Skip to main content

Great Divergence and the Rise of the West

  • Chapter
Great Divergence and Great Convergence

Abstract

In this chapter the authors first of all give a sketch of the whole process of the Great Divergence and its transformation into the Great Convergence. This is followed by a detailed analysis of those factors that allowed the West to overtake the East in the Modern Period, as well as those factors that put in motion the process of the Great Divergence. This necessitates the consideration of certain aspects of the development of the East and the West from the mid-fifteenth century (and even earlier in some respects) till the late twentieth century. Among the most important provisions that the authors develop in this chapter is the idea that, starting with the early second millennium BC, one can distinguish the potential that later enabled Europe to overtake the East. However, for a long time Europe lagged far behind the East, and it managed to develop its potential advantages only in the Early Modern Period. The chapter analyzes in detail the reasons that enabled Europe to achieve this. Another important idea in this chapter is that the authors believe it is much more reasonable to consider the Industrial Revolution as a rather long-term process that started in the late fifteenth century and continued till the mid-nineteenth century. This process went through several phases, and, in our understanding, the period between the last third of the eighteenth and the first third of the nineteenth century (this period is traditionally denoted as the period of the “Industrial Revolution”) was only the final phase of the Industrial Revolution, at which an irreversible transition to machine technology and at the same time to a new kind of energy occurred. But it was the most prominent and visible phase of the industrial revolution. The authors do not consider the European nineteenth-century breakthrough as a really unexpected development, they rather view it as a fairly long process that continued from the fifteenth to the nineteenth century, during which in some respects (e.g. military-technical and scientific) Europe was already ahead of the advanced countries of Asia, whereas in others (such as the level of craftsmanship) it still lagged behind. But in general, we denote this period as “catching up divergence”. All of the above said has allowed the authors to express their own opinion on the reasons for the Britain leadership in that period. Although Britain was clearly the leader at that point, but in that period one also observes a number of important processes that can be identified as pan-European (including the development of military technology, trade, science, pan-European commercial and industrial crises of the second half of the eighteenth century, and the beginning of the demographic transition). From this perspective, the authors clearly trace in the Industrial Revolution the result of the collective achievements of different European societies.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    With some exceptions that will be mentioned specially below.

  2. 2.

    Note that in his turn Goldstone based himself on the survey produced by Li and Soylu (2004).

  3. 3.

    “There are no precise data on the scale of the decline between the period before 1348 and the population nadir reached during the first half of the fifteenth century, but a loss of 30–40 % is corroborated by local studies in Piedmont and Tuscany, and in France, Spain, England, and Germany” (Livi-Bacci 2012: 44).

  4. 4.

    It should be also noted (though it goes beyond the scope of our research) that all three picks of the filling of the ecological niche, as well as their regression, were connected with the climate change (e.g., Flohn and Fantechi 1984; Мельянцев 1996: 85–88; Клименко 2009; Parker 2013).

  5. 5.

    Generally, by the end of the Middle Ages the West was superior to the East only in certain military, navigation and a few other technologies (e.g., Parker 1997), whereas in most respects the East was more developed than the West.

  6. 6.

    However, in the late seventeenth in France, under the pressure of manufacturers and sellers of silk and woolen cloth, Colbert imposed a total ban on production of cotton cloth as it rivaled strongly the former; in England (for the same reason) it was prohibited partially (Mantoux 1929; Чичеров 1965; Allen 2009; Аллен 2014). It is important, that in Europe the textile industry needed raw materials, while for silk and porcelain production there was a complete circle (from raw stuff to finish goods). Cotton seems to be the only popular article supplied by Asia in that time.

  7. 7.

    From 1750 to 1850, Britain raised its consumption of raw cotton from one thousand to 267 thousand metric tons (Mitchell 1978: 253). But by 1850 the rest of Europe also imported about 130 thousand metric tons more (Mitchell 1978: 253).

  8. 8.

    In this respect, the period from 1870 to 1990 seems to be to a certain extent a reflection of the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries. In the sixteenth-eighteenth centuries, one could observe a powerful hidden divergence between the West and the East which showed up after the 1800s. The period between 1870 and 1990 can be characterized as a period of hidden convergence which in the form of vector of the converging per capita GDP production started to show up only after the late 1980s.

  9. 9.

    In fact, the abovementioned statement of Goldstone in its full form looks as follows: “the only way forward is to abandon both the notion of Europe as having an inherent, durable advantage or superiority in some respect that goes back thousands of years, and the notion that there was no essential difference between Europe and other major civilizations until relatively late, around 1800” (Goldstone 2013: 59).

  10. 10.

    One of such reasons was a prohibition of slavery in Western Europe while there were comparable many slaves in eastern countries especially in the Near and Middle East.

  11. 11.

    A larger population density in Asia as compared to Europe was promoted by the fact that in Europe the share of arable lands was relatively larger, namely, 45 % of total territory compared to 23 % in Asia (Галич 1986: 188; Рябчиков 1976: 124, 342).

  12. 12.

    For example, “in England c. 1750, more than half the population engaged in wage labor either full-time or part time; farmers and freeholders in agriculture were only about a quarter of households. In Japan and China… a much smaller proportion of the population were laborers” (Goldstone 2007: 213).

  13. 13.

    In their turn, Huang’s calculations are based on Buck’s (1937: 314) data.

  14. 14.

    On the large role of trade in the Arab world see, for example, Abu-Lughod (1991), Goldstone (2009a).

  15. 15.

    In the East, especially in China, Mesopotamia, or Egypt sometimes the state could invest large amounts of money in the land amelioration, but since the state itself developed in a cyclic manner, the process of such improvements was not sustained and sometimes the irrigation amelioration declined completely. In the West, starting from the Modern Age, the investments in land or agricultural technology generally increased.

  16. 16.

    It is quite natural that there was an abundant evidence of the direct impact of the prohibitions that were spread in the seventeenth-century France during Colbert’s times (see Rayner 1964: 42–44; Малов 1994: 142–150) as well as in other parts of Europe in general. We also do not consider here the epoch of catching modernization in Europe and Japan in the second half of the nineteenth century, when industrialization (including the construction of railways and telegraph) was to a large extent directed and financed by the state (see, e.g., Supple 1976: 329–330, 340–351).

  17. 17.

    In the Southern Netherlands, half the population or even more lived in towns (Bruges, Ghent, and Antwerp), the share of the urban population was still larger in Northern Italy in the Po valley where Venice, Milan, and Genoa were situated (Blockmans 1989: 734). Such a high share of the urban population could be supported only by profitable trade. That is why its decline in the Italian Republics (as well as in the Southern Netherlands as a result of the destruction of Antwerp (the Spanish Fury) led to their transformation and stunted development.

  18. 18.

    With respect to the early (gunpowder) military revolution, one should note that the matter was rather ambiguous. The Ottoman Empire was among leaders in this sphere and produced a significant impact on its neighboring countries, both European and Eastern (Iran and India). But unlike Europe, the further development of military revolution failed there. Moreover, starting from the late eighteenth century first Turkey and later all other Oriental countries began to adopt the European achievements.

  19. 19.

    Kuran (2011) denotes the period between the sixteenth and eighteenth centuries as “the Long Divergence”. But in our opinion, this definition fails to reflect the actual significance of that period.

  20. 20.

    For example, in the first half of the eighteenth century, the ratio between goods and silver carried on the British vessels that traded with China (Port of Guangzhou) was 10–90 %, or at best 75–25 % (<Author-Query><!----></Author-Query>Симоновская and Юрьев 1974: 175; see also Чичеров 1965: 135. 139; Петров 1986: 171; Goldstone 2013).

  21. 21.

    This was observed by Eric Jones (1987) and David Landes (1998, 2006) and some other scholars.

  22. 22.

    Thus, having constructed a powerful and advanced navy in the fifteenth century, later China gave up developing it and the Chinese lost the skills of shipbuilding.

  23. 23.

    Not to be mixed with his nephew, the famous British historian Arnold Joseph Toynbee (1889–1975).

  24. 24.

    However, today assumption is that the term “industrial revolution” (la révolution industrielle) was introduced as early as in 1837 by the French economist Jerome-Adolphe Blanqui to describe the social and technological transformation that had occurred in Britain within the previous decades (Mokyr 1999: 4).

  25. 25.

    For example, in the sixteenth century, the average tonnage of ships increased tenfold in comparison with the fifteenth century (Чистозвонов 1991: 15).

  26. 26.

    Note also, that, according to Wrigley (1988), the industrial revolution is a transition from the organic economy (energy resource) to inorganic, from organic production to inorganic one (that is from the agrarian production with its usage of land, plants and animals to the usage of mineral resources). Wrigley implied steam energy, yet, generally speaking, water energy also refers to inorganic energy resources (as we will further show just this energy resource promoted the machinery phase of the industrial revolution in the USA). Thus, already from the fifteenth century, we observe an obvious transition to inorganic energy resources and during the subsequent centuries the distribution of these energy resources proceeded at impressive rates.

  27. 27.

    A bit earlier he also notes that the industrial revolution extended over 100 years and represented a gradual evolutionary process (Clark 2007: 232, 239), although unfortunately, he does not denote any landmarks in this process.

  28. 28.

    One can take the liberty to draw an analogу between the epoch of revolution and the period from the creation of the first samples of a new seminal invention in an inventor’s workshop to the creation of the first working production prototypes. And from this stage there can be a long way to the further large-scale implementation of the invention.

  29. 29.

    However, we should note that during 300 years (from the sixteenth to the eighteenth century) the Western Europe demonstrated a close to contemporary type of economic growth in the foreign trade averaging to 1.06 % per year (O’Rourke et al. 2010), which provided a basis for a transition to such a type of economic growth.

  30. 30.

    Nevertheless, one should make a distinction between “agricultural” mills, which grind grain, and “industrial” mills, which were devoted to what are now commonly thought of as industrial applications, such as fulling of cloth, forging iron, and sharpening tools (Lucas 2005), which were obviously less in number (Ibid.).

  31. 31.

    It is widely assumed that the Lateen sail was actually adopted from the Arab navigators who used it in the Indian Ocean and brought to the Mediterranean in the ninth century (see, e.g., Шумовский 2010).

  32. 32.

    Nevertheless, one should note that the non-farm sector of the world’s gross volume was primarily concentrated in Asia. According to Allen (2009), in 1750 the bulk of craft production was concentrated in China (33 % of global output) and the Indian subcontinent (25 %). This has two important implications: (1) The main amount of both general GDP and industrial GDP was concentrated mostly in Asian countries. (2) Therefore, as we have pointed out, the primary divergence was at the same time a catching up convergence.

  33. 33.

    For more details on the “production principle” notion see Grinin (2007, 2012a) and Grinin and Grinin (2013).

  34. 34.

    This is often connected with the point that Medieval West Europe was very effectively shielded from the invasions of the external barbarians in general and the nomadic world in particular (e.g., Crone 1989: 150).

  35. 35.

    This thesis is often ascribed to Max Weber. Note, however, that Max Weber himself opposed it very strongly: “… however, we have no intention whatever of maintaining such a foolish and doctrinaire thesis as that the spirit of capitalism… could have only arisen as the result of certain effect of the Reformation, or even that capitalism as an economic system is a creation of the Reformation” (Weber 1930 [1904]: 91). Hence, this thesis should be denoted as “pseudo-Weberian” rather than Weberian.

  36. 36.

    Note that Jack Goldstone (2007) convincingly proved the irrelevance of this factor.

  37. 37.

    However, later it involved the other European countries due the fast diffusion of innovations, the formation of the European market and maturing globalization.

  38. 38.

    The first wave of this migration was caused by the ban of cotton fabric production in France, whereas the second wave was produced by the abolition of the Edict of Nantes.

  39. 39.

    As has already been mentioned, the importation of such fabrics increased enormously. Hence, it is not surprising that the woolen and silk traders struggled to impose such restrictions, whereas the process of introduction and raising the import customs began already since 1660; however, the importation of the Indian fabrics continued to grow (Чичеров 1965: 141; Allen 2009), which necessitated the introduction of the total ban of those imports.

  40. 40.

    Even in 1850 the total power of the hydraulic engines in the cotton industry was 11,000 hp or approximately 13 % of the total power of all the engines (Lilley 1966).

  41. 41.

    Bishnupriya Gupta and Debin Ma arrive at rather similar conclusions: “Chinese real wages were far behind those in London or Amsterdam—only about 30–40 % of earning levels there in terms of purchasing power… Unskilled laborers in the major cities of China and Japan—poor as they were—had roughly the same standard of living as their counterparts in central and southern Europe for the larger part of the eighteenth century” (Gupta and Ma 2010: 272), whereas Mokyr notes that “high real wages may simply have reflected higher output per worker, not a cost disadvantage to labor utilization that was absent elsewhere” (Mokyr 2010: 270–271).

  42. 42.

    However, a very much attention is paid to this point by the institutionalist economic historians (North and Thomas 1973: 155–156; North 1981: 164–166; Chang 2001).

  43. 43.

    With the accession of the Tudor dynasty the patent system underwent a characteristic change. In place of the open letters for the furtherance of the national industry, we now find the Crown negotiating for the purpose of attracting skilled foreigners (for example, German armourers, Italian shipwrights and glass-makers, and French iron makers) (Hulme 1909). We also see that those monopolies were not without foreign precedents. Throughout Western Europe the new art of printing was being controlled and regulated by special licenses (Hulme 1909).

  44. 44.

    One of the important indicators for it is that in those years the number of steam engines in the British economy became equal to the number of the hydraulic engines—there were 160 thousand of each (Crafts 2004; Kanefsky 1979; Allen 2009).

  45. 45.

    See, e.g., Zinkina and Korotayev (2014).

  46. 46.

    The report quite adequately explained the exceptional success of the Americans in the production of machinery first of all by the acute shortage of workers in the country, the presence of a huge domestic market, high level of education and the widespread use of foreign experience (Болховитинов 1983: 215–216).

  47. 47.

    It appears appropriate to mention here some quantitative data. The greatest scale of the railway construction in Europe was observed between 1850 and 1870. During that period, the European railway network grew from 14 thousand miles up to 65 thousand miles (Mosse 1974: 23). And in the decade between 1857 and 1866 the world’s total railway increased by 75,000 km. Between 1860 and 1887, the telegraph network in Europe grew from 126,000 to 652,000 km and worldwide its length approached 1.5 million km, including 200,000 km of underwater lines (Мендельсон 1959, т. 2: 194).

  48. 48.

    Among the reasons one could mention a larger willingness to learn from the West than was found among the Chinese, as the Japanese traditionally borrowed much more from abroad, as was noted by the Japanese researchers (Ōkuma Shigenobu) already at the beginning of the twentieth century (Загорский 1991 : 68). Allen also points to a more creative use and adaptation of western technology to local conditions than in other modernizing countries in this period (Allen 2011 ).

  49. 49.

    Why did the flow of European capitals and technologies to Canada or Australia lead to their successful modernization, and why did not it produce the same result in Brazil or India? In the nineteenth century, Canada, Australia, India, and Brazil were turned into an agrarian and raw material appendages of Western Europe and the United States. This, however, did not prevent Canada and Australia to join the club of developed countries, while Brazil and India as a result of the processes of the Great Divergence found themselves among the Third World countries. What is the explanation? We will try to answer this question below in Appendix B to this book.

References

  • Abu-Lughod, J. (1991). Before European hegemony. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2005). The rise of Europe: Atlantic trade, institutional change and economic growth. American Economic Review, 95, 546–579.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail. New York, NY: Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Al-Hasan, A. Y., & Hill, D. R. (1991). Science and techniques in Islam. Paris: Unesco.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ali, W. (1999). The Arab contribution to Islamic art from the seventh to fifteenth centuries. Cairo: The American University of Cairo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2001). The great divergence in European wages and prices from the Middle Ages to the First World War. Explorations in Economic History, 38, 411–447.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2003). Was there a timber crisis in early modern Europe? In S. Cavaciocchi (Ed.), Economia e energia secc, XIII–XVII (pp. 469–482). Florence: Instituto Internazionale di Storia Economia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2007). Pessimism preserved: Real wages in the British industrial revolution (Working Paper No. 314). Department of Economics, Oxford: Oxford University

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2009). The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C. (2011). Global economic history: A very short introduction. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C., Bassino, J.-P., Ma, D., Moll-Murata, C., & van Zanden, J. L. (2005a). Wages, prices, and living standards in China, 1738–1925: In сomparison with Europe, Japan, and India (Working Paper No. 316). Department of Economics, Oxford: Oxford University

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C., Bengtsson, T., & Dribe, M. (2005b). Living standards in the past: New perspectives on well-being in Asia and Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. C., Bassino, J.-P., Ma, D., Moll-Murata, C., & van Zanden, J. L. (2011). Wages, prices, and living standards in China, Japan, and Europe, 1738–1925. Economic History Review, 64, 8–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amin, S. (2010). Global history—A view from the South. Oxford: Pambazuka.

    Google Scholar 

  • Apostolides, A., Broadberry, S., Campbell, B., Overton, M., & van Leeuwen, B. (2008). English agricultural output and labour productivity, 1250–1850: Some preliminary estimates. Retrieved March 21, 2012, from http://www.basvanleeuwen.net/bestanden/agriclongrun1250to1850.pdf

  • Armengaud, A. (1976). Population in Europe 1700–1914. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The industrial revolution 1700–1914 (pp. 22–76). London: Harvester.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armytage, W. H. G. (1961). A social history of engineering. London: Faber and Faber.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrighi, G. (1994). The long twentieth century: Money, power, and the origins of our times. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Artzrouni, M., & Komlos, J. (1985). Population growth through history and the escape from the Malthusian trap: A homeostatic simulation model. Genus, 41(3–4), 21–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ashtor, E. (1978). Underdevelopment in pre-industrial era. The case of declining economies. The Journal of European Economic History, 7(2–3), 285–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Aström, S. E. (1963). From cloth to iron. The Anglo-Baltic trade in the late seventeenth century. Part I. The growth, structure and organization of the trade. Helsinki: Centraltryckeriet.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bairoch, P. (1985). De jéricho à Mexico. Paris: Villes et economies dans l’histoire.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bairoch, P. (1992). Le Tiers-Monde dans l’impasse (IIIth ed.). Paris: Gallimard.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barkan, O., & McCarthy, J. (1975). The price revolution of the sixteenth century: A turning point in the economic history of the near east. International Journal of Middle East Studies, 6(1), 3–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benson, I., & Lloyd, J. (1983). New technology and industrial change: The impact of the scientific-technical revolution on labour and industry. London; New York, NY: Kogan Page; Nichols.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernal, J. D. (1965). Science in history (3rd ed.). New York, NY: Hawthorn Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blair, J., & Ramsay, N. (Eds.). (1991). English medieval industries: Craftsmen, techniques, products. London: Hambledon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaut, J. (1993). The colonizer’s model of the world. New York, NY: Guilford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaut, J. (2000). Eight Eurocentric historians. New York, NY: Guilford.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloch, M. (1935). Avènement et conquêtes du moulin à eau. Annales d’histoire économique et sociale, 7, 538–563.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blockmans, W. T. (1989). Preindustrial Europe. Theory and Society, 18(5), 733–755.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bogart, D., Drelichman, M., Gelderblom, O., & Rosenthal, J.-L. (2010). State and private institutions. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 70–95). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bolich, S. (2005). The history of farming machinery. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borsch, S. J. (2004). Environment and population: The collapse of large irrigation systems reconsidered. Comparative Studies of Society and History, 46(3), 451–468.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borsch, S. J. (2005). The black death in Egypt and England. Cairo: The American University of Cairo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boxer, C. R. (1965). The Dutch seaborne empire 1600–1800. New York, NY: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady, T. A., Jr. (1997). The rise of merchant empires 1400–1700. In J. D. Tracy (Ed.), The political economy of merchant empires: State power and world trade 1350–1759 (pp. 117–160). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, F. (1973). Capitalism and material life, 1400–1800. New York, NY: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, F. (1981–1984). Civilization and capitalism, 15th–18th Century (3 vols). New York, NY: Harper and Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, F. (1985). La dynamique du capitalism. Paris: Flammarion.

    Google Scholar 

  • Braudel, F., & Spooner, F. (1980). Prices in Europe from 1450 to 1750. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wils (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries (Vol. IV, pp. 378–486). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Broadberry, S., & O’Rourke, K. H. (Eds.). (2010). The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buck, J. L. (1937). Land utilization in China: Statistics. Shanghai: University of Nanking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bulter-Thomas, V. (1994). The economic history of Latin America since independence. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burns, R. I. (1996). Paper comes to the West, 800–1400. In U. Lindgren (Ed.), Europäische Technik im Mittelalter. 800 bis 1400. Tradition und Innovation (4th ed., pp. 413–422). Berlin: Gebr. Mann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cameron, R. (1989). A concise economic history of the world: From Paleolithic times to present. New York, NY: Hill Wang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantrell, J., & Cookson, G. (Eds.). (2002). Henry Maudslay and the pioneers of the machine age. Stroud: Tempus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cao, S. (2001). Zhongguo renkou shi: Qing shiqi [A history of Chinese population: The Qing period] (Vol. 5). Shanghai: Fudan daxue chubanshe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carus-Wilson, E. (1941). An industrial revolution of the thirteenth century. Economic History Review, 11, 39–60.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carus-Wilson, E. (1987). The woolen industry. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 6148–6692). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chamberlain, J. E. (2006). Horse: How the horse has shaped civilizations. New York, NY: BlueBridge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler, T. (1987). Four thousand years of urban growth: An historical census. Lewiston, NY: Edwin Mellen Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C.-L. (1962). The income of the Chinese gentry. Seattle, WA: University of Washington Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J. (2001). Intellectual property rights and economic development: Historical lessons and emerging issues. Journal of Human Development, 2, 287–309.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chase-Dunn, C. (1998). Global formation: Structures of the world-economy. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chase-Dunn, C., Kawano, Y., & Brewer, B. (2000). Trade globalization since 1795: Waves of integration in the world-system. American Sociological Review, 65(1), 77–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chase-Dunn, C., & Lerro, B. (2013). Social change: Globalization from the Stone Age to the present. Boulder, CO: Paradigm Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaunu, P. (1979). European expansion in the later Middle Ages. Amsterdam: North Holland Pub. Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chaunu, P. (1984). La civilization de l’Europe classique. Paris: Arthaud.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chirot, D. (1985). The rise of the West. American Sociological Review, 50, 181–195.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chirot, D. (1986). Social change in the modern era. San Diego, CA: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christian, D. (2004). Maps of time: An introduction to big history. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chu, S. C., & Liu, K.-C. (Eds.). (1994). Li Hung-chang and China’s early modernization. Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (1965). Guns, sails and empires: Technological innovation and the early phases of European expansion, 1400–1700. New York, NY: Minerva Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (Ed.). (1972). The Fontana economic history of Europe: The Middle Ages (Vol. 1). London: Collins/Fontana.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (1976). Introduction. The industrial revolution: 1700–1914. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The industrial revolution: 1700–1914 (pp. 7–21). London – New York, NY: Harvester Press – Barnes and Noble.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (1978). The economic history of world population. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cipolla, C. M. (1981). Before the industrial revolution: European society and economy, 1000–1700. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, C. (1968). Population growth and land use. New York, NY: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2001). Farm wages and living standards in the industrial revolution: England, 1670–1869. Economic History Review, 54(3), 477–505.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2003). Agricultural wages. In J. Mokyr (Ed.), The Oxford encylopedia of economic history (Vol. 1, pp. 59–65). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2005). The condition of the working class in England, 1209–2004. Journal of Political Economy, 113(6), 1307–1340.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, G. (2007). A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Collins, J. B., & Taylor, K. L. (Eds.). (2006). Early modern Europe. Issues and interpretations. Malden, MA: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crafts, N. F. R. (2004). Steam as a general purpose technology: A growth accounting perspective. Economic Journal, 114(495), 338–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Craig, L., & Garcia-Iglesias, C. (2010). Business Cycles. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 122–146). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crone, P. (1989). Pre-industrial societies. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cuno, K. (1985). Landholding, society and economy in rural Egypt: 1740–1850. Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, I. N. R. (1996). Europe: A history. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, I. N. R. (2001). Heart of Europe: The past in Poland’s present. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, L. J. (1998). Fleet fire: Thomas Edison and the pioneers of the electric revolution. New York, NY: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Moor, T., & van Zanden, J. L. (2010). Girl power: the European marriage pattern and labour markets in the North Sea region in the late medieval and early modern period. The Economic History Review, 63(1), 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debeir, J.-C., Deléage, J.-P., & Hémery, D. (1991). In the servitude of power: Energy and civilization through the age. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Long, J. B., & Shleifer, A. (1993). Princes and merchants: European city growth before the industrial revolution. Journal of Law and Economics, 36, 671–702.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dennison, T., & Simpson, J. (2010). Agriculture. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 147–163). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diffie, B., & Winius, G. D. (1977). Foundations of the Portuguese empire, 1415–1580. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dobb, M. (1963b). Studies in the development of capitalism. New York, NY: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downing, B. (1992). The military revolution and political change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duffy, M. (Ed.). (1980). The military revolution and the state, 1500–1800. Exeter: University of Exeter Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Durand, J. D. (1960). The population statistics of China, A.D. 2–1953. Population Studies, 13, 209–256.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dutton, H. (1984). The patent system and inventive activity during the industrial revolution: 1750–1852. Manchester, NH: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elvin, M. (1973). The pattern of the Chinese past. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Epstein, S. A. (2009). An economic and social history of later medieval Europe: 1000–1500. Cambridge: University of Cambridge Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, N. (2011). Civilization: The west and the rest. New York, NY: The Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feuerwerker, A. (1969). The Chinese economy ca. 1870–1911. Ann-Arbor, MI: Center for Chinese Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feuerwerker, A. (1980). Economic trends in the late Ch’ing empire, 1800–1911. In J. K. Fairbank & K. C. Liu (Eds.), The Cambridge history of China 1980. Part 2: Late Ch’ing 1800–1911 (Vol. 11, pp. 1–69). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, D. (1989). The price revolution: A monetary interpretation. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flinn, M. W. (1959). Timber and the advance of technology. Annals of Science, 15, 109–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flohn, H., & Fantechi, R. (Eds.). (1984). The climate of Europe: Past, present and future. Dordrecht: D. Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flower, R. (1972). Napoleon to Nasser. The story of modern Egypt. London: Tom Stacey.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forbes, R. J. (1956). Power. In C. Singer et al. (Eds.), A history of technology. The Mediterranean civilizations and the Middle Ages, c. 700 B.C. to c. A.D. 1500 (Vol. 2, pp. 601–606). London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, A. G. (1979). Dependent accumulation and underdevelopment. New York, NY: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, A. G. (1998). ReOrient: Global economy in the Asian age. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gellner, E. (1984). Nations and nationalism. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gieysztor, A. (1987). Trade and industry in Eastern Europe before 1200. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 474–524). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gille, B. (1969). The problems of power and mechanization. In M. Daumas (Ed.), A history of technology and invention: Progress through the ages. The origins of technological civilization (Vol. 1) (E. B. Hennessy, Trans.). New York, NY: Crown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimpel, J. (1992). The medieval machine: The industrial revolution of the Middle Ages (2nd ed.). London: Pimlico.

    Google Scholar 

  • Le Goff, J. (1988). Medieval civilization, 400–1500. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldschmidt, A. (2004). Modern Egypt. The formation of a nation state. Cambridge, MA: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1984). Urbanization and inflation: Lessons from the English price revolution of the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. The American Journal of Sociology, 89(5), 1122–1160.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1988). East and West in the seventeenth century: Political crises in Stuart England, Ottoman Turkey and Ming China. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 30, 103–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (1991). Revolution and rebellion in the early modern world. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2000). The rise of the West – or not? A revision to socio-economic history. Sociological Theory, 18(2), 173–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2002). Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: Rethinking the ‘rise of the West’ and the British industrial revolution. Journal of World History, 13, 323–389.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2007). Unraveling the mystery of economic growth. A review of Gregory Clark’s ‘A farewell to alms: A brief economic history of the world’. World Economics, 8(3), 207–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2008a). Capitalist origins, the advent of modernity, and coherent explanation. A response to Joseph M. Bryant. Canadian Journal of Sociology/Cahiers canadiens de sociologie, 33(1), 119–133.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2008b). Why Europe? The rise of the West in global history, 1500–1850. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2009a). Why Europe? The rise of the West in world history: 1500–1850. New York, NY: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2009b). The origins of capitalism and the rise of the West by Mielants, E. H. The British Journal of Sociology, 60(3), 651–653.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2011). Rezension zu: Ferguson, Niall: Civilization. The west and the rest. London 2011. Retrieved from http://hsozkult.geschichte.hu-berlin.de/rezensionen/id=16383

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2012a). Is Islam bad for business? Perspectives on Politics, 10(1), 97–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2012b). Divergence in cultural trajectories: The power of the traditional within the early modern. In D. Porter (Ed.), Comparative early modernities 1100–1800 (pp. 165–192). New York, NY: Palgrave-Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2013). The origins of western superiority—A comment on modes of meta-history and Duchesne’s Indo-Europeans. Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History, 4(1), 54–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goody, J. (1996). The east in the west. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goody, J. (2004). Capitalism and modernity: The great debate. Cambridge, MA: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gould, J. D. (1972). Economic growth in history. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A. (2006). Institutions and the path to the modern economy: Lessons from medieval trade. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2007). Production revolutions and periodization of history: A comparative and theoretic-mathematical approach. Social Evolution and History, 6(2), 75–120.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2008a). Early state, developed state, mature state: Statehood evolutionary sequence. Social Evolution and History, 7(1), 67–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2011a). The evolution of statehood: From early state to global society. Saarbrücken: Lambert Academic Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2012a). Macrohistory and globalization. Volgograd: Uchitel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2012b). State and socio-political crises in the process of modernization. Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History, 3(1), 124–157.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2012c). New foundations of international system or why do states lose their sovereignty in the age of globalization? Journal of Globalization Studies, 3(1), 3–38.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E. (2013). The tiger and the dragon. Development models and perspectives of India and China. Journal of Globalization Studies, 4(1), 5–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E., & Grinin, A. L. (2013). Macroevolution of technology. In L. E. Grinin & A. V. Korotayev (Eds.), Evolution: Development within big history, evolutionary and world-system paradigms (pp. 143–178). Volgograd: Uchitel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2006). Political development of the world system: A formal quantitative analysis. In P. Turchin, L. Grinin, V. de Munck, & A. Korotayev (Eds.), History and mathematics: Historical dynamics and development of complex societies (pp. 63–114). Moscow: KomKniga.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2012a). Global urbanization and political development of the world system. In L. E. Grinin, I. V. Ilyin, & A. V. Korotayev (Eds.), Globalistics and globalization studies (pp. 28–78). Volgograd: Uchitel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2013a). Globalization and the world system evolution. In L. E. Grinin & A. V. Korotayev (Eds.), Evolution: Development within big history, evolutionary and world-system paradigms. Yearbook (pp. 30–68). Volgograd: Uchitel Publishing House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L. E., & Korotayev, A. V. (2013b). The origins of globalization. In J. Sheffield, A. Korotayev, & L. Grinin (Eds.), Globalization: Yesterday, today, and tomorrow (pp. 1–29). Litchfield Park, AZ: Emergent Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grinin, L., Markov, A., & Korotayev, A. (2013). On similarities between biological and social evolutionary mechanisms: Mathematical modeling. Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History, 4(2), 185–228.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gunn, G. C. (2003). First globalization: The Eurasian exchange, 1500 to 1800. Lanham, MD: Rowman and Littlefield.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gupta, B., & Ma, D. (2010). Europe in an Asian mirror: The great divergence. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 264–285). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hale, J. (1993). The civilization of Europe in the renaissance. London: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, A. R. (1980). Scientific method and the progress of techniques. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wilson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries (Vol. IV, pp. 96–154). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, J. A. (1985). Powers and liberties: The causes and consequences of the rise of the West. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammersley, G. (1957). Crown woods and the exploitation in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Bulletin of the Institute of Historical Research, 30, 136–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, A. H. (1951). Business cycles and national income. New York, NY: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hart, M. T. (1989). Cities and statemaking in the Dutch Republic: 1580–1680. Theory and Society, 18(5), 663–687.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatcher, J. (1993). The history of the British coal industry. Before 1700: Towards the age of coal (Vol. 1). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heaton, H. (1948). Economic history of Europe. New York, NY: Harper and Brothers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Held, D., McGrew, A., Goldblatt, D., & Perraton, J. (1999). Global transformations: Politics, economics and culture. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hellemans, A., & Bunch, B. (1988). The timetables of science. New York, NY: Simon and Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herlihy, D. (1997). The black death and the transformation of the West. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, C. (1955). The English revolution, 1640 (3rd ed.). London: Lawrence and Wishart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobson, J. M. (2004). The Eastern origins of Western civilization. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgen, M. (1939). Domesday water mills. Antiquity, 13, 261–279.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, P. C. C. (2002). Development or involution in eighteenth-century Britain and China? A review of Kenneth Pomeranz’s ‘The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world Economy’. The Journal of Asian Studies, 61(2), 501–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hulme, E. W. (1909). The early history of the English patent system, with a list of monopoly grants for new industries and inventions, A.D. 1554–1603. Boston, CO: Little, Brown, and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunter, R. (1999). Egypt under the Khedives, 1805–1879. From household government to modern bureaucracy. Cairo: The American University in Cairo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inkster, I. (1991). Science and technology in history: An approach to industrial development. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Israel, J. I. (1995). The Dutch Republic, its rise, greatness, and fall: 1477–1806. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issawi, C. (1947). Egypt: An economic and social analysis. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issawi, C. (1980). Europe, the Middle East and the shift in power: Reflections on a theme by Marshall Hodgson. Comparative Studies in Society and History, 22, 487–504.

    Google Scholar 

  • Issawi, C. (1991). Technology, energy, and civilization: Some historical observations. International Journal of Middle East Studies, 23(3), 281–289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, E. L. (1987a). The European miracle (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, G. P. (1987b). Building in stone in medieval Western Europe. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 763–787). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, J. R. (1996). The Anglo-Dutch wars of the seventeenth century. London: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jonnes, J. (2003). Empires of light: Edison, Tesla, Westinghouse, and the race to electrify the world. New York, NY: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, A. (1955). Europe in the sixteenth century: 1494–1598. London: Rivingtons.

    Google Scholar 

  • van de Kaa, D. J. (1987). Europe’s second demographic transition. Population Bulletin, 42(1), 1–57.

    Google Scholar 

  • van de Kaa, D. J. (1994). The second demographic transition revisited: Theories and expectations. In G. C. N. Beets, J. C. van den Brinkel, R. L. Cliquet, G. Dooghe, & J. de Jong (Eds.), Population and family in the low countries (pp. 81–126). Amsterdam: Swets and Zeitlinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanefsky, J. (1979). The diffusion of power technology in British industry (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Exeter).

    Google Scholar 

  • Kehoe, A. B. (1992). North American Indians: A comprehensive account (2nd ed.). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, C. (2010). Furs, fish, and ivory: Medieval Norsemen at the arctic fringe. Journal of the North Atlantic, 3, 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan, B. Z., & Sokoloff, K. L. (1998). Patent institutions, industrial organization, and early technological change: Britain and the United States, 1790–1850. In M. Berg & K. Bruland (Eds.), Technological revolutions in Europe. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger, C. P., & Aliber, R. Z. (2005). Manias, panics, and crashes: A history of financial crises. Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, P. (2005). The production and consumption of bar iron in early modern England and Wales. Economic History Review, 58, 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirkland, E. C. (1961). Industry comes of age, business, labor, and public policy, 1860—1897. New York, NY: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kögel, T., & Prskawetz, A. (2001). Agricultural productivity growth and escape from the Malthusian trap. Journal of Economic Growth, 6, 337–357.

    Google Scholar 

  • Komlos, J., & Artzrouni, M. (1990). Mathematical investigations of the escape from the Malthusian trap. Mathematical Population Studies, 2, 269–287.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2005). A compact macromodel of world system evolution. Journal of World-Systems Research, 11(1), 79–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. V. (2006). The world system history periodization and mathematical models of socio-historical processes. In L. Grinin, V. de Munck, & A. Korotayev (Eds.), History and mathematics: Analyzing and modeling global development (pp. 39–98). Moscow: KomKniga/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2007). Compact mathematical models of world system development, and how they can help us to clarify our understanding of globalization processes. In G. Modelski, T. Devezas, & W. R. Thompson (Eds.), Globalization as evolutionary process: Modeling global change (pp. 133–160). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2008). Globalization and mathematical modeling of global development. In L. E. Grinin, D. D. Beliaev, & A. V. Korotayev (Eds.), Hierarchy and power in the history of civilizations: Political aspects of modernity (pp. 225–240). Moscow: LIBROCOM/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2009). Compact mathematical models of the world system development and their applicability to the development of local solutions in third world countries. In J. Sheffield (Ed.), Systemic development: Local solutions in a global environment (pp. 103–116). Litchfield Park, AZ: ISCE Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. (2012). Globalization and mathematical modeling of global development. In L. Grinin, I. Ilyin, & A. Korotayev (Eds.), Globalistics and globalization studies (pp. 148–158). Moscow – Volgograd: Moscow State University – Uchitel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. V., & Grinin, L. E. (2006). Urbanization and political development of the world system: A comparative quantitative analysis. In P. Turchin, L. Grinin, V. de Munck, & A. Korotayev (Eds.), History and mathematics: Historical dynamics and development of complex societies (pp. 115–153). Moscow: KomKniga/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. V., & Grinin, L. E. (2012a). Global urbanization and political development of the world system. In L. Grinin, I. Ilyin, & A. Korotayev (Eds.), Globalistics and globalization studies (pp. 28–78). Moscow – Volgograd: Moscow State University – Uchitel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A. V., & Grinin, L. E. (2013). Urbanization and political development of the world system. Entelequia, 15, 197–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., & Khaltourina, D. (2006). Introduction to social macrodynamics: Secular cycles and millennial trends in Africa. Moscow: URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., & Komarova, N. (2004). A new mathematical model of pre-industrial demographic cycle. In M. G. Dmitriev & A. P. Petrov (Eds.), Mathematical modeling of social and economic dynamics (pp. 157–163). Moscow: Russian State Social University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Malkov, A., & Khaltourina, D. (2006a). Introduction to social macrodynamics: Compact macromodels of the world system growth. Moscow: KomKniga/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Malkov, A., & Khaltourina, D. (2006b). Introduction to social macrodynamics: Secular cycles and millennial trends. Moscow: KomKniga/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Zinkina, J., & Bogevolnov, J. (2011a). Kondratieff waves in global invention activity (1900–2008). Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 78, 1280–1284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Zinkina, J., Bogevolnov, J., & Malkov, A. (2011b). Global unconditional convergence among larger economies after 1998? Journal of Globalization Studies, 2(2), 25–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Zinkina, J., Bogevolnov, J., & Malkov, A. (2011c). Unconditional convergence among larger economies. In D. Liu (Ed.), Great powers, world order and international society: History and future (pp. 70–107). Changchun: The Institute of International Studies – Jilin University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Korotayev, A., Zinkina, J., Kobzeva, S., Bogevolnov, J., Khaltourina, D., Malkov, A., et al. (2011d). A trap at the escape from the trap? Demographic-structural factors of political instability in modern Africa and West Asia. Cliodynamics: The Journal of Theoretical and Mathematical History, 2(2), 276–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kremer, M. (1993). Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 681–716.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuran, T. (2011). The long divergence: How Islamic law held back the Middle East. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. S. (1966). Modern economic growth. Rate, structure and spread. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lal, D. (1988). The Hindu equilibrium (Vol. 1). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. (1998). The wealth and poverty of nations. New York, NY: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Landes, D. S. (2006). Why Europe and the West? Why not China? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2), 3–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • La Porta, R., Lopez de Silanez, F., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1997). Legal determinants of external finance. Journal of Finance, 52, 1131–1150.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M. S. (2011). The Sakoku edicts and the politics of Tokugawa hegemony. Amherst, NY: Cambria Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lee, J., & Wang, F. (1999). One quarter of humanity. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Léon, P. (1977). Histoire économique et sociale du monde (Vol. I). Paris: A. Colin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R. (1995). The second demographic transition in Western countries: An interpretation. In K. O. Mason & A. Jensen (Eds.), Gender and family change in industrialized countries (pp. 17–62). Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lesthaeghe, R., & van de Kaa, D. (1986). Twee demografische transities? In R. Lesthaeghe & D. van de Kaa (Eds.), Groei of Krimp (pp. 9–25). Deventer: Van Loghum-Dlaterus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, C., & Soylu, U. (2004). Innovations in the Chinese history of science: Compiled from Joseph Needham’s science and civilization in China. In P. Bernholz & R. Vaubel (Eds.), Political competition, innovation and growth in the history of Asian civilizations (pp. 91–95). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman, V. (Ed.). (1999). Beyond binary histories: Reimagining Eurasia to c. 1830. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lieberman, V. (2003). Strange parallels: Southeast Asia in global context, c. 800–1830. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lilley, S. (1966). Men, machines and history: The story of tools and machines in relation to social progress. New York, NY: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lilley, S. (1976). Technological progress and the industrial revolution, 1700–1914. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The industrial revolution, 1700–1914: The Fontana economic history of Europe (Vol. 3, pp. 187–254). New York, NY: The Harvest Press Limited; Barnes and Noble.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, K.-C., & Smith, R. G. (1980). The military challenge: The north-west and the coast. In J. K. Fairbank & K. C. Liu (Eds.), The Cambridge history of China 1980. Part 2: Late Ch’ing 1800–1911 (Vol. 11, pp. 1–69). Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Livi-Bacci, M. (2012). A concise history of world population. Chichester: Wiley-Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, A. R. (2005). Industrial milling in the ancient and medieval worlds. A survey of the evidence for an industrial revolution in medieval Europe. Technology and Culture, 46(1), 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlup, F., & Penrose, E. (1950). The patent controversy in the nineteenth century. The Journal of Economic History, 10(1), 1–29.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod, C. (1988). Inventing the industrial revolution: The English patent system, 1660–1800. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod, C. (2009). Patents for invention: Setting the stage for the British industrial revolution? EMPIRIA. Revista de Metodología de Ciencias Sociales, 18, 37–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacLeod, C., & Nuvolari, A. (2007). Inventive activities, patents, and early industrialization: A synthesis of research issues, Mimeo.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (1989). Dutch income in and from Indonesia: 1700–1938. Modern Asian Studies, 23(4), 645–670.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (1991). Dynamic forces in capitalist development. New York, NY: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, A. (2001). Monitoring the world economy: A millennial perspective. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Maddison, А. (2010). World population, GDP and per capita GDP, A.D. 1–2008. Retrieved from http://www.ggdc.net/maddison

  • Man, J. (2002). The Gutenberg revolution: The story of a genius and an invention that changed the world. London: Headline Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, M. (1986). The source of social power: A history of power from the beginning to AD 1760 (Vol. 1). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mantoux, P. (1929). The industrial revolution in the eighteenth century: An outline of the beginnings of the modern factory system in England (M. Vernon, Trans.). London: Jonathan Cape.

    Google Scholar 

  • Masefield, G. B. (1980). Crops and livestock. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wilson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe (The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Vol. IV, pp. 276–307). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathias, P. (1979). Leisure and wages in theory and practice. In P. Mathias (Ed.), The transformation of England (pp. 148–167). London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. (2007). The bourgeois virtues. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McEvedy, C., & Jones, R. (1978). Atlas of population history. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeill, H. W. (1963). The rise of the West: A history of the human community. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeill, W. H. (1982). The pursuit of power. Technology, armed force and society since A.D. 1000. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeill, W. H. (1998). Plagues and peoples. New York, NY: Anchor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ménard, C., & Shirley, M. M. (Eds.). (2008). Handbook of new institutional economics. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mielants, E. H. (2007). The origins of capitalism and the rise of the West. Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minghinton, W. (1976). Patterns of demand, 1750–1914. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The industrial revolution: 1700–1914 (pp. 77–186). London: Harvester.

    Google Scholar 

  • Minsky, H. P. (2005). Induced investment and business cycles. Cheltenham: Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, B. R. (1978). European historical statistics. New York, NY: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1990a). Twenty-five centuries of technological change. London: Harwood Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (1999). Editor’s introduction: The new economic history and the industrial revolution. In J. Mokyr (Ed.), The British industrial revolution: An economic perspective (pp. 1–84). Boulder, CO: Westview Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2002). The gifts of Athena: Historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J. (2010). The enlightened economy: An economic history of Britain, 1700–1850. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr, J., & Foth, H.-J. (2010). Understanding growth in Europe, 1700–1870: Theory and evidence. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 7–42). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Monro, J. H. (1994). Patterns of trade, money, and credit. In T. A. Brady, H. A. Oberman, & J. D. Tracy (Eds.), Handbook of European history, 1400–1600 (Vol. 1, pp. 147–195). Leiden: Brill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mosse, W. E. (1974). Liberal Europe. The age of bourgeois realism, 1848–1875. London: Thames and Hudson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mumford, L. (1934). Technics and civilization. New York, NY: Harcourt, Brace & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Musson, A. E., & Robinson, E. (1969). Science and technology in the industrial revolution. Manchester: Manchester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Needham, J. (1981). Science in traditional China. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nef, J. U. (1932). The rise of the British coal industry. London: George Routledge and Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nef, J. U. (1987). Mining and metallurgy in medieval civilisation. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 693–762). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nehru, J. (1982). The discovery of India. New Delhi: Jawaharlal Nehru Memorial Fund, Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Thomas, R. P. (1973). The rise of the Western world: A new economic history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1981). Structure and change in economic history. New York, NY: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1993, December 9). Economic performance through time. Lecture to the memory of Alfred Nobel. Retrieved from http://nobelprize.org/economics/laureates/1993/north-lecture.html

  • North, D. (1996). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge: University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, M. (1994). The money and it’s history from the Middle Ages to the present. Munich: Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2002). The gifts of Athena. Historical origins of the knowledge economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., & Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and social orders: A conceptual framework for interpreting recorded human history. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C., & Weingast, B. R. (1989). Constitutions and commitment: Evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. Journal of Economic History, 49, 803–832.

    Google Scholar 

  • O’Rourke, K. H., Prados de la Escosura, L., & Daudin, G. (2010). Trade and empire. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 96–121). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Overton, M. (1996). Agricultural revolution in England: The transformation of the agrarian economy, 1500–1850. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Owen, R. (1969). Cotton and the Egyptian economy, 1820–1914: A trade and development. Oxford: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pacey, A. (1990). Technology in world civilization. A thousand-year history. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pamuk, S., & van Zanden, J.-L. (2010). State and private institutions. In S. Broadberry & K. H. O’Rourke (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of modern Europe: 1700–1870 (Vol. 1, pp. 217–234). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G. (1997). Europe and the wider world 1500–1700: The military balance. In J. D. Tracy (Ed.), The political economy of merchant empires. State power and world trade 1350–1759 (pp. 161–195). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, J. (1996). The military revolution: Military innovation and the rise of the West, 1500–1800 (2nd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, J. (2013). Global crisis: War, climate change and catastrophe in the seventeenth century. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parry, J. H. (1980). Transport and trade roots. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wilson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries (Vol. IV, pp. 155–222). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, P. L. (1978). Industrial entrepreneurship and management in Great Britain. In P. Mathias & M. M. Postan (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe. The industrial economies: Capital, labour and enterprise. Part 1: Britain, France, Germany, and Scandinavia (Vol. VII, pp. 180–230). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearson, M. N. (1997). Merchants and states. In J. D. Tracy (Ed.), The political economy of merchant empires. State power and world trade 1350–1759 (pp. 41–116). New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, K. G. (1988). Pre-industrial economic growth. Social organization and technological progress in Europe. New York, NY: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pirenne, H. (1920–1932). Histoire de Belgique (Vols. I–VII). Bruxelles: H. Lamertin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pomeranz, K. (2000). The great divergence: China, Europe, and the making of the modern world economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pomeranz, K. (2002). Beyond the East–West binary: Resituating development paths in the eighteenth-century world. Journal of Asian Studies, 61(2), 539–590.

    Google Scholar 

  • Popov, V. (2014). Mixed fortunes. An economic history of China, Russia, and the West. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Porter, D. (Ed.). (2012). Comparative early modernities 1100–1800. New York, NY: Palgrave-Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Postan, M. (1987). The trade of medieval Europe: The north. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 168–305). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raychaudhuri, T., & Habib, I. (Eds.). (1982). The Cambridge economic history of India: c. 1200–c. 1750 (Vol. 1). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rayner, R. M. (1964). European history, 1648–1789. New York, NY: David McKay Company, Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reinert, E. S. (2007). How rich countries got rich and why poor countries stay poor. London: Constable.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rich, E. E. (1980). Colonial settlement and its labour problems. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wilson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe (The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, Vol. IV, pp. 308–377). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rietbergen, P. J. A. N. (2002). A short history of the Netherlands. From prehistory to the present day (5th ed.). Amersfoort: Bekking.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roekholt, R. (2004). A short history of Amsterdam. Amersfoort: Bekking and Blitz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenthal, J.-L., & Wong, R. B. (2011). Before and beyond divergence: The politics of economic change in China and Europe. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell, J. C. (1972). Population in Europe. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The Fontana economic history of Europe: The Middle Ages (Vol. 1, pp. 25–71). Glasgow: Collins/Fontana.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell, P. E. (2000). Prince Henry ‘the Navigator’: A life. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saliba, G. (2007). Islamic science and the making of the European Renaissance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanderson, S. K. (1995). Social transformations. A general theory of historical development. Cambridge: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanderson, S. K. (1999). Macrosociology (4th ed.). New York, NY: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Al-Sayyid Marsot, A. L. (2004). A short history of modern Egypt. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, M. F. (1989). A new view of economic growth. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherrat, A. (1995). Reviving the grand narrative: Archaeology and long-term change. Journal of European Archaeology, 3(1), 1–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singer, C. (1941). A short history of science to the nineteenth century. London: Clarendon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smil, V. (1994). Energy in world history. Bolder, CO: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snooks, G. D. (1996). The dynamic society. Exploring the sources of global change. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snooks, G. D. (1997). The ephemeral civilization. Exploding the myth of social evolution. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • So, A. Y. (1984). The process of incorporation into the capitalist world-system: The case of China in the nineteenth century. Review, 8(1), 91–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • So, A. Y. (2012). The East Asian path of development. In J. Salvatore, S. J. Babones, & C. Chase-Dunn (Eds.), Routledge handbook of world-systems analyses (pp. 71–79). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spufford, P. (1987). Coinage and currency. In M. M. Postan & E. Miller (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: Trade and industry in the Middle Ages (Vol. II, pp. 788–873). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Supple, B. (1976). The states and the industrial revolution, 1700–1914. In C. M. Cipolla (Ed.), The industrial revolution: 1700–1914. The Fontana economic history of Europe (Vol. 3, pp. 301–357). New York, NY: The Harvest Press Limited; Barnes and Noble.

    Google Scholar 

  • Steinmann, G., Prskawetz, A., & Feichtinger, G. (1998). A model on the escape from the Malthusian trap. Journal of Population Economics, 11, 535–550.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R. (1976). Crisis around 2005 A.D.? A technology-population interaction model. General Systems, 21, 137–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R. (1979). People, skills, and resources: An interaction model for world population growth. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 13, 13–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Taagepera, R. (2014). A world population growth model: Interaction with Earth’s carrying capacity and technology in limited space. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 82, 34–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tignor, R. (1966). Modernization and British colonial rule in Egypt, 1882–1914. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tooke, T. A. (1838–1857). A history of prices and the state of the circulation. London: Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toynbee, A. (1927[1884]). Lectures on the industrial revolution of the eighteenth century in England: Popular addresses, notes, and other fragments. London: Rivingtons.

    Google Scholar 

  • Toynbee, A. (1956 [1884]). The industrial revolution. Boston: Beacon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tracy, J. D. (Ed.). (1997). The political economy of merchant empires. State power and world trade 1350–1759. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trevelyan, G. M. (1978). English social history. A survey of six centuries, Chaucer to Queen Victoria. London: Longmans.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsirel, S. V. (2004). On the possible reasons for the hyperexponential growth of the Earth population. In M. G. Dmitriev & A. P. Petrov (Eds.), Mathematical modeling of social and economic dynamics (pp. 367–369). Moscow: Russian State Social University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tugan-Baranovsky, M. I. (1954). Periodic industrial crises. Annals of the Ukrainian Academy of Arts and Sciences in the United States, 3(3), 745–802.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turchin, P. (2003). Historical dynamics: Why states rise and fall. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turchin, P. (2005). War and peace and war: Life cycles of imperial nations. New York, NY: Pi Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turchin, P., & Korotayev, А. (2006). Population density and warfare: A reconsideration. Social Evolution and History, 5(2), 121–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Turchin, P., & Nefedov, S. (2009). Secular cycles. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tylecote, R. F. (2002). A history of metallurgy (2nd ed.). London: Maney Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Unger, R. W. (2008). The ship in the medieval economy, 600–1600. New York, NY: ACLS Humanities E-Book.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, J. (1994). The industrial revolution and the industrious revolution. Journal of Economic History, 54(2), 249–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, J. (2008). The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Vries, J., & van der Woude, A. (1997). The first modern economy. Success, failure, and perseverance of the Dutch economy, 1500–1815. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vries, P. (2013). Escaping poverty: The origins of modern economic growth. Vienna: W&R Unipress.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallerstein, I. (1974, 1980, 1988). The modern world-system, 3 vols. New York, NY: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Watson, A. M. (1981). A medieval green revolution. In A. L. Udovitch (Ed.), The Islamic Middle East, 700–1900: Studies in economic and social history (pp. 29–58). Princeton: The Darwin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1930[1904]). The Protestant ethic and the spirit of capitalism. New York, NY: The Citadel Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Wee, H. (1990). Structural changes in European long-distance trade, and particularly in the re-export trade from south to north, 1350–1850. In J. D. Tracy (Ed.), The rise of merchant empires: Long-distance trade in the early modern world, 1350–1750 (pp. 14–33). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Wee, H. (1994). Urban industrial development in the low countries during the late Middle Ages and early modern times (Working Papers in Economic History, No. 179). Canberra: Australian National University.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L. (1962). Medieval technology and social change. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, L., Jr. (1978). Medieval religion and technology: Collected essays. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wigelsworth, J. R. (2006). Science and technology in medieval European life. Westport, CT: Greenwood Publishing Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wikander, Ö. (2000). Industrial applications of water-power. In Ö. Wikander (Ed.), Handbook of ancient water technology (pp. 401–412). Leiden: Brill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, C. H. (1980). Trade, society and the state. In E. E. Rich & C. H. Wilson (Eds.), The Cambridge economic history of Europe: The economy of expanding Europe in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries (Vol. IV, pp. 487–576). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodbury, R. S. (1961). History of the Lathe to 1850. Cleveland, OH: Society for the History of Technology.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wong, R. B. (1997). China transformed: Historical change and the limits of the European experience. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, D. C. (2001). The history of China. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wrigley, E. A. (1988). Continuity, chance, and change. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zhao, W. & Xie, S.-Z. (1988). History of Chinese population. Peking: People’s Publisher (in Chinese).

    Google Scholar 

  • Zinkina, J., & Korotayev, A. (2014). Explosive population growth in tropical Africa: Crucial omission in development forecasts (emerging risks and way out). World Futures, 70(4), 271–305.

    Google Scholar 

  • Аллен, Р. (2014). Британская промышленная революция в глобальной картине мира. Москва: Изд-во Института Гайдара.

    Google Scholar 

  • Бабинцева, Н. С. (1982). Индустриализация в развивающихся странах. Ленинград: Ленинградский Государственный Университет.

    Google Scholar 

  • Бакс, К. (1986). Богатства земных недр. Москва: Прогресс.

    Google Scholar 

  • Барг, М. А. (1993). Введение. В: Мильская, Л. Т., и Рутенбург, В. И. (ред.), История Европы: в 8 т. Т. 3. Oт средневековья к новому времени (конец XV – первая половина XVII в.) (с. 11–15). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Белоусова, К. А. (2004). Египет. В: Родригес, А. М. (ред.), Новая история стран Азии и Африки XVI–XIX века. Часть 2 (с. 126–153). Москва: Владос.

    Google Scholar 

  • Боголюбов, А. Н. (1988). Творения рук человеческих. Естественная история машин. Москва: Знание.

    Google Scholar 

  • Болховитинов, Н. Н. (1983). Основные тенденции социально-экономического развития (конец XVIII в. – 1860 г.). В: Болховитинов, Н. Н. (ред.), История США. Т. 1. 1607–1877 (с. 205–234). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Близнец, И. А. (2001). Интеллектуальная собственность и закон. Теоретические вопросы. Том III. Актуальные проблемы авторских и смежных прав. Москва: Институт международного права и экономики имени А. С. Грибоедова

    Google Scholar 

  • Белькинд, Л. Д. (1964). Томас Альва Эдисон. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Бобровников, А. В. (2004). Макроциклы в экономике стран Латинской Америки. Москва: Институт Латинской Америки РАН.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ванина, Е. Ю. (1991). Средневековое городское ремесло Индии XIII–XVIII вв. Москва: Наука, Главная редакция восточной литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Вирт, М. (1877). История торговых кризисов в Европе и Америке. Санкт-Петербург: Знание.

    Google Scholar 

  • Вишневский, А. Г. (1976). Демографическая революция. Москва: Статистика.

    Google Scholar 

  • Вишневский, А. Г. (2005). Избранные демографические труды. Т. 1. Демографическая теория и демографическая история. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Галич, З. Н. (1986). К сравнительной характеристике базисных структур Европы и Азии в канун промышленной революции. В: Рейснерб, Л. И., и Славный, Б. И. (отв. ред.), Исторические факторы общественного воспроизводства в странах Востока (с.184–216). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гиббинс, Г. (1898). Промышленная история Англии. Санкт-Петербург: Издательство О. Н. Поповой.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гинцберг, Л. И. (1960). Основные черты экономического развития капиталистического мира в 70–90-х годах. В: Губер, А. А. (ред.), Всемирная история. Т. 7 (с. 41–50). Москва: Издательство социально-экономической литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гордон, Л. С., & Поршнев, Б. Ф. (1972). Абсолютизм XVII века. В: Манфред, А. З. (ред.), История Франции. Т. 1 (с. 235–284). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е. (2006). Трансформация государственной системы Египта в XIX – начале XX в.: от развитого государства к зрелому. В: Логунов, А. П. (ред.), Египет, Ближний Восток и глобальный мир: сб. науч. статей (с. 123–132). Москва: Кранкэс.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е. (2007). Политические процессы в османском Египте XVI–XVIII вв. и теория развитого государства. История и современность, 1, 38–84.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е. (2010). Государство и исторический процесс: Эволюция государственности. От раннего государства к зрелому (Изд. 2-е, испр.). Москва: Либроком.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е. (2012). Кондратьевские волны, технологические уклады и теория производственных революций. В: Акаев, А. А., Гринберг, Р. С., Гринин, Л. Е., Коротаев, А. В., и Малков, С. Ю. (отв. ред.), Кондратьевские волны: Аспекты и перспективы (с. 222–262). Волгоград: Учитель.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е., & Коротаев, А. В. (2009а). О некоторых особенностях социально-политического развития османского Египта. Восток, 1, 46–62.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е., & Коротаев, А. В. (2009б). О типологических характеристиках государственности в османском Египте XVI–XIX вв (к постановке проблемы). Восток, 3, 35–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. E., & и Коротаев, А. В. (2012). Циклы, кризисы, ловушки современной Мир-Системы. Исследование кондратьевских, жюгляровских и вековых циклов, глобальных кризисов, мальтузианских и постмальтузианских ловушек. Москва: Издательство ЛКИ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Гринин, Л. Е., Малков, С. Ю., Гусев, В. А., & и Коротаев, А. В. (2009). Некоторые возможные направления развития теории социально-демографических циклов и математические модели выхода из «мальтузианской ловушки». В: Малков, С. Ю., Гринин, Л. Е., и Коротаев, А. В. (ред.), История и Математика: процессы и модели (с. 134–210). Москва: ЛИБРОКОМ/URSS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Джинчарадзе, В. З. (1973). Экономическая история США. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Джонс, Р. (1937). Экономические сочинения. Ленинград: Соцэкгиз.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ефимов, А. В. (1955). Очерки истории США. 1492–1870 гг. Москва: Государственное учебно-педагогическое издательство Министерства просвещения РСФСР.

    Google Scholar 

  • Загорский, Ф. Н. (1960). Очерки по истории металлорежущих станков до середины XIX в. Издательство АН СССР: Москва – Ленинград.

    Google Scholar 

  • Загорский, А. В. (1991). Япония и Китай. Пути общественного развития в оценке японской историографии. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Загорский, Ф. Н., & и Загорская, И. М. (1989). Джеймс Несмит. 1808–1890. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Зеленев, Е. И. (2003). Государственное управление, судебная система и армия в Египте и Сирии (XVI – начало XX века). Санкт-Петербург: Издательство Санкт-Петербургского университета.

    Google Scholar 

  • Зингер, Е. М. (1981). Между полюсом и Европой. Москва: Мысль.

    Google Scholar 

  • Кирилин, В. А. (1986). Страницы науки и техники. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Клименко, В. В. (2009). Климат. Непрочитанная глава истории. Москва: МЭИ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Куликов, В. В. (1979). Общественно-экономическая формация. В: Румянцев, А. М. (ред.), Экономическая энциклопедия. Политическая экономия. T. 3 (с. 146–149). Москва: Советская энциклопедия.

    Google Scholar 

  • Лавровский, В. М. (Ред.). (1973). Сборник документов по истории Английской буржуазной революции XVII века. Москва: Высшая школа.

    Google Scholar 

  • Лавровский, В. М., & и Барг, М. А. (1958). Английская буржуазная революция XVII века. Некоторые проблемы Английской буржуазной революции 40-х годов XVII века. Москва: Издательство социально-экономической литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ламан, Н. К. (1989). Развитие техники обработки металлов давлением с древнейших времен до наших дней. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Литаврина, Э. Э. (1972). Испанский экономист XVI в. Томас Меркадо о причинах и сущности «революции цен». В: Удальцова, З. В. (ред.), Европа в средние века: экономика, политика, культура (с. 249–259). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Малов, В. Н. (1994). Европейский абсолютизм второй половины XVII – начала XVIII века. В: Барг, М. А. (ред.), История Европы. Т. 4. Европа Нового времени (с. 138–179). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мейер, М. С. (1978). К характеристике экономической жизни городов Османской империи в XVII веке. В: Чистозвонов, А. Н. (отв. ред.), Проблемы генезиса капитализма (с. 242–276). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мельянцев, В. А. (1996). Восток и Запад во втором тысячелетии: экономика, история и современность. Москва: Издательство Московского Государственного Университета.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мендельсон, Л. А. (1959). Теория и история экономических кризисов и циклов. Т. 1–3. Москва: Издательство социально-экономической литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мильская, Л. Т., & и Рутенбург, В. И. (ред.). (1991). История Европы: в 8 т. Т. 3. Oт средневековья к новому времени (конец XV – первая половина XVII в). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Миткевич, В. Ф. (Ред.). (1936). Очерки истории техники докапиталистических формаций. Москва – Ленинград: Издательство АН СССР.

    Google Scholar 

  • Михайлов, О. В. (2007). Защита интеллектуальной собственности и патентоведение (тексты лекций). Учебное пособие. Казань: Издательство Казанского государственного технологического университета.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мокир, Дж. (2012). Дары Афины. Исторические истоки экономики знаний. Москва: Издательство Института Гайдара.

    Google Scholar 

  • Моллаева, Д. Г. (1993). Патентное право Великобритании, унификация его с европейским патентным правом: Автореферат диссертации на соискание ученой степени кандидата юридических наук. Москва.

    Google Scholar 

  • Мугрузин, А. С. (1986). Роль природного и демографического факторов в динамике аграрного сектора средневекового Китая (к вопросу о цикличности докапиталистического воспроизводства). В: Рейснер, Л. И., Славный, Б. И. (отв. ред.), Исторические факторы общественного воспроизводства в странах Востока (с.11–44). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Назарчук, А. В. (2006). Влияние книгопечатания на развитие протестантизма в Европе. Новая и новейшая история, 4, 79–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • Нарочницкий, А. Л. (1973). Международные отношения на Дальнем Востоке во время «опиумных войн» и тайпинского восстания (30–60-е годы XIX в.) В: Нарочницкий, А. Л. и др. (ред.), Международные отношения на Дальнем Востоке. Том 1. С конца XVI в. до 1917 г (с. 58–123). Москва: Мысль.

    Google Scholar 

  • Непомнин, О. Е. (2005). История Китая: Эпоха Цин. XVII – начало XX века. Москва: Восточная литература.

    Google Scholar 

  • Непомнин, О. Е., & и Меньшиков, В. Б. (1986). Китай: синтез традиционного и современного (середина XIX – середина XX в.). В: Рейснер, Л. И., и Славный, Б. И. (отв. ред.), Исторические факторы общественного воспроизводства в странах Востока (с. 45–79). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Орд-Хьюм, А. (1980). Вечное движение. Москва: Знание.

    Google Scholar 

  • Петров, А. М. (1986). Внешняя торговля древней и средневековой Азии в отечественном востоковедении (обзор литературы и попытка нового подхода к исследованию проблемы). В: Рейснер, Л. И., и Славный, Б. И. (отв. ред.), Исторические факторы общественного воспроизводства в странах Востока (с. 149–183). Москва: Наука, Главная редакция восточной лит-ры.

    Google Scholar 

  • Райерсон, С. Б. (1963). Основание Канады. Москва: Издательство иностранной литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Рейснер, Л. И. (1986). Генезис системы «наука – техника– производство» в западноевропейском регионе в XVI–XVIII вв. и оценка перспектив этого процесса в восточных обществах эпохи НТР. В: Рейснер, Л. И., и Славный, Б. И. (отв. ред.), Исторические факторы общественного воспроизводства в странах Востока (с. 111–148). Москва: Наука, Главная редакция восточной литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Рябчиков, А. М. (Отв. ред.). (1976). Природные ресурсы зарубежных территорий Европы и Азии. Москва: Мысль.

    Google Scholar 

  • Сванидзе, А. А. (1990). Производительные силы общества Западной Европы в V–XV вв. В: Удальцова З. В., Карпов, С. П. (ред.), Т. 1. История средних веков (с. 402–416). Москва: Высшая школа.

    Google Scholar 

  • Симоновская, Л. В., & и Юрьев, М. Ф. (ред.) (1974). История Китая с древнейших времен до наших дней. Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Сказкин, С. Д. (1968). Очерки истории западноевропейского крестьянства в Средние века. Москва: МГУ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Смилянская, И. М., & и Родионов, М. А. (2004). Арабские страны в 1840–1870-е годы. В: Алаев, Л. Б., и др. (ред.), Кн. 1. История Востока. 4: Восток в новое время (конец XVIII – начало XIX в.) (с. 372–403). Москва: Восточная литература.

    Google Scholar 

  • Толстихин, О. Н. (1981). Земля в руках людей. Москва: Недра.

    Google Scholar 

  • Трахтенберг, И. А. (1963). Денежные кризисы (1821–1938 гг.). Москва: Издательство АН СССР.

    Google Scholar 

  • Туган-Барановский, М. (2008 [1894]). Промышленные кризисы в современной Англии, их причины и влияние на народную жизнь. Санкт-Петербург: Тип. ИН Скороходова.

    Google Scholar 

  • Фостер, У. (1955). Очерк политической истории Америки. Москва: Издательство иностранной литературы.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ханке, Х. (1976). Люди, корабли, океаны. Москва: Судостроение.

    Google Scholar 

  • Цейтлин, Е. А. (1940). Очерки истории текстильной техники. Гизлегпром: Москва – Ленинград.

    Google Scholar 

  • Чистозвонов, А. Н. (1978). Генезис капитализма в Нидерландах. В: Чистозвонов, А. Н. (ред.), Проблемы генезиса капитализма (с. 71–177). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Чистозвонов, А. Н. (1991). Развитие производительных сил в западноевропейских странах в XVI – первой половине XVII в. В: Удальцова, З. В., Карпов, С. П. (ред.), История средних веков. T. 2 (с. 12–19). Москва: Высшая школа.

    Google Scholar 

  • Чичеров, А. И. (1965). Экономическое развитие Индии перед английским завоеванием (ремесло и торговля в XVI–XVIII в.). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Шейпак, А. А. (2009). История науки и техники. Материалы и технологии. Ч. 1. Москва: МГИУ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Шемякин, И. Н. (ред.). (1978). Экономическая история СССР и зарубежных стран. Москва: Высшая школа.

    Google Scholar 

  • Шумовский, Т. (2010). Арабы и море. Москва: Марджани.

    Google Scholar 

  • Якубский, В. А. (1975). Проблемы аграрной истории позднесредневековой Польши. Ленинград: Изд-во ЛГУ.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ястребицкая, А. Л. (1993а). Германия. В: Мильская, Л. Т., Рутенбург, В. И. (ред.), История Европы: в 8 т. Т. 3. От Средневековья к Новому времени (c. 68–80). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ястребицкая, А. Л. (1993б). Материальная культура и образ жизни в Европе на исходе средневековья. В: Мильская, Л. Т., и Рутенбург, В. И. (ред.), История Европы: в 8 т. Т. 3. От Средневековья к Новому времени (c. 16–39). Москва: Наука.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Grinin, L., Korotayev, A. (2015). Great Divergence and the Rise of the West. In: Great Divergence and Great Convergence. International Perspectives on Social Policy, Administration, and Practice. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-17780-9_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics