Skip to main content

Game Theory and Morality

  • Chapter
The Evolution of Morality

Part of the book series: Evolutionary Psychology ((EVOLPSYCH))

Abstract

Why do we think it’s wrong to treat people merely as a means to end? Why do we consider lies of omission less immoral than lies of commission? Why do we consider it good to give, regardless of whether the gift is effective? We use four simple game theoretic models—the Coordination Game, the Hawk–Dove game, Repeated Prisoner’s Dilemma, and the Envelope Game—to shed light on these and other puzzling aspects of human morality. We also justify the use of game theory for the study of morality and explore implications for group selection and moral realism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Note that we focus on the concept of Nash equilibrium in this chapter and not evolutionary stable strategy (ESS), a refinement of Nash that might be more familiar to an evolutionary audience. ESS are the Nash equilibria that are most relevant in evolutionary contexts. However, ESS is not well defined in many of our games, so we will focus on the insights garnered from Nash and directly discuss evolutionary dynamics when appropriate.

  2. 2.

    Technically, the conditions under which we expect players to avoid looking and attend to looking are c h > a/(1 − w) > c l p + c h(1 − p) and bp + d(1 − p) < 0), where c h and c l are the magnitudes of the high and low temptations, respectively; p is the likelihood of the low temptation; a/(1 − w) is the value of a repeated, cooperative interaction to player 1; and bp + d(1 − p) is the expected payoff to player 2 if player 1 only cooperates when the temptation is low.

  3. 3.

    The simulations employ numerical estimation of the replicator dynamics for a limited strategy space: cooperate without looking, cooperate with looking, look and cooperate only when the temptation is low, and always defect for player 1, and end if player 1 looks, end if player 1 defects, and always end for player 2.

  4. 4.

    In fact, even if one knows that others know that the transgression was intended, omission will still be judged as less wrong, since the transgression still won’t create what game theorists call common p-belief, which is required for an event to influence behavior in a game with multiple equilibria.

  5. 5.

    This is where the assumption of a uniform distribution comes in. Had we instead assumed, for instance, that the continuous variable is normally distributed, then it would not be exactly 50–50 but would deviate slightly depending on the standard deviation and the location of the threshold. Nevertheless, the upcoming logic will still go through for most Coordination Games, i.e. any Coordination Game with risk dominance not too close to .5.

  6. 6.

    As with omission, this follows from iterative elimination of strictly dominated strategies (see Hoffman et al., 2015, for details).

References

  • Alpizar, F., Carlsson, F., & Johansson-Stenman, O. (2008). Anonymity, reciprocity, and conformity: Evidence from voluntary contributions to a national park in Costa Rica. Journal of Public Economics, 92(5), 1047–1060.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., & Petrie, R. (2004). Public goods experiments without confidentiality: A glimpse into fund-raising. Journal of Public Economics, 88(7), 1605–1623.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J. (1990). Impure altruism and donations to public goods: A theory of warm-glow giving. The Economic Journal, 100, 464–477.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andreoni, J., Rao, J. M., & Trachtman, H. (2011). Avoiding the ask: A field experiment on altruism, empathy, and charitable giving. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. M. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R., & Hamilton, W. D. (1981). The evolution of cooperation. Science, 211(4489), 1390–1396.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Ayres, I., Raseman, S., & Shih, A. (2012). Evidence from two large field experiments that peer comparison feedback can reduce residential energy usage. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization, 2–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateson, M., Nettle, D., & Roberts, G. (2006). Cues of being watched enhance cooperation in a real-world setting. Biology Letters, 2(3), 412–414.

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Batson, C. D. (2014). The altruism question: Toward a social-psychological answer. Hillside, NJ: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Batson, C. D., Kobrynowicz, D., Dinnerstein, J. L., Kampf, H. C., & Wilson, A. D. (1997). In a very different voice: Unmasking moral hypocrisy. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 72(6), 1335.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Bolton, G. E., Katok, E., & Ockenfels, A. (2005). Cooperation among strangers with limited information about reputation. Journal of Public Economics, 89(8), 1457–1468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cain, D., Dana, J., & Newman, G. (2014). Giving vs. giving in. Yale University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chammah, A. M., & Rapoport, A. (1965). Prisoner’s dilemma; a study in conflict and cooperation. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chwe, M. (2013). Rational ritual: Culture, coordination, and common knowledge. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cone v. West Virginia Pulp & Paper Co., 330 U.S. 212, 67 S. Ct. 752, 91 L. Ed. 849 (1947).

    Google Scholar 

  • Critcher, C. R., Inbar, Y., & Pizarro, D. A. (2013). How quick decisions illuminate moral character. Social Psychological and Personality Science, 4(3), 308–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cushman, F., Young, L., & Hauser, M. (2006). The role of conscious reasoning and intuition in moral judgment testing three principles of harm. Psychological Science, 17(12), 1082–1089.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Dalkiran, N. A., Hoffman, M., Paturi, R., Ricketts, D., & Vattani, A. (2012). Common knowledge and state-dependent equilibria. In Algorithmic game theory (pp. 84–95). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dana, J., Cain, D. M., & Dawes, R. M. (2006). What you don’t know won’t hurt me: Costly (but quiet) exit in dictator games. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 100(2), 193–201.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dana, J., Weber, R. A., & Kuang, J. X. (2007). Exploiting moral wiggle room: Experiments demonstrating an illusory preference for fairness. Economic Theory, 33(1), 67–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davies, N. B. (1978). Territorial defense in the speckled wood butterfly (pararge aegeria): The resident always wins. Animal Behaviour, 26, 138–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins, R. (2006). The selfish gene. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S., List, J. A., & Malmendier, U. (2012). Testing for altruism and social pressure in charitable giving. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(1), 1–56.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Delton, A. W., Krasnow, M. M., Cosmides, L., & Tooby, J. (2011). Evolution of direct reciprocity under uncertainty can explain human generosity in one-shot encounters. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 108(32), 13335–13340.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeScioli, P., Bruening, R., & Kurzban, R. (2011). The omission effect in moral cognition: Toward a functional explanation. Evolution and Human Behavior, 32(3), 204–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeScioli, P., Gilbert, S. S., & Kurzban, R. (2012). Indelible victims and persistent punishers in moral cognition. Psychological Inquiry, 23(2), 143–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeScioli, P., & Wilson, B. J. (2011). The territorial foundations of human property. Evolution and Human Behavior, 32(5), 297–304.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeScioli, P., & Kurzban, R. (2009). Mysteries of morality. Cognition, 112(2), 281–299.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Descioli, P., & Karpoff, R. (2014). People’s judgments about classic property law cases. Brandeis University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Desvousges, W. H., Johnson, F. R., Dunford, R. W., Boyle, K. J., Hudson, S. P., Wilson, K. N., et al. (2010). Measuring nonuse damages using contingent valuation: An experimental evaluation of accuracy. Research Triangle Park, NC: RTI Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Epley, N., Keysar, B., Van Boven, L., & Gilovich, T. (2004). Perspective taking as egocentric anchoring and adjustment. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 87(3), 327.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Fischbacher, U. (2003). The nature of human altruism. Nature, 425(6960), 785–791.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., Fischbacher, U., & Gächter, S. (2002). Strong reciprocity, human cooperation, and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature, 13(1), 1–25.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, R. A. (1958). The genetic theory of natural selection. Mineola, NY: Dover.

  • Frank, R. H. (1988). Passions within reason: The strategic role of the emotions. New York: WW Norton & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frey, B. S., & Meier, S. (2004). Social comparisons and pro-social behavior: Testing “conditional cooperation” in a field experiment. American Economic Review, 94, 1717–1722.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Funk, P. (2006). Modern voting tools, social incentives and voter turnout: Theory and evidence. In Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, Chicago, IL.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gelman, A., Silver, N., & Edlin, A. (2012). What is the probability your vote will make a difference? Economic Inquiry, 50(2), 321–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2007). The evolution of private property. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 64(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H., Bowles, S., Boyd, R., & Fehr, E. (2003). Explaining altruistic behavior in humans. Evolution and Human Behavior, 24(3), 153–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, N. J., Cialdini, R. B., & Griskevicius, V. (2008). A room with a view-point: Using social norms to motivate environmental conservation in hotels. Journal of Consumer Research, 35(3), 472–482.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greene, J. D., Cushman, F. A., Stewart, L. E., Lowenberg, K., Nystrom, L. E., & Cohen, J. D. (2009). Pushing moral buttons: The interaction between personal force and intention in moral judgment. Cognition, 111(3), 364–371.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Haidt, J. (2012). The righteous mind: Why good people are divided by politics and religion. New York: Vintage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haley, K. J., & Fessler, D. M. (2005). Nobody’s watching? Subtle cues affect generosity in an anonymous economic game. Evolution and Human Behavior, 26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hedden, T., & Zhang, J. (2002). What do you think I think you think? Strategic reasoning in matrix games. Cognition, 85(1), 1–36.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, M., Yoeli, E., & Nowak, M. A. (2015). Cooperate without looking: Why we care what people think and not just what they do. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 112(6), 1727–1732.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, M., Yoeli, E., & Dalkiran, A. (2015). Social applications of common knowledge. Harvard University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325–1348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1997/1787). Groundwork of the metaphysics of morals (1785). Practical Philosophy, 108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlan, D., & List, J. A. (2006). Does price matter in charitable giving? Evidence from a large-scale natural field experiment. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurzban, R. (2012). Why everyone (else) is a hypocrite: Evolution and the modular mind. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lacetera, N., & Macis, M. (2010). Social image concerns and prosocial behavior: Field evidence from a nonlinear incentive scheme. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 76(2), 225–237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levitt, S. D., & List, J. A. (2007). What do laboratory experiments measuring social preferences reveal about the real world? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 21, 153–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A. (2007). On the interpretation of giving in dictator games. Journal of Political Economy, 115(3), 482–493.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A., Berrens, R. P., Bohara, A. K., & Kerkvliet, J. (2004). Examining the role of social isolation on stated preferences. American Economic Review, 94, 741–752.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Locke, J. (1988/1688). Locke: Two treatises of government student edition. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G. (2007). Principles of economics. Thomson Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Weber, R. J. (1982). The value of information in a sealed-bid auction. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 10(1), 105–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morris, S., & Shin, H. S. (2002). Social value of public information. The American Economic Review, 92(5), 1521–1534.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (2004). Justice, institutions, and multiple equilibria. Chicago Journal of International Law, 5, 91.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuwirth, R. (2005). Shadow cities: A billion squatters, a new urban world. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nowak, M. A. (2006). Evolutionary dynamics: Exploring the equations of life. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Panchanathan, K., & Boyd, R. (2004). Indirect reciprocity can stabilize cooperation without the second-order free rider problem. Nature, 432(7016), 499–502.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Pinker, S. (2003). The blank slate: The modern denial of human nature. UK: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinker, S., Nowak, M. A., & Lee, J. J. (2008). The logic of indirect speech. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 105(3), 833–838.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rand, D. G., & Epstein, Z. G. (2014). Risking your life without a second thought: Intuitive decision-making and extreme altruism. Available at SSRN 2424036.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, L., & Ward, A. (1996). Naive realism: Implications for social conflict and misunderstanding. In T. Brown, E. Reed, & E. Turiel (Eds.), Values and knowledge (pp. 103–135).

    Google Scholar 

  • Roth, A. E. (1995). Bargaining experiments. In J. H. Kagel & E. R. Alvin (Eds.), The handbook of experimental economics (pp. 253–342). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sigg, H., & Falett, J. (1985). Experiments on respect of possession and property in hamadryas baboons (Papio hamadryas). Animal Behaviour, 33(3), 978–984.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. M., & Price, G. (1973). The logic of animal conflict. Nature, 246, 15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sosis, R., & Alcorta, C. (2003). Signaling, solidarity, and the sacred: The evolution of religious behavior. Evolutionary Anthropology: Issues, News, and Reviews, 12(6), 264–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spranca, M., Minsk, E., & Baron, J. (1991). Omission and commission in judgment and choice. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 27(1), 76–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sudarshan, A. (2014). Nudges in the marketplace: Using peer comparisons and incentives to reduce household electricity consumption. Technical report, Harvard University Working Paper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. (1980). Toward a positive theory of consumer choice. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1(1), 39–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thomson, J. J. (1976). Killing, letting die, and the trolley problem. The Monist, 59(2), 204–217.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Tirole, J. (1988). The theory of industrial organization. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R. (2011). The folly of fools: The logic of deceit and self-deception in human life. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R. L. (1971). The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quarterly Review of Biology, 46, 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, R. L. (1974). Parent-offspring conflict. American Zoologist, 14(1), 249–264.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, G. S. (1984). Reciprocal food sharing in the vampire bat. Nature, 308(5955), 181–184.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S. (2010). Darwin’s cathedral: Evolution, religion, and the nature of society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, E. O. (2012). The social conquest of earth. New York: WW Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S. (2006). Human groups as adaptive units: Toward a permanent consensus. In P. Carruthers, S. Laurence, & S. Stich (Eds.), The innate mind: Culture and cognition. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Winter, E. (2014). Feeling smart: Why our emotions are more rational than we think. Public Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wroughton, L. (2013). As Syria War Escalates, Americans Cool to U.S. Intervention: Reuter/Ipsos Poll. Reuters, August 24, 2013. Accessed at http://www.reuters.com/article/2013/08/25/us-syria-crisis-usa-poll-idUSBRE97O00E20130825 on 12 March 2015.

  • Yoeli, E., Hoffman, M., Rand, D. G., & Nowak, M. A. (2013). Powering up with indirect reciprocity in a large-scale field experiment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 110(Suppl. 2), 10424–10429.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zahavi, A. (1975). Mate selection: A selection for a handicap. Journal of Theoretical Biology, 53(1), 205–214.

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Moshe Hoffman .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Hoffman, M., Yoeli, E., Navarrete, C.D. (2016). Game Theory and Morality. In: Shackelford, T., Hansen, R. (eds) The Evolution of Morality. Evolutionary Psychology. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-19671-8_14

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics