Skip to main content

Abstract

Human economic activity and its effects on the environment are ever more clearly approaching critical ecological limits. At the same time, the ecological crisis is accompanied by multiple socio-economic crises in the economy, society, state governance capacity, and in the development of scientific theory. Under such crisis conditions, how should successful ecological sustainability institutions be designed and how can social change be initiated? Far-reaching visions of a “great transformation” stand alongside rather sobering findings from institutional and behavioral economics research on the institutional framework for change and collective mitigation through cooperation.

The biggest problem is not to let people accept new ideas, but to let them forget the old ones.

(Keynes 2009[1936], Preface).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Here, the term “common goods” is used to summarize those (partially) public goods that dominate in the environment, which are characterized by rivalrous consumption but which face problems of excludability of access. Such goods are also referred to as common-pool resources and describe natural (fishing grounds, pastures) or man-made resource systems (irrigation) exploited by a majority of users; at the same time, excluding or restricting use by parties potentially interested in using the resource is either technically impossible, too costly to organize, or has been deliberately suspended by collective use regulations (non-excludability). Pure public goods, on the other hand, lack the “consumption rivalry” characteristic that is so typical to environmental resources: Use of a fishing ground or an area of rain forest typically depletes the supply for other parties interested in using the resource.

  2. 2.

    The term is used here in the wider sense of allocation theory, according to which common goods, in general, pose economic problems of efficient management due to lacking, too costly, or non-implementable exclusion technologies.

  3. 3.

    The concept of “spontaneous order” (also known as self-organization) regards social structures as the unplanned result of interaction between decentralized decisions—for an overview see, for example, Barry (1982). Prominent examples from the field of economics are the “invisible hand” developed by Adam Smith and the Hayek’s idea of markets as a “discovery procedure”.

  4. 4.

    That a privatization of property rights—insofar as this is possible or economically viable—does not necessarily lead to efficient results is also illustrated by the “tragedy of the anticommons”: here the over-optimal distribution of rights leads to market paralysis (co-ordination problem as a result of “too many” rather than “too few private” rights-holders), as for example in the case of patent protection or bureaucracy in licensing law—see Heller (1998).

  5. 5.

    Stollorz (2011, p. 5), for instance, talks of an “economic theory that is cast in stone,” in which “for too long […] people’s ability to engage in cooperative behaviour in complex situations has been underestimated.” Of course, this view is at best outdated: decades earlier, Musgrave (1959) and Olson (1965) already expressed differentiated views on the success of cooperation in relation to public goods, and the research carried out over the years since then is simply ignored.

  6. 6.

    Cf. Güth and Kliemt (2011, p. 69). The experimentally well established set of bounded rational behaviour types includes partial orientation to the past (not relevant for future findings), revenge-motivated rather than exclusively self-interest-motivated strategic action, and initial willingness to cooperate under supposed freedom from exploitation in the group (Kreps et al. 1982; Milgrom 1982).

  7. 7.

    See Güth and Kliemt (2011, p. 78) for deviating findings based on laboratory results.

  8. 8.

    This so-called “altruistic punishing” behavior is boundedly rational because after-the-fact punishment of free riders for refusal to cooperate merely eats into one’s own resources (revenge costs), but there are no immediate gains for the punisher. The collective stabilization effect, however, is all the more effective.

  9. 9.

    In particular, the obtruding comparison to the Great Transformation of nineteenth century English society described by Polyani (1971[1944]) is up for debate: According to Polyani, the two most important moments of secular change were the emergence of market economies and nation-states.

References

  • Angus I (ed) (2011) The global fight for climate justice—anticapitalist responses to global warming and environmental destruction. Resistance Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Aumann RJ (1981) Survey of repeated games. In: Aumann RJ et al (eds) Essays in game theory and mathematical economics. Bibliographisches Institut, Mannheim, pp 11–42

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod R (1984) The evolution of cooperation. Basic Books, New York, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Barry N (1982) The tradition of spontaneous order. Lit Lib 5:7–58

    Google Scholar 

  • Bartz S, Kelly DL (2008) Economic growth and the environment: theory and facts. Resour Energ Econ 30:115–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beck U (1992) Risk society: towards a new modernity. Sage, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Beck S (2009) Das Klimaexperiment und der IPCC: Schnittstellen zwischen Wissenschaft und Politik in den internationalen Beziehungen. Metropolis, Marburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Beyer J (2006) Pfadabhängigkeit. Über institutionelle Kontinuität, anfällige Stabilität und fundamentalen Wandel. Campus, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Bizer K, Führ M, Hüttig C (eds) (2002) Responsive Regulierung: Beiträge zur interdisziplinären Institutionenanalyse und Gesetzesfolgenabschätzung. Mohr Siebeck, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruins JJ, Liebrand WBG, Wilke HAM (1989) About the saliency of fear and greed in social dilemmas. Eur J Soc Psychol 19:155–161

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dijkstra BR (1998) The political economy of instrument choice in environmental policy. Dissertation, University of Groningen, Groningen

    Google Scholar 

  • Edelman MJ (1985) The symbolic uses of politics. University of Illinois Press, Urbana

    Google Scholar 

  • Eissrich D (2001) Systemtransformation aus der Sicht der Neuen Institutionenökonomik. Campus, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Emerich MM (2011) The gospel of sustainability: media, market and LOHAS. University of Illinois Press, Urbana

    Google Scholar 

  • Flachsland C, Edenhofer O (2013) Auf mehreren Ebenen agieren. Klimaschutz und Transformation. Politische Ökologie 133:108–117

    Google Scholar 

  • Gawel E (1995) Zur Politischen Ökonomie von Umweltabgaben. JCB Mohr, Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Gawel E (1996) Neoklassische Umweltökonomie in der Krise? Kritik und Gegenkritik. In: Köhn J, Welfens MJ (eds) Neue Ansätze in der Umweltökonomie. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 45–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Gawel E (2011) Die Allmendeklemme und die Rolle der Institutionen—oder: Wozu Märkte auch bei Tragödien taugen. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte 61(28–30):27–33 (“Gemeingüter”)

    Google Scholar 

  • Giddens A (1990) The consequences of modernity. Polity, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Grimm D (ed) (1990) Wachsende Staatsaufgaben, sinkende Steuerungsfähigkeit des Rechts. Nomos, Baden-Baden

    Google Scholar 

  • Güth W, Kliemt H (2011) Sozial-ökologische Dilemmata und ihre experimentelle Analyse. In: Held M, Kubon-Gilke G, Sturn R (eds) Institutionen ökologischer Nachhaltigkeit. Yearbook 9 Normative und institutionelle Grundfragen der Ökonomik. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 63–87

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansmeyer K-H, Rürup B (1973) Umweltgefährdung und Gesellschaftssystem. Wirtschaftspolitische Chronik 22:396–417

    Google Scholar 

  • Held M, Kubon-Gilke G, Sturn R (eds) (2011) Ökonomik in der Krise. Metropolis, Marburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Heller M (1998) The tragedy of the anticommons. Harv Law Rev 111:621–688

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann-Riem W (1993) Verwaltungsrechtsreform—Ansätze am Beispiel des Umweltschutzes. In: Hoffmann-Riem W, Schmidt-Aßmann E, Folke Schuppert G (eds) Reform des Allgemeinen Verwaltungsrechts. Nomos, Baden-Baden, pp 115–175

    Google Scholar 

  • Horbach J (1992) Neue Politische Ökonomie und Umweltpolitik. Campus, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Issing O (1975) Zerstörung der Umwelt—ein Versagen des marktwirtschaftlichen Systems? In: Recktenwald HC (ed) Das Umweltproblem aus ökonomischer und juristischer Sicht. Vandenhoeck und Ruprecht, Göttingen, pp 127–144

    Google Scholar 

  • Kelly DL (2013) Capitalism, socialism, and the environment. Nat Cult 8:226–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (2009) The general theory of employment, interest and money. Signalman, Kissimmee (Orig. 1936)

    Google Scholar 

  • Khan U, Dhar R (2006) Licensing effect in consumer choice. J Mark Res 43:259–266

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kreps D, Milgrom P, Roberts J, Wilson R (1982) Rational cooperation in the finitely-repeated prisoners’ dilemma. J Econ Theory 27:245–252

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lehmann P, Gawel E (2013) Why should support schemes for renewable electricity complement the EU emissions trading scheme? Energy Policy 52:597–607

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leskow J, Puchet M, Punzo LF (eds) (2010) New tools of economic dynamics. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Lübbe-Wolff G (1996) Modernisierung des Umweltordnungsrechts. Vollziehbarkeit—Deregulierung—Effizienz. Economica, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Luhmann N (1973) Vertrauen—Ein Mechanismus der Reduktion sozialer Komplexität, 2nd edn. Ferdinand Enke, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayntz R (1979) Regulative Politik in der Krise? In: Matthes J (ed) Sozialer Wandel in Westeuropa. Campus, Frankfurt am Main, pp 55–81

    Google Scholar 

  • Meadows DL, Meadows DH, Zahn E (1972) The limits to growth. Universe Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom P (1982) Predation, reputation, and entry deterrence. J Econ Theory 27:280–312

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millennium Ecosystem Assessment (2005) Ecosystems and human well-being. Synthesis. Island Press, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Musgrave R (1959) Theory of public finance. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (2009) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance, 27th edn. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1965) The logic of collective action. Public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E (1990) Governing the commons. The evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Gardner R, Walker J (1994) Rules, games, and common pool resources. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor, MI

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom E, Burger J, Field CB, Norgaard RB, Policansky D (1999) Revisiting the commons: local lessons, global challenges. Science 284:278–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paech N (2013) Befreiung vom Überfluss: Auf dem Weg in die Postwachstumsökonomie. Oekom, München

    Google Scholar 

  • Polanyi K (1971) The great transformation, 11th edn. Beacon Press, Boston, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Polimeni JM, Mayumi K, Giampietro M, Alcott B (2008) The Jevons paradox and the myth of resource efficiency improvements. Earthscan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Priddat BP, Kabalak A (eds) (2013) Ungewissheit als Herausforderung für die ökonomische Theorie: Nichtwissen, Ambivalenz und Entscheidung. Metropolis, Marburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Rockström J, Steffen W, Noone K, Persson Å, Chapin FS, Lambin EF, Lenton TM, Scheffer M, Folke C, Schellnhuber HJ, Nykvist B, de Wit CA, Hughes T, van der Leeuw S, Rodhe H, Sörlin S, Snyder PK, Costanza R, Svedin U, Falkenmark M, Karlberg L, Corell RW, Fabry VJ, Hansen J, Walker B, Liverman D, Richardson K, Crutzen P, Foley JA (2009) A safe operating space for humanity. Nature 461:472–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose CM (1986) The comedy of the commons: commerce, custom, and inherently public property. Univ Chic Law Rev 53:711–781

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwanitz D (1993) Kommunikation und Bewusstsein. In: de Berg H, Prangel M (eds) Kommunikation und Differenz. Westdeutscher Verlag, Opladen, pp 101–113

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Soete B, Blasch J, Schubert R (2011) Eine Krise kommt selten allein—Zusammenhänge zwischen den ökologischen und ökonomischen Krisen 2007–2009. In: Held M, Kubon-Gilke G, Sturn R (eds) Ökonomik in der Krise, Yearbook 9 “Normative und institutionelle Grundfragen der Ökonomik”. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 93–121

    Google Scholar 

  • SRU (Sachverständigenrat für Umweltfragen = German Advisory Council on the Environment) (2012) Umweltgutachten 2012. Verantwortung in einer begrenzten Welt, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Stollorz V (2011) Elinor Ostrom und die Wiederentdeckung der Allmende. Aus Politik und Zeitgeschichte 61(28-30):3–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Sturm B, Weimann J (2001) Experimente in der Umweltökonomik. FEMM Working Paper 7/2001, Magdeburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Sturn R (2011) Die Natur der Probleme—Institutionen ökologischer Nachhaltigkeit. In: Held M, Kubon-Gilke G, Sturn R (eds) Institutionen ökologischer Nachhaltigkeit, Yearbook 9 Normative und institutionelle Grundfragen der Ökonomik. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 9–38

    Google Scholar 

  • Töller AE (2010) Umweltpolitik in Zeiten der Krise. Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 33:445–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Voigt R (ed) (1983) Abschied vom Recht? Suhrkamp, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • von Prittwitz V (1990) Das Katastrophenparadox: Elemente einer Theorie der Umweltpolitik. Leske and Budrich, Opladen

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Weizsäcker CC (2011) Vorsicht vor dem “gestaltenden Staat”! GAIA 20:246–247

    Google Scholar 

  • WBGU (German Advisory Council on Global Change) (2011) World in transition—a social contract for sustainability. WBGU, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Weikard P (2011) Towards a global climate constitution. In: Held M, Kubon-Gilke G, Sturn R (eds) Institutionen ökologischer Nachhaltigkeit. Yearbook 9 Normative und institutionelle Grundfragen der Ökonomik. Metropolis, Marburg, pp 89–106

    Google Scholar 

  • Wissenschaftlicher Beirat beim Bundesfinanzministerium (Scientific Advisory Board of the German Federal Ministry of Finance) (2010) Klimapolitik zwischen Emissionsvermeidung und Anpassung, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Young OR (2011) Effectiveness of international environmental regimes: existing knowledge, cutting-edge themes, and research strategies. Proc Natl Acad Sci USA 108(50):19853–19860

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erik Gawel .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Gawel, E. (2016). “Great Transformation” Towards Sustainability and Behavioral Economics. In: Beckenbach, F., Kahlenborn, W. (eds) New Perspectives for Environmental Policies Through Behavioral Economics. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-16793-0_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics