Skip to main content

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Statistics ((LNS,volume 214))

  • 1705 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter demonstrates how majorization theory provides a powerful tool for the study of robustness of many important models in economics, finance, econometrics, statistics, risk management, and insurance to heavy-tailedness assumptions. The majorization relation is a formalization of the concept of diversity in the components of vectors. Over the past decades, majorization theory, which focuses on the study of this relation and functions that preserve it, has found applications in disciplines ranging from statistics, probability theory, and economics to mathematical genetics, linear algebra, and geometry (see Marshall et al. 2011, and the references therein).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The functions ϕ p have the same form as measures of diversification considered in Bouchaud and Potters (2004), Chap. 12, p. 205.

  2. 2.

    Throughout the chapter, we interpret the negative values of risks X as a risk holder’s losses. This interpretation is similar to that in Artzner et al. (1999) and Christoffersen (2012) and is in contrast to Chap. 2 in McNeil et al. (2005) who interpret positive values of risks X as losses. All the results presented and discussed in the chapter can be easily reformulated in terms of interpretation of positive values of the risks as losses (see Ibragimov 2009a,b, for details).

  3. 3.

    Here, as usual, \(\Gamma (r)\) and B(a, b) denote the Gamma and Beta functions.

  4. 4.

    This section draws upon material from the following articles: Ibragimov (2009b) “Portfolio diversification and VaR under thick-tailedness”, Quantitative Finance, Vol. 9, No. 5, 565–580, and Ibragimov (2009a) “Heavy-tailed densities,” “The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,” Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume, Palgrave Macmillan, reproduced with permission of Palgrave Macmillan. The full published version of this publication is available from: http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2009_H000191.

  5. 5.

    In particular, the results Theorems 2.1.1 and 2.1.2 and their analogues under dependence provided by Theorems 5.1 and 5.2 in Ibragimov (2009b) substantially generalize the riskiness analysis for uniform (equal weights) portfolios of independent stable risks considered, among others, in the papers by Fama (1965b), Samuelson (1967a) and Ross (1976): These theorems demonstrate that the formalization of portfolio diversification on the basis of majorization pre-ordering allows one to obtain comparisons of riskiness for portfolios of heavy-tailed and possibly dependent risks with arbitrary, rather than equal, weights.

  6. 6.

    From the proof of Theorems 2.1.1 and 2.1.2 and this property it follows that the theorems continue to hold for convolutions of distributions from the classes \(\overline{\mathcal{C}\mathcal{S}\mathcal{L}\mathcal{C}}\) and \(\underline{\mathcal{C}\mathcal{S}}\) with Cauchy distributions S 1(σ).

  7. 7.

    See also Ibragimov et al. (2014) for the analysis of the interplay of dependence modeled using different copula structures, the degree of heavy-tailedness and the values of loss probabilities and disaster levels in problems of portfolio diversification in VaR frameworks.

  8. 8.

    Proschan’s (1965) results are an example of many results and inequalities in probability whose formulation or proofs are based on majorization theory (for further examples of such inequalities, see Chap. 3 in Marshall et al. 2011).

  9. 9.

    The main results in Proschan (1965) are reviewed in Sect. 12.J in Marshall et al. (2011). The work by Proschan (1965) is also presented, in a rearranged form, in Sect. 11 of Chap. 7 in Karlin (1968). Peakedness results in Proschan (1965) and Karlin (1968) are formulated for “PF2 densities,” which is the same as “log-concave densities.”

  10. 10.

    The analysis of tail probabilities of linear combinations of r.v.’s is related to the field of probability and moment inequalities in probability and statistics (see, among others, Sect. 12 in de la Peña and Giné 1999; de la Peña et al. 2003; Hansen 2015; Ibragimov and Ibragimov 2008; Ibragimov and Sharakhmetov 19972002; Marshall et al. 2011; Nze and Doukhan 2004; Utev 1985, and the references therein for a number of results in the field and their statistical and econometric applications).

  11. 11.

    This section draws upon material from the following articles: Ibragimov (2007) “Efficiency of linear estimators under heavy-tailedness: Convolutions of α-symmetric distributions,” Econometric Theory, Volume 23(3), pp. 501–517 (2010) \(\copyright\) Cambridge University Press, reproduced with permission, and Ibragimov (2009a) “Heavy-tailed densities,” “The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics,” Eds. Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume, Palgrave Macmillan, reproduced with permission of Palgrave Macmillan. The full published version of this publication is available from: http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2009_H000191.

  12. 12.

    This definition of truncation moves probability mass to the edges of the distributions. The results in this section continue to hold for the more commonly used truncations XI( | X | ≤ a) which move probability mass to the center.

  13. 13.

    That is, in the case of an absolutely continuous risk Z, P(Z ≤ VaR q (Z)) = q.

  14. 14.

    See Cummins (2006), Jaffee (2006a), and Jaffee and Russell (2006) for recent discussions and references to the literature. OECD (2005a) and OECD (2005b) discuss government interventions around the world to reactivate terrorism insurance. Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan (2006) discuss the specific issue of terrorism insurance in the United States.

  15. 15.

    There is generally open access to scientific forecasts of natural disasters, much of it provided by governments. Terrorists may be more strategic in their choice of targets, but this does not create a moral hazard on the part of those purchasing terrorism insurance (unless the terrorists particularly target insured properties).

  16. 16.

    These data are from the Insurance Information Institute; see http://iii.org/media/industry/.

  17. 17.

    Insurance is unique among U.S. financial services in that it is regulated in the United States only at the state level. The structure of a catastrophe insurance market is well illustrated by California’s earthquake risk market. As of 2005, 70 % of the coverage was provided by the California Earthquake Authority, an entity created by the State of California following the 1994 Northridge quake. With no major quakes since then, private insurers have slowly reentered the market, now representing about 30 % of the market. However, still only 35 private insurance groups are offering California earthquake coverage (based on annual written premiums of USD 1 million or more). Furthermore, the top 5, 10, and 20 firms represent 46, 66, and 89 % of the total private market, respectively.

  18. 18.

    We assume that a third party, perhaps the government, covers the excess losses to policy holders. This avoids the complications of any impact on policyholder demand.

  19. 19.

    Here, in line with the previous discussion on reduced strategy space, \(\tilde{q}_{m}\) does not need to be conditioned on the participation choices \(q_{m^{{\prime}}}\) of agents m  = 1, , m − 1. This is the case as the equilibrium mapping \(q = \mathcal{E}(p) \in \{ 0, 1\}^{M}\) is known, so \(q_{m^{{\prime}}}\) is uniquely implied by p in equilibrium.

  20. 20.

    For example, in a calibration to earthquake insurance (see Ibragimov et al. 2009), we arrive at nondiversification trap arising for annual insurance premiums, λ, between USD 1,840 and USD 2,300 per household. Below USD 1,840, the only equilibrium is the nondiversification equilibrium, and above USD 2,300, the only equilibrium is the full-diversification equilibrium. The range of λ for which a nondiversification trap arises is thus about 20 % of the premium—i.e., (2,300–1,840)/2,340. With other parameter values, we have derived ranges from a few percent up to an order of magnitude.

  21. 21.

    The moment magnitude is almost the same as the Richter magnitude, M R, for M ≤ 6. 5, but provides a more accurate measure for earthquakes of larger magnitudes.

  22. 22.

    This is the moment magnitude version of the celebrated Gutenberg–Richter exponential law for the Richter magnitude.

  23. 23.

    Although for very high levels, physical arguments imply that there has to be an upper bound on the energy released; see Knopoff and Kagan (1977), and Kagan and Knopoff (1984). However, even if there is an upper bound, say at M = 10 to 11, this still leads to an approximate Pareto law for over 15 magnitudes of energy release. The upper bound is well beyond the limited liability threshold of most insurance markets and is therefore not crucial for our trap argument.

  24. 24.

    This estimate may be somewhat outdated, as building structures nowadays may be stronger. However, this does not change our general conclusions, only the constants in the formulae (personal communication with William L. Ellsworth, Chief Scientist, Western Region Earthquake Hazards Team, United States Geological Survey).

  25. 25.

    1. 10 ≈ 1. 84 × 0. 6.

  26. 26.

    Other estimates for the relation are available—e.g., in Bakun et al. (2003). However, as with the strength of building structures, they are qualitatively similar and will not change our main conclusions (personal communication with William L. Ellsworth, Chief Scientist, Western Region Earthquake Hazards Team, United States Geological Survey).

  27. 27.

    0. 3 ≈ 1. 10∕3. 7, 0. 76 ≈ 1. 10∕1. 44.

  28. 28.

    0. 6 ≈ 1. 10∕(3. 7∕2), 1. 5 ≈ 1. 10∕(1. 44∕2).

  29. 29.

    Our analysis applies to banks, but more broadly to general financial intermediaries, like pension funds, insurance companies, and hedge funds.

  30. 30.

    Circulant topological structures have been used in the economics literature to provide a simple spatial “distance” metric without discontinuities, see, e.g., the discussion in Hennessy and Lapan (2009) and the references therein.

  31. 31.

    We focus on multivariate normal risks, for tractability. Similar results arise with other, thin-tailed, individual risks, e.g., Bernoulli distributions, although the analysis becomes more complex, because other distribution classes are not closed under portfolio formation so the central limit theorem needs to be incorporated into the analysis.

  32. 32.

    For review and discussion of models with common shocks and modeling approaches for spatially dependent economic and financial data, see, among others, Conley (1999), Andrews (1993), Ibragimov and Walden (2007), and Ibragimov (2009b).

  33. 33.

    A Toeplitz matrix A = Toeplitz N [a N+1, a N+2, , a −1, a 0, a 1, , a N−2, a N−1], is an N × N matrix with the elements given by (A) ij  = a ji , 1 ≤ i ≤ N, 1 ≤ j ≤ N. A Toeplitz matrix is banded if (A) ij  = 0 for large | ji | , corresponding to a i  = 0 for indices i that are large by absolute value. When a i  = 0 if i < −k or i > m, for k < N − 1 or m < N − 1, we use the notation \(a_{-k},a_{-k+1},\ldots,\underline{a_{0}},\ldots,a_{m-1},a_{m}\) to represent the whole sequence generating the Toeplitz matrix. For example, the notation \(\mathbf{A} = \mbox{ Toeplitz}_{N}[a_{-1},\underline{a_{0}}]\) then means that A ii  = a 0, A i, i−1 = a −1, and that all other elements of A are zero. For an N × N Toeplitz matrix, if a Nj  = a j , then the matrix is, in addition, circulant. See Horn and Johnson (1990) for more on the definition and properties of Toeplitz and circulant matrices.

  34. 34.

    As we shall see, our approach leads to very tractable formulas. An alternative approach for introducing more complex correlation structures than the standard multivariate normal one is to use copulas, which may also lead to heavy-tailed portfolio distributions.

  35. 35.

    We allow for short-selling. In the proof, we show that the optimal portfolio does not involve short-selling, so we could equivalently have permitted only nonnegative portfolios, c ∈ R + N.

  36. 36.

    In Ibragimov et al. (2010), equilibrium premiums are derived in a model with multiple risk factors and risk-averse agents. The general model, however, is quite intractable, and the simplifying assumptions in this section allow us to carry through a more complete study of the role of risk distributions.

  37. 37.

    It may be optimal, if possible, for the owners of the intermediary to infuse more capital even if losses exceed k, to keep the option of generating future profits alive. Equivalently, they may be able to borrow against future profits. Taking such possibilities into account would increase the point of default to a value higher than k, but would qualitatively not change the results, since there would always be some realized loss level beyond which the intermediary would be shut down even with such possibilities.

  38. 38.

    This is not a critical assumption. Alternatively, we could have assumed that the regulator anticipates whether the individual intermediaries will trade risks, and adjusts the VaR requirements accordingly.

  39. 39.

    It is easy to show that λ ∈ [0, T], and that λ is increasing in δ and T.

  40. 40.

    This follows trivially, since 1 − q M  = P( i ξ i  > MK) ≥ P(∩ i { −ξ i  > K}) = (1 − q)M.

  41. 41.

    This also follows trivially, since 1 − q M  ≥ (1 − q)M and therefore, if q ≥ q M , then \(\frac{1+\delta q} {1+\lambda (1-q)^{M}} \geq \frac{1+\delta q} {1+\lambda (1-q_{M})} \geq \frac{1+\delta q_{M}} {1+\lambda (1-q)^{M}}\).

  42. 42.

    The debt overhang problem arises in recapitalizing a bank because the existing shareholder ownership is diluted while some of the cash inflow benefit accrues as a credit upgrade for the existing bondholders and other bank creditors. The agency problems arise because larger capital ratios provide management greater incentive to carry out risky investments that raise the expected value of compensation but may reduce expected equity returns; for further discussion, see Kashyap et al. (2008). While the tax shield benefit of debt is valuable for the banking industry, it is not necessarily welfare-enhancing for society.

  43. 43.

    The efficiency costs of capital requirements can be mitigated by setting the requirements in terms of contingent capital in lieu of balance sheet capital. One mechanism is based on bonds that convert to capital if bankruptcy is threatened (Flannery 2005), but that instrument is not particularly directed to systemic risk. Kashyap et al. (2008) take the contingent capital idea a step further by requiring banks to purchase “capital insurance” that provides cash to the bank if industry losses, or some comparable aggregate trigger, hits a specified threshold. This mechanism may reduce or eliminate the costs that are otherwise created by bankruptcy, but it does not eliminate the negative externality that creates the systemic risk.

  44. 44.

    It is important to note that AIG wrote its CDS contracts from its Financial Products subsidiary, which was chartered as a savings and loan association and not as an insurance firm. Indeed, AIG also owns a monoline mortgage insurer, United Guaranty, but this subsidiary was not the source of the losses that forced the government bailout.

  45. 45.

    The terms “reservation prices” and “valuations” are used as synonyms in this section, in accordance with the well-established tradition in the bundling literature.

  46. 46.

    The arguments for the results in this section are based on peakedness, majorization and VaR comparison results for heavy-tailed distributions discussed in Sects. 2.1.3 and 2.1.4.

  47. 47.

    From Theorems 2.1.1 and 2.1.2 it further follows that the regularity condition is also satisfied for moderately heavy-tailed valuations, but it does not hold for extremely heavy-tailed valuations. Therefore, Chakraborty’s analysis cannot be applied if consumers’ valuations are extremely heavy-tailed.

  48. 48.

    In particular, the assumptions are satisfied for valuations with a finite support \([\underline{v},\overline{v}]\) distributed as the truncation XI( | Xμ |  < h), h > 0, of an arbitrary random variable X with a log-concave density symmetric about \(\mu = (\underline{v} + \overline{v})/2\), where \(h = (\overline{v} -\underline{v})/2\) and I(⋅ ) is the indicator function (see also Remark 2 in An 1998).

  49. 49.

    Clearly, in the case of discretely distributed valuations X i , i ∈ M, consumers unanimously prefer \(\mathcal{B}_{1}\) to \(\mathcal{B}_{2}\) ex ante if each of them prefers \(\mathcal{B}_{1}\) to \(\mathcal{B}_{2}\) for all but a finite number of realizations of their stand-alone valuations.

  50. 50.

    From the proof of the results in this section it follows that they continue to hold in the case of arbitrary loss functions ρ(x, y) = ψ( | xy | ), where ψ is nonnegative and increasing on R +.

  51. 51.

    By Proposition 4 in JR, in the model of demand-driven innovation and spatial competition over time involving the choice of informational gathering effort z in addition to the choice of output y, larger firms always invest more in information if the function G is convex (G″ > 0). Thus, under this condition, investment z into gathering information in JR is secondary with respect to persistence results comparing to y. One should note that, according to empirical studies, there is a positive relationship between R&D expenditures and firm size, that suggests that G is indeed convex (see Kamien and Schwartz 1982, and the discussion following Proposition 4 in JR).

  52. 52.

    In JR, the proposition is formulated for the Poisson distribution π 0. The argument for the distributions π j , j = 1, 2, is completely similar to that case.

Bibliography

  • Acharya, V. (2009). A theory of systemic risk and design of prudent bank regulation. Journal of Financial Stability, 5, 224–255.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adams, W. J., & Yellen, J. L. (1976). Commodity bundling and the burden of monopoly. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 90, 475–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adrian, T., & Brunnermeier, M. (2011). CoVar. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report no. 348. Available at http://www.newyorkfed.org/research/staff_reports/sr348.pdf.

  • Agarwal, R., & Gort, M. (1996). The evolution of markets and entry, exit and survival of firms. Review of Economics and Statistics, 78, 489–498.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, F., & Gale, D. (2000). Financial contagion. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • An, M. Y. (1998). Logconcavity versus logconvexity: A complete characterization. Journal of Economic Theory 80, 350–369.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Andrews, D. W. K. (1993). Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica, 61(4), 821–856. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2951764.

  • Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M., & Heath, D. (1999). Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance, 9, 203–228.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Audretsch, D. B. (1991). New firm survival and the technological regime. Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, 441–450.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., & Stachurski, J. J. (2006). Poverty traps. In P. Aghion & S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagnoli, M., & Bergstrom, T. (2005). Log-concave probability and its applications. Economic theory, 26, 445–469.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (1999). Bundling information goods: Pricing, profits and efficiency. Management Science, 45, 1613–1630.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000a). Aggregation and disaggregation of information goods: Implications for bundling, site licensing and micropayment systems. In D. Hurley, B. Kahin & H. Varian (Eds.), Proceedings of Internet Publishing and Beyond: The Economics of Digital Information and Intellectual Property. Cambridge, MA: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakos, Y., & Brynjolfsson, E. (2000b). Bundling and competition on the internet. Marketing Science, 19, 63–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bakun, W. H., Johnston, A. C., & Hopper, M. G. (2003). Estimating locations and magnitudes of earthquakes in eastern North American from Modified Mercalli intensities. Bulletin of the Seismological Society of America, 93, 190–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2004). Economic growth. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berger, J. O. (1985). Statistical decision theory and Bayesian analysis. New York: Springer.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, B. S. (1983). Nonmonetary effects of the financial crisis in the propagation of the great depression. American Economic Review, 73, 257–276.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickel, P. J., & Lehmann, E. L. (1975a). Descriptive statistics for nonparametric models. I. Introduction. Annals of Statistics, 3, 1038–1044.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bickel, P. J., & Lehmann, E. L. (1975b). Descriptive statistics for nonparametric models. II. Location. Annals of Statistics, 3, 1045–1069.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bouchaud, J.-P. and Potters, M. (2004). Theory of financial risk and derivative pricing: From statistical physics to risk management (2nd edn.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Box, G. E. P., & Tiao, G. C. (1973). Bayesian inference in statistical analysis. Reading/London/Don Mills: Addison-Wesley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M. (2009). Deciphering the liquidity and credit crunch 2007–2008. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 23, 77–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brunnermeier, M., & Pedersen, L. H. (2009). Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 2201–2238.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caballero, R., & Krishnamurthy, A. (2008). Collective risk management in a flight to quality episode. Journal of Finance, 63, 2195–2230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carlin, B. P., & Louis, T. A. (2000). Bayes and empirical Bayes methods for data analysis. London: Chapman & Hall.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, S., LaTourrette, T., Chow, B. G., Jones, G. S., & Martin, C. (2005). Distribution of losses from large terrorist attacks under the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act. Santa Monica, Calif: Rand Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakraborty, I. (1999). Bundling decisions for selling multiple objects. Economic Theory, 13, 723–733.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chan, W., Park, D. H., & Proschan, F. (1989). Peakedness of weighted averages of jointly distributed random variables. In L. J. Gleser, M. D. Perlman, S. J. Press & A. R. Sampson (Eds.), Contributions to Probability and Statistics (pp. 58–62). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christoffersen, P. F. (2012). Elements of financial risk management (2nd edn.). New York: Elsevier.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Chu, C. S., Leslie, P., & Sorensen, A. (2011). Bundle-size pricing as an approximation to mixed bundling. American Economic Review, 101, 263–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Conley, T. G. (1999). GMM estimation with cross sectional dependence. Journal of Econometrics, 92, 1–45.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Cont, R. (2001). Empirical properties of asset returns: Stylized facts and statistical issues. Quantitative Finance, 1, 223–236.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins, J. D. (2006). Should the government provide insurance for catastrophes? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 88, 337–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins, J. D., Doherty, N., & Lo, A. (2002). Can insurers pay for the ‘big one’? Measuring the capacity of the insurance market to respond to catastrophic losses. Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, 557–583.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cummins, J. D., & Mahul, O. (2003). Optimal insurance with divergent beliefs about insurer total default risk. The Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 27, 121–138.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Dansby, R. E., & Conrad, C. (1984). Commodity bundling. American Economic Review, 74, 377–381.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davis, R. A., & Mikosch, T. (1998). The sample autocorrelations of heavy-tailed processes with applications to ARCH. Annals of Statistics, 26, 2049–2080.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • de la Peña, V. H., & Giné, E. (1999). Decoupling: From dependence to independence. Probability and Its Applications. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • de la Peña, V. H., Ibragimov, R., & Sharakhmetov, S. (2003). On extremal distributions and sharp L p -bounds for sums of multilinear forms. Annals of Probability 31, 630–675.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, D., & Dybvig, P. (1983). Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. Journal of Political Economy, 91, 401–419.

    Google Scholar 

  • Embrechts, P., Klüppelberg, C., & Mikosch, T. (1997). Modelling Extremal Events for Insurance and Finance. New York: Springer.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Embrechts, P., McNeil, A., & Straumann, D. (2002). Correlation and dependence in risk management: Properties and pitfalls. In M. A. H. Dempster (Ed.), Risk Management: Value at Risk and Beyond (pp. 176–223). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Embrechts, P., Neslehova, J., & Wüthrich, M. (2009). Additivity properties for Value-at-Risk under Archimedean dependence and heavy-tailedness. Insurance: Mathematics and Economics, 44, 164–169.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, E. (1965b). Portfolio analysis in a stable Paretian market. Management Science, 11, 404–419.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Fang, H., & Norman, P. (2006). To bundle or not to bundle. Marketing Science, 37, 946–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Flannery, M. (2005). No pain, no gain: Effecting market discipline via reverse convertible debentures. In H. Scott (Ed.),Capital Adequacy beyond Basel: Banking, Securities, and Insurance (Chap. 5, pp. 171–197.). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fölmer, H., & Schied, A. (2002). Convex measures of risk and trading constraints. Finance and Stochastics, 6, 429–447.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Frittelli, M., & Gianin, E. R. (2002). Putting order in risk measures. Journal of Banking & Finance, 26, 1473–1486.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K. A. (2001). The market for catastrophe risk: A clinical examination. Journal of Financial Economics, 60, 529–571.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K. A., & Posner, S. (2002). The pricing of event risks with parameter uncertainty. The Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance, 27(2), 153–165.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K. A., Scharfstein, D., & Stein, J. (1993). Risk management: Coordinating corporate investment and financing policies. Journal of Finance, 48, 1629–1658.

    Google Scholar 

  • Froot, K. A., & Stein, J. (1998). Risk management, capital budgeting, and capital structure policy for financial institutions: An integrated approach. Journal of Financial Economics, 47, 55–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordy, M. B. (2000). Credit VaR and risk-bucket capital rules: A reconciliation. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago (May) (pp. 406–417).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gordy, M. B. (2003). A risk-factor based model foundation for ratings-based bank capital rules. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 12, 199–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Granger, C. W. J., & Orr, D. (1972). Infinite variance and research strategy in time series analysis. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 67, 275–285.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Hanks, T., & Johnston, A. (1992). Common features of the excitation and propagation of strong ground motion for north american earthquakes. Bulletin of the Seismological Society of America, 82, 1–23.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hanks, T., & Kanamori, H. (1979). A moment magnitude scale. Journal of Geophysical Research, 84, 2348–2350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, B. E. (2015). The integrated mean squared error of series regression and a Rosenthal hilbert-space inequality. Econometric Theory, 31, 337–361.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Hennessy, D. A., & Lapan, H. E. (2009). Harmonic symmetries of imperfect competition on circular city. Journal of Mathematical Economics, 45, 124–146.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Hitt, L. M., & Chen, P.-y. (2005). Bundling with customer self-selection: A simple approach to bundling low-marginal-cost goods. Management Science, 51, 1481–1493.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho, P., Sussman, J., & Veneziano, D. (2001). Estimating the direct and indirect losses from a Midwest earthquake. Report SE-10, Mid-America Earthquake Center.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hogg, R., & Klugman, S. (1983). On the estimation of long tailed skewed distributions with actuarial applications. Journal of Econometrics, 23, 91–102.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horn, R. A., & Johnson, C. R. (1990) Matrix Analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; Corrected reprint of the 1985 original.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, P. (1999). Robustness of tail index estimation. Journal of Computational Graphical Statistics, 8, 318–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hubbard, G., Deal, B., & Hess, P. (2005). The economic effect of federal participation in terrorism risk. Risk Management & Insurance Review, 8, 177–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, M., & Ibragimov, R. (2008). Optimal constants in the rosenthal in- equality for random variables with zero odd moments. Statistics and Probability Letters, 78, 186–189.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R. (2005). New majorization theory in economics and martingale convergence results in econometrics. Ph.D. Dissertation, Yale University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R. (2007). Efficiency of linear estimators under heavy-tailedness: Convolutions of α-symmetric distributions. Econometric Theory, 23, 501–517.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R. (2009a). Heavy-tailed densities, In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics Online. Palgrave Macmillan. http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_H000191.

  • Ibragimov, R. (2009b). Portfolio diversification and value at risk under thick-tailedness. Quantitative Finance, 9, 565–580.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R. (2014). On the robustness of location estimators in models of firm growth under heavy-tailedness. Journal of Econometrics. In press, http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2014.02.005. Also available as Harvard Institute of Economic Research Discussion Paper No. 2087. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=774865.

  • Ibragimov, R., Jaffee, D., & Walden, J. (2009). Nondiversification traps in catastrophe insurance markets. Review of Financial Studies, 22, 959–993.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Jaffee, D., & Walden, J. (2010). Pricing and capital allocation for multiline insurance firms. Journal of Risk and Insurance, 77, 551–578.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Jaffee, D., & Walden, J. (2011). Diversification disasters. Journal of Financial Economics, 99, 333–348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Jaffee, D., & Walden, J. (2012). Insurance equilibrium with monoline and multiline insurers. Working paper, Imperial College Business School and the University of California at Berkeley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., Mo, J., & Prokhorov, A. (2014). Fat tails and copulas: Limits of diversification revisited. Working paper, Imperial College Business School and the University of Sydney Business School.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., & Sharakhmetov, S. (1997). On an exact constant for the Rosenthal inequality. Theory of Probability and Its Applications, 42, 294–302.

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., & Sharakhmetov, S. (2002). Bounds on moments of symmetric statistics. Studia Scientiarum Mathematicarum Hungarica, 39, 251–275 (Date of submission: 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., & Walden, J. (2007). The limits of diversification when losses may be large. Journal of Banking and Finance, 31, 2551–2569.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibragimov, R., & Walden, J. (2010). Optimal bundling strategies under heavy-tailed valuations. Management Science, 56, 1963–1976.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. (2006a). Commentary on Should the government provide insurance for catastrophes? Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 88, 381–385.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. (2006b). Monoline restrictions, with applications to mortgage insurance and title insurance. Review of Industrial Organization, 28, 88–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaffee, D. (2009). Monoline regulations to control the systemic risk created by investment banks and GSEs. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 9(3). Available at http://www.bepress.com/bejeap/vol9/iss3/art17.

  • Jaffee, D., & Russell, T. (2006). Should governments provide catastrophe insurance? The Economists’ Voice, 3(5). Available at http://www.bepress.com/ev/vol3/iss5/art6.

  • Jensen, D. R. (1997). Peakedness of linear forms in ensembles and mixtures. Statistics and Probability Letters 35, 277–282.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Jovanovic, B., & Rob, R. R. (1987). Demand-driven innovation and spatial competition over time. Review of Economic Studies, 54, 63–72.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Jurečková, J., & Sen, P. K. (1996). Robust statistical procedures: Asymptotics and interrelations, New York: Wiley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kagan, Y., & Knopoff, L. (1984). A stochastic model of earthquake occurrence. In Proceedings of the 8th International Conference on Earthquake Engineering (Vol. 1, pp. 295–302). Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kamien, M., & Schwartz, N. (1982). Market structure and innovation. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karlin, S. (1968). Total positivity (Vol. I). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Kashyap, A., Rajan, R., & Stein, J. (2008). Rethinking capital regulation. In Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Symposium on Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System (pp. 431–471).

    Google Scholar 

  • Knopoff, L., & Kagan, Y. (1977). Analysis of the theory of extremes as applied to earthquake problems. Journal of Geophysical Research, 82, 5647–5657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kodes, L., & Pritsker, M. (2002). A rational expectations model of financial contagion. Journal of Finance, 57, 769–799.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, V. (2002). Auction theory. San Diego, CA: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kunreuther, H., & Michel-Kerjan, E. (2006). Looking beyond TRIA: A clinical examination of potential terrorism loss sharing. NBER Working paper No. 12069. http://www.nber.org/papers/w12069.

  • Kyle, A., & Xiong, W. (2001). Contagion as a wealth effect. Journal of Finance, 56, 1401–1440.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewbel, A. (1985). Bundling of substitutes or complements. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 3, 101–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ma, C. (1998). On peakedness of distributions of convex combinations. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 70, 51–56.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Mahul, O., & Wright, B. (2004). Efficient risk sharing within a catastrophe insurance pool. Paper presented at the 2003 NBER Insurance Project Workshop. Available at http://www.arec.umd.edu/Department/Seminars/mahulwright0204.pdf.

  • Marshall, A. W., Olkin, I., & Barro, A. (2011). Inequalities: Theory of majorization and its applications (2nd edn.). New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAfee, R., M. J., & Whinston, M. (1989). Multiproduct monopoly, commodity bundling and correlation of values. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, 371–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGuire, R. (2004). Seismic Hazard and Risk Analysis. Oakland, CA: Earthquake Engineering Research Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • McNeil, A. J., Frey, R., & Embrechts, P. (2005). Quantitative risk management: Concepts, techniques, and tools. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mikosch, T., & Stărică, C. (2000). Limit theory for the sample autocorrelations and extremes of a GARCH (1, 1) process. Annals of Statistics, 28, 1427–1451.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P., & Weber, R. (1982). A theory of auctions and competitive bidding. Econometrica, 50, 1089–1122.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, C. R., & Plosser, C. I. (1982). Trends and random walks in macroeconomic time series. Journal of Monetary Economics, 10, 139–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nze, P. A., & Doukhan, P. (2004). Weak dependence: Models and applications to econometrics. Econometric Theory, 20, 995–1045.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005a). Policy issues in insurance no. 08: Catastrophic risks and insurance. OECD Publishing, August.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2005b). Policy issues in insurance no. 09: Terrorism risk insurance in OECD countries. OECD Publishing, July.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R. (1983). Bundling decisions by a multiproduct monopolist with incomplete information. Econometrica 51, 463–483.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Proschan, F. (1965). Peakedness of distributions of convex combinations. Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 36, 1703–1706.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Rachev, S. T., & Mittnik, S. (2000). Stable Paretian Models in Finance, New York: Wiley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Rochet, J. C., & Tirole, J. (1996). Interbank lending and systemic risk. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 28, 773–762.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. A. (1976). A note on a paradox in portfolio theory. Philadelphia: Mimeo, University of Pennsylvania.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rousseeuw, P. J., & Leroy, A. M. (1987). Robust regression and outlier detection. New York: Wiley.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Roy, A. D. (1952). Safety first and the holding of assets. Econometrica, 20, 431–449.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Salinger, M. A. (1995). A graphical analysis of bundling. Journal of Business, 68, 85–98.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1967a). Efficient portfolio selection for Pareto-Lévy investments. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 2, 107–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1967b). General proof that diversification pays. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 2, 1–13.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmalensee, R. L. (1984). Gaussian demand and commodity bundling. Journal of Business, 57, S211–S230.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, D., & Coppersmith, K. (1984). Fault behavior and characteristic earthquakes. Journal of Geophysical Research, 89, 5681–5698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaffer, S. (1994). Pooling intensifies joint failure risk. Research in Financial Services, 6, 249–280.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D., Knopoff, L., Kagan, Y., & Vanneste, C. (1996). Rank-ordering statistics of extreme events: Application to the distribution of large earthquakes. Journal of Geophysical Research, 101, 13883–13894.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stremersch, S., & Tellis, G. J. (2002). Strategic bundling of products and prices: A new synthesis. Journal of Marketing, 66, 55–72.

    Google Scholar 

  • SwissRe (2006). Sigma. Sigma, 2, 267–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tong, Y. L. (1994). Some recent developments on majorization inequalities in probability and statistics. Linear Algebra and its Applications, 199, 69–90.

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Uchaikin, V. V., & Zolotarev, V. M. (1999). Chance and stability. Stable distributions and their applications. Utrecht: VSP.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Utev, S. A. (1985). Extremal problems in moment inequalities. Proceedings of the Mathematical Institute of the Siberian Branch of the USSR Academy of Sciences, 5, 56–75. (In Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Venkatesh, R., & Kamakura, W. (2003) Optimal bundling and pricing under a monopoly: Contrasting complements and substitutes from independently valued products. Journal of Business 76, 211–231.

    Google Scholar 

  • Volcker, P. A. (2010). Statement for the committee on banking, housing, and urban affairs of the United States Senate, February 2, 2010. Available at http://banking.senate.gov/public/index.cfm?FuseAction=Files.View&FileStore_id=ec787c56-dbd2-4498-bbbd-ddd23b58c1c4.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner, W. (2010). Diversification at financial institutions and systemic crises. Journal of Financial Intermediation, 19, 373–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, G. (1999). The Mathematics of Natural Catastrophes. London: Imperial College Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wu, S.-y., Hitt, L. M., Chen, P.-y., & Anandalingam, G. (2008). Customized bundle pricing for information goods: A nonlinear mixed-integer programming approach. Management Science, 54, 608–622.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zolotarev, V. M. (1986). One-dimensional stable distributions. Providence: American Mathematical Society.

    MATH  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Ibragimov, M., Ibragimov, R., Walden, J. (2015). Implications of Heavy-Tailedness. In: Heavy-Tailed Distributions and Robustness in Economics and Finance. Lecture Notes in Statistics, vol 214. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16877-7_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics