Skip to main content

Aggregation of Coherent Experts’ Opinions: A Tractable Extreme-Outcomes Consistent Rule

  • Chapter
Fusion Methodologies in Crisis Management

Abstract

The paper defines a consensus distribution with respect to experts’ opinions using a multiple quantile utility model. We show that the Steiner point (Schneider, Isr J Math 2:241–249, 1971) is the representative consensus probability. The new rule for aggregation of experts’ opinions, which can be simply evaluated by the Shapley value, is prudential and coherent.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Whether opinions are expressed as probability measures, densities, mass functions, or odds, subjective probability distributions are used to form a consensus distribution through linear opinion pools (Stone 1961), linear opinion pools that only satisfy the marginalization property (DeGroot and Montera 1991), logarithmic opinion pools that satisfy external Bayesianity (Winkler 1968), or generalized logarithmic opinion pools (Genest et al. 1986) that use mathematical aggregation models.

  2. 2.

    Crès et al. (2011) focus on the maxmin expected utility model so that “the decision maker’s valuation of an act is the minimal weighted valuation, over all weight vectors of the experts’ valuations” (a weight pessimistic scenario). Gajdos and Vergnaud (2013) characterize preferences that exhibit independently aversion towards imprecision and conflict. They aggregate different evaluations through a multiple weights model where “a decision maker will satisfy the conflict aversion hypothesis whenever her degree of conflict aversion is higher than her degree of imprecision aversion.”

  3. 3.

    A capacity υ is convex if \(\upsilon (A \cup B) +\upsilon (A \cap B) \geq \upsilon (A) +\upsilon (B)\),\(\forall A,B \in 2^{S}\).

  4. 4.

    The Steiner point of a polytope, also called Steiner curvature centroid, is the weighted average of its vertices, in which the weight for each vertex is proportional to its outer angle. Details are in Schneider (1971, 1993).

  5. 5.

    The Shapley value is an operator that assigns an expected marginal contribution to each player in a coalitional game with respect to a uniform distribution over the set of all permutations on the finite set of players. Details are in Gajdos et al. (2008).

  6. 6.

    Details are in Basili and Chateauneuf (2011).

  7. 7.

    The dual or conjugate capacity \(\overline{\upsilon }\) is defined by \(\overline{\upsilon }(A) = 1 -\upsilon (A^{C})\ \forall A \in 2^{S}\).

  8. 8.

    Proposition 1 is a direct consequence of Proposition 3 in Basili and Chateauneuf ( 2011).

References

  • Ayyub B (2001) A practical guide on conducting expert-opinion elicitation of probabilities and consequences for corps facilities. IWR report 01-R-01

    Google Scholar 

  • Basili M, Chateauneuf A (2011) Extreme events and entropy: a multiple quantile utility model. Int J Approx Reason 52:1095–1102

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bi Y, Bell D, Wang H, Guo G, Guan J (2007) Combining multiple classifier using Dempster’s rule for text categorization. Appl Artif Intell 21:211–239

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chateauneuf A, Cornet B (2012) Computing the cost spread of a financial structure with bid/ask. Working paper, Universite Paris 1 and University of Kansas

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooke R (1991) Experts in uncertainty: opinion and subjective probability in science. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooke R, Wilson A, Toumisto J, Morales O, Tanio M, Evans J (2007) A probabilistic characterization of the relationship between fine particulate matter and mortality: elicitation of European experts. Environ Sci Toxicol 41:6598–6605

    Google Scholar 

  • Crès H, Gilboa I, Vieille N (2011) Aggregation of multiple prior opinions. J Econ Theory 146:2563–2582

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Curtwright A, Morgan M, Keith D (2008) Expert assessment of future photovoltaic technology. Environ Sci Technol 42:9031–9038

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • de Campos L, Huete J, Moral S (1994) Probability intervals: a tool for uncertain reasoning. Int J Uncertain Fuzziness Knowl Based Syst 2:167–196

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • DeGroot M, Montera J (1991) Optimal linear opinion pools. Manag Sci 37:546–558

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Denoeux T (2008) Conjunctive and disjunctive combination of belief functions induced by non distinct bodies of evidence. Artif Intell 172:234–264

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dubois D (2011) Fuzzy measures on finite scales as families of possibility measures. EUSFLAT-LFA

    Google Scholar 

  • Dubois D, Prade H (1994) Possibility theory and data fusion in poorly informed environments. Control Eng Pract 2:812–823

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gajdos T, Vergnaud J (2013) Decisions with conflicting and imprecise information. Soc Choice Welf 41:427–452

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Gajdos T, Hayashi T, Tallon JM, Vergnaud JC (2008) Attitude toward imprecise information. J Econ Theory 140:27–65

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Genest C, Remillard B (2006) Comments on T. Mikosh’s paper “Copulas: tales and facts”. Extremes 9:27–36

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Genest C, McConway K, Schervish M (1986) Characterization of externally Bayesian pooling operators. Ann Stat 14:487–501

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Grabish M, Labreuche C (2005) Bi-capacities II: the Choquet integral. Fuzzy Set Syst 151: 237–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guidance Note for Lead Authors (2010) IPCC 5th assessment report on consistent treatment of uncertainties. Intergovernmental panel on climate change (IPCC), IPCC cross-working group meeting on consistent treatment of uncertainties, Jasper Ridge, CA

    Google Scholar 

  • Hadar J, Russell W (1969) Rules for ordering uncertain prospects. Am Econ Rev 59:25–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Ha-Duong M (2008) Hierarchical fusion of expert opinion in the transferable belief model, application to climate sensitivity. Int J Approx Reason 49:555–574

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hammitt J, Zhang Y (2012) Combining experts’ judgments: comparison of algorithmic methods using synthetic data. TSE working paper, pp 12–293

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2013) In: Stocker F, Qin D, Plattner G, Tignor M, Allen S, Boschung J, Nauels A, Xia Y, Bex V, Midgley PM (eds) Climate change 2013: The physical science basis. Contribution of working group I to the 5th assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge/New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Kriegler E, Hall J, Held H, Dawson R, Schellnhuber H (2009) Imprecise probability assessment of tipping points in the climate system. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 106:5041–5046

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levi H, Wiener Z (1998) Stochastic dominance and prospect dominance with subjective weighting functions. J Risk Uncertain 16:147–163

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Owen G (1968) Game theory. Saunders Company, Philadelphia

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Plous S (1993) The psychology of judgment and decision making. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Roman H, Walker K, Walsh T, Conner L, Richmond H, Hubbell B (2008) Expert judgment assessment of the mortality impact of changes in ambient fine particulate matter in the US. Environ Sci Technol 42:2268–2274

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandri S, Dubois D, Kalfsbeek H (1995) Corrections to elicitation, assessment, and pooling of expert judgments using possibility theory. IEEE Trans Fuzzy Syst 3. doi:10.1109/TFUZZ.1995.4819

    Google Scholar 

  • Savage L (1971) Elicitation of personal probabilities and expectations. J Am Stat Assoc 66:783–801

    Article  MathSciNet  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider R (1971) On Steiner points of convex bodies. Isr J Math 2:241–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schneider R (1993) Convex bodies: the Brunn-Minkowski theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Stephanou H, Lu S (1988) Measuring consensus effectiveness by a generalized entropy criterion. IEEE Trans Pattern Anal Mach Intell 10:544–554

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stone M (1961) The opinion pool. Ann Math Stat 32:1339–1342

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Department of Transportation/Federal Railroad Administration (2003) Chapter 2: approach to estimation of human reliability in train control system studies. In: Human reliability analysis in support of risk assessment for positive train control. DOT/FRA/ORD- 03/15. Office of Research and Development, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2005) Guidelines for carcinogen risk assessment. EPA/630/P-03-001B. Risk Assessment Forum, Office of Research and Development, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2006) Regulatory impact analysis of the final PM national ambient air quality standards, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2007) Regulatory impact analysis of the proposed revisions to the national ambient air quality standards (NAAQS) for ground-level ozone

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (2011) Expert elicitation task force white paper, EPA-452/R-07-008, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Office of Management and Budget (USOMB) (2002) Guidelines for ensuring and maximizing the quality, objectivity, utility, and integrity of information disseminated by federal agencies. Fed Regist 67(36):8452–8460

    Google Scholar 

  • U.S. Nuclear Regulatory Commission (USNRC) (1996) Branch technical position on the use of expert elicitation in the high-level radioactive waste program. NUREG-1563. Division of Waste Management, Office of Nuclear Material Safety and Standards, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Winkler R (1968) The consensus of subjective probability distributions. Manag Sci 15:61–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yu D (1997) Expert opinion elicitation process using a fuzzy probability. J Korean Nucl Soc 29: 25–34

    Google Scholar 

  • Zickfeld K, Morganb M, Frame D, Keithd D (2010) Expert judgments about transient climate response to alternative future trajectories of radiative forcing. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 107:12451–12456

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcello Basili .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Basili, M., Chateauneuf, A. (2016). Aggregation of Coherent Experts’ Opinions: A Tractable Extreme-Outcomes Consistent Rule. In: Rogova, G., Scott, P. (eds) Fusion Methodologies in Crisis Management. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-22527-2_19

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-22527-2_19

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-22526-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-22527-2

  • eBook Packages: EngineeringEngineering (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics