Skip to main content

Change Frameworks

  • Chapter
  • 1547 Accesses

Part of the book series: Management for Professionals ((MANAGPROF))

Abstract

Whoever wishes or needs to change must fully understand the levers of the reality to be changed in order to be able to make precise corrections. In this chapter, therefore, we shall examine the framework conditions of banks’ present-day business models.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The sixth Kondratieff cycle has begun in parallel with the intensification of the fifth. An empirical analysis has shown that health, in the holistic sense of the bearer, will be the next long cycle. The main bearers of the sixth Kondratieff are psychosocial health and biotechnology (on the further developments of the Kondratieff cycles see Kondratieff 2013).

  2. 2.

    The term Web 2.0 describes the altered use of the internet and emerged with the strong growth of community sites at the middle of the last decade. Web 2.0 offers not only the mere dissemination of information or product sales, but also enables the participation of the user, which leads to the generation of additional benefits (Gabler Wirtschaftslexikon 2013). Web 3.0 is based on the semantic web. The information on the internet can be ascribed with clear meanings, which allows the mechanical processing of the information gathered on the internet, leading to more efficient search engines and the generation of new web services (Wikipedia 2013; Swisscom 2013).

  3. 3.

    Utterback speaks of “dominant design”, meaning “the design that wins the allegiance of the marketplace, the one that competitors and innovators must adhere to if they hope to command significant market following”. Utterback (1994, p. 24).

  4. 4.

    An example of path dependency is the IT equipment of large companies. If the entire company uses Microsoft products, a change of system to Apple involves much time, effort, and expense, even if the quality of the Apple products is often better that that of Microsoft. The initial fundamental decision to install the Microsoft Windows system led to the path dependency of the company in later years.

  5. 5.

    At first, the PC was underestimated by all makers of mainframes. They did not believe that existing customers would be interested in these devices. That was true, but a much larger market emerged with new customer segments, which was occupied by new manufacturers.

  6. 6.

    When the PC was invented, not many market participants realised just how revolutionary the changes to the working environment would be. The mainframe computer industry, which dominated at the time, was completely obliterated. Only IBM managed to adapt to the PC age (Downes and Mui 1998).

  7. 7.

    “In the extreme manifestation of market coordination, all transactions in an economic system between individuals are processed on the basis of individual contractual rules; no multi-person economic units participate in the transaction process.” (Freese 1993, p. 203).

  8. 8.

    “If companies are founded, then transactions are removed from the market and processed in companies. […] Outside of companies, price movements control production; it is determined by a series of exchange transactions on the market. Within companies the market transactions are suspended and complicated market transactions with exchange transactions are replaced by coordination by the company owner, who controls production.” (Freese 1993, p. 204).

  9. 9.

    Coase (1960, p. 15) describes market transaction costs as follows: “In order to conduct a market transaction, one must find out with whom one wishes to transact; inform people that one wishes to transact with them, and under which conditions; conduct negotiations that will lead to a conclusion; draw up the contract; install the requisite controls to ensure that the contractual conditions will be observed.” Somewhat deviating, but substantially similar categorisations can be found, for example, in Freixas and Rochet (1998), Fuchs (1994) and Picot (1991).

  10. 10.

    In the service provision sector, the search for suitable employees, for example, is a complicated process (Richter and Furubotn 1999).

  11. 11.

    Kreps (1999) notes that inefficient results can arise from information asymmetries (if one partner has more, perhaps private information).

  12. 12.

    These costs will also be addressed in detail in the context of the process costs analysis.

  13. 13.

    In the 1980s (equity) capital was a scarce commodity and therefore the focus was placed on shareholders’ profitability, which had been somewhat neglected in previous years.

  14. 14.

    The total capital value from DCF minus the market value of the borrowed capital produces the market value of equity.

  15. 15.

    25 % equity profitability was an established measured and target value prior to the outbreak of the financial crisis in 2008.

  16. 16.

    On the discussion in Switzerland, which also includes Germany, see also Handelszeitung (2013).

  17. 17.

    In addition to these there are “search qualities”, which can be assessed analytically prior to the conclusion of a transaction, and “experience qualities”, which can be assessed after the conclusion of a transaction (Bruhn 1997; Bruhn and Meffert 1995).

  18. 18.

    Thus many users can read the online version of a daily newspaper at the same time. The freedom of financial products from competition is limited, however. The danger of insider trading and the delayed forwarding of information are just two examples of possible conflicts of interest when it comes to financial products.

  19. 19.

    Internet Explorer by Microsoft, for example, is a protected object, but a browser in general is not, which is why there are a number of products that are based on the same idea.

  20. 20.

    See Nelson (1970) on trust-based goods. From this perspective, the importance of brand management for asset managers is understandable.

References

  • Arrow, K. (1962). Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for innovation. In National Bureau of Economic Research (Ed.), The rate and direction of incentive activity: Economic and social factors (pp. 609–626). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow, K. (1969). The organization of economic activity. The analysis and evaluation public expenditures: The PBB-system. In R. Richter & E. Furubotn (Eds.), Neue Institutionenökonomik. Tübingen: JCB Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. (1990, February). Positive feedbacks in the economy. Scientific American, 262, 92–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W. (1994). Path dependence, self-reinforcement and human learning. In W. Arthur (Hrsg), Increasing returns and path dependency in the economy (S. 133–158). Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bächtold, R. (2003). Marketing für Finanzdienstleistungen. Bern: Eigenverlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernet, B. (2003). Institutionelle Grundlagen der Finanzintermediation. Oldenbourg: München.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernet, B. (2004, Juni 13.). zit. In F. Pfiffner (Ed.), Keine einfache Liaison. NZZ am Sonntag, S. 47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bisignano, J. (1998). Towards an understanding of the changing structure of financial intermediation – An evolutionary theory of institutional survival, SUERF Studies, Nr. 4, Amsterdam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruhn, M. (1997). Marketing – Grundlagen für Studium und Praxis. Gabler: Wiesbaden.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruhn, M., & Meffert, H. (1995). Dienstleistungsmarketing. Wiesbaden: Gabler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brynjolfsson, E., & Hitt, L. (1998). Beyond the productivity paradox. Communications of the ACM, 41(8), 49–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Büschgen, H. (1991). Prinzipien, Aufgaben und Teilbereiche der Organisation. In J. Stein & J. Terrahe (Hrsg), Handbuch der Bankorganisation (S. 27–58). Wiesbaden.

    Google Scholar 

  • Büschgen, H. (1994). Bankbetriebswirtschaftslehre. Stuttgart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Büschgen, H. (1998). Bank-marketing. Wiesbaden: Gabler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, C. (1997). The innovator’s dilemma—When technologies cause great firms to fail. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen, C., & Overdorf, M. (2000, March). Meeting the challenge of disruptive change. Harvard Business Review, 78(2), 66–76.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4, 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cocca, T., Linner, F., Podlewski, M., & Stapfer, P. (2001). Finanzportale—Die neuen Konkurrenten der klas- sischen Universalbanken? Österreichisches Bankarchiv (ÖBA), 03(2001), 229–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, S., Delong, J., & Zysman, J. (2000). Tools for thought: What is new and important about the Economy (BRIE Working Paper Nr. 138). Berkeley: BRIE.

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsten, H. (1990). Betriebswirtschaftslehre der Dienstleistungsunternehmungen. München.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downes, L., & Mui, C. (1998). Unleashing the killer app—Digital strategies for market dominance. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P., & Wurster, T. (1998). Die Internet-Revolution—Alte Geschäfte vergehen, neue entstehen. Harvard Business Manager, 2, 51–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, R. (1986). Innovation: The attacker’s advantage, New York. In J. M. Utterback (Hrsg), (1994) Mastering the dynamics of innovation: How companies can seize opportunities in the face of technological change. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freese, G. (1993). Organisationstheorie. Wiesbaden.

    Google Scholar 

  • Freixas, X., & Rochet, J. (1998). Microeconomics of banking. London: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuchs, W. (1994). Die Transaktionskostentheorie und ihre Anwendung auf die Ausgliederung von Verwaltungsfunktionen aus industriellen Unternehmen. Trier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gabler Wirtschaftslexikon. (2013). Web 2.0. Zugegriffen September 18, 2013, http://wirtschaftslexikon.gabler.de/Definition/web-2-0.html

  • Geiger, H. (1999). E-Commerce und die Banken. Soft(net) Update, 02/1999b, S 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handelszeitung. (2013). Die Abzocker-Initiative. Zugegriffen February 10, 2013, from http://www.handelszeitung.ch/die-abzocker-initia-tive

  • Hirshleifer, J. (1973). Exchange theory: The missing chapter. Western Economic Journal, 11, 129–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, J., & Riley, J. (1979). The analytics of uncertainty and intermediation—An expository survey. Journal of Economic Literature, 17, 1375–1421.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hotz-Hart, B., Dümmler, P., Mäder, S., Schmuki, D., & Vock, P. (2001). Volkswirtschaft der Schweiz. Zürich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kondratieff, L. (1926). About the question of major cycles in the conjuncture. In C. Freeman & F. Louca (Hrsg), As time goes by—From the industrial revolutions to the information revolution (S. 384). Oxford: Oxford University Press (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kondratieff, L. (2013). Der sechste Kondratieff. Zugegriffen September 25, 2013, from http://www.kondratieff.net/19.html

  • Kotler, P., & Bliemel, F. (1992). Marketing-management: Analyse, Planung, Umsetzung und Steuerung. Stuttgart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koye, B. (2005). Private Banking im Informationszeitalter. Bern: Haupt Verlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D. (1999). A course in microeconomic theory. New York. In R. Richter & E. Furubotn (Hrsg), Neue Institutionenökonomik (S. 52). JCB Mohr: Tübingen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nefiodow, A. (1999). Der sechste Kondratieff—Wege zur Produktivität und Vollbeschäftigung im Zeitalter der Information. St. Augustin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 2(78), 311–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Picot, A. (1991). Ökonomische Theorien der Organisation—Ein Überblick über neuere Ansätze und deren betriebswirtschaftliches Anwendungspotential. In D. Orderheide, B. Rudolph, & E. Büsselmann (Hrsg), Betriebswirtschaftslehre und ökonomische Theorie (S. 143–170). Stuttgart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Platzek, H. (1996). Perspektiven des Vertriebs von Finanzdienstleistungen. Bank und Markt, 25(2), 10–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • PWC. (2013). Profitable growth in the digital age. Retrieved May 5, 2015, from https://www.pwc.ch/user_content/editor/files/svcs_adv/pwc_profitable_growth_e[1].pdf

  • Rappaport, A., & Klien, W. (1998). Shareholder Value: Ein Handbuch für Manager und Investore. Stuttgart: Schäffer Pöschel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richter, R., & Furubotn, E. (1999). Neue Institutionenökonomik. Tübingen: JCB Mohr.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1911). Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung. Leipzig: Duncker and Humbolt.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1942). Capitalism, socialism and democracy. In C. Freeman & F. Louca (Hrsg), As time goes by. (S. 48). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J. (1961). Konjunkturzyklen: Eine theoretische, historische und statistische Analyse des kapitalistischen Prozesses. Göttingen: Vandenhoek & Ruprecht.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shapiro, C., & Varian, H. (1999). Information rules—A strategic guide to the networked economy. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solow, M. (1957). Technical change and the aggregate production function. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 39, 312–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Süchting, J. (1991). Die Theorie der Bankenloyalität—(noch) eine Basis zum Verständnis der Absatz- beziehungen von Kreditinstituten? In J. Süchting & E. van Hooven (Hrsg), Handbuch des Bankmarketing (S. 1–42). Wiesbaden.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swisscom. (2013). Zuge-griffen Okt. 10, 2013, from www.swisscom.ch/de/ghq/innovation/forschung/trends/…/web-30.html

  • Utterback, J. (1994). Mastering the dynamics of innovation: How companies can seize opportunities in the face of technological change. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Utterback, J., & Abernathy, W. (1978). Patterns of industrial innovation. Technology Review, 80, 40–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volkart, R. (2006). Corporate finance: Grundlagen von Finanzierung und Investition. Zürich: Versus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiber, R. (1992). Die Diffusion von Innovationen in der Telekommunikation—Probleme der kritischen Massen. Wiesbaden: Gabler.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whinston, A., Stahl, D., & Choi, S. (1997). The economics of electronic commerce. Indianapolis, IN: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wikipedia. (2013). Semantisches Web. Zugegriffen November 28, 2013, from http://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Semantisches_Web

  • Williamson, O. (1990). Die ökonomischen Institutionen des Kapitalismus. Heidelberg.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zöllner, G. (1995). Kundennähe in Dienstleistungsunternehmen. Wiesbaden: Deutscher Universitäts-Verlag.

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Auge-Dickhut, S., Koye, B., Liebetrau, A. (2016). Change Frameworks. In: Customer Value Generation in Banking. Management for Professionals. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-19938-2_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics