Based Approaches to Asset Allocation: The Case for Risk Parity. In: Risk-Based Approaches to Asset Allocation. SpringerBriefs in Finance. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-24382-5_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics