Skip to main content

The Four Worlds of Democracy: Commentary on Arend Lijphart’s Revised Edition of Patterns of Democracy (2012)

  • Chapter

Abstract

The first edition of Lijphart’s Patterns of Democracy (Yale University Press, 1999) has been praised as a seminal contribution to the comparative study of democracies. The revised edition, published in 2012, advances even stronger arguments with better data and a better methodology in support of Lijphart’s key message: consensus democracies are superior to majoritarian democracies—measured by a wide variety of indicators of participation, contestation, policy outputs and policy outcomes. The present chapter is an assessment of the revised edition of Lijphart’s book. Starting from a comparison of two schools of research on non-majoritarian democracies—Lijphart’s approach and Lehmbruch’s contributions to the study consociational democracy—, the commentary reports the changes in the second edition of Patterns of Democracy (such as updated data sources and a more comprehensive and rigorous analysis of the relationship between types of democracy and policy indicators), and discusses the many merits and the few limits of Lijphart’s book. The 2012 edition is another milestone in empirical democratic theory even if it reproduces some of the limits of the first edition. Both editions of Patterns of Democracy disregard deviant cases (such as the strong welfare state in a majoritarian democracy in France), tend to overestimate the exportability of consensus democracy, and abstain from complementing the association between democratic institutions and policy output and outcomes with agency-centred variables, such as parties in office. Moreover, both editions focus attention ultimately on two worlds of democracy while Lijphart’s data suggest the usefulness of distinguishing between four worlds of democracy: unitary majoritarian democracy (like Great Britain), federalist majoritarian democracy (such as the United States of America), unitary consensus democracy (the northern European countries) and federalist consensus democracy (Germany and Switzerland). The distinction between four types of democracy also allows for a more precise identification of some of the mechanisms which account for the success of consensus democracies. There are two different roads that lead to superior performance of consensus democracies: one is based on federalism and the other on a unitary state, and, hence, to some extent on a majoritarian device.

Translation of original text from German into English by Deanna Stewart.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In future updates of the study, more than two dozen additional democracies will be added to the list if these selection criteria continue to be adhered to, including the post-communist democracies in Central and Eastern Europe.

  2. 2.

    Still, the differences between Germany and Switzerland are worth noting: Germany has much higher scores on the index of executive dominance and the index of judicial review of legislation. However, Lijphart has once again neglected (as in the 1999 edition) one particularly striking difference, that between Germany’s representative democracy and Switzerland’s direct democracy.

  3. 3.

    On the other hand, he mainly ignored critical commentary on other parts of the 1999 edition, such as Adrian Vatter’s suggestion that direct democracy should be incorporated into the concept of majoritarian and consensus democracies (Vatter 2009).

  4. 4.

    Evaluation based only on those OECD member states included among the 36 countries in the Lijphart study, as in Lijphart’s analyses of welfare spending and spending on foreign aid (Lijphart 2012: 290).

  5. 5.

    Lijphart has explained the difference between consensus democracy and consociational democracy elsewhere (Lijphart 2008a: 8f): consensus democracy is measured using ten quantitative indicators of rather formal institutional characteristics; consociational democracy, on the other hand, is based on the qualitative identification of four very broad components that emphasize informal aspects, namely, large coalitions, autonomous segments in a divided society, proportionality and minority rights. While both forms of democracy are possible in deeply divided countries, consociational democracy is “the stronger medicine” (Lijphart 2008a: 8); consociational democracy demands the inclusion of all important groups, while most consensus democracies only set incentives for cooperative behavior (Armingeon 2011: 555).

  6. 6.

    In this respect, Columbia’s exclusion from the list of established democracies in Lijphart’s study (2012) also reflects the boundaries of a previous case of classifying countries as democracies or consociational democracies (Lijphart 1984, 1999, 2008b: 29).

  7. 7.

    The same thing applies for liberal parties—if nothing else, it is an effect of the system of proportional representation found in the consensus democracies.

    Fig. 3
    figure 3

    Executives–party dimension according to Lijphart (2012) and partisan composition of the government, as measured by the proportion of cabinet seats held by secular–conservative parties (1945–2010)

    Fig. 4
    figure 4

    Executives–party dimension according to Lijphart (2012) and the participation of social democratic and secular conservative parties in government (1945–2010)

  8. 8.

    An examination of Lijphart’s data leads to the same result in the case of two other indicators: the budget deficit (2003–2007) and spending on development and collaboration. The other indicators of outputs and outcomes in the Lijphart study are not affected, though, by the situation discussed here (Lijphart 2012: 304–309; see also the policy output and outcome data posted on Lijphart’s web site, UC San Diego 2014). The indicators of the partisan composition of governments are taken from a database compiled by the author. For more on the definition and measurement of party families, see Schmidt (1996) and Schmidt (2010a).

References

  • Adema, W., & Ladaique, M. (2009). How expensive is the welfare state? Gross and net indicators in the OECD Social Expenditure Database (SOCX). OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers Nr. 92. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armingeon, K. (2011). Democracy, consensual. In B. Badie, D. Berg-Schlosser, & L. Morlino (Eds.), International encyclopedia of political science (Vol. 2, pp. 553–559). Los Angeles: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Busch, A. (1995). Preisstabilitätspolitik. Politik und Inflationsraten im internationalen Vergleich. Opladen: Leske+Budrich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The three worlds of welfare capitalism. Cambridge: Polity.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ganghof, S. (2005). Normative Modelle, institutionelle Typen und beobachtbare Verhaltensmuster: Ein Vorschlag zum Vergleich parlamentarischer Demokratien. Politische Vierteljahresschrift, 46(3), 406–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hermens, F. A. (1931). Demokratie und Kapitalismus. Ein Versuch zur Soziologie der Staatsformen. München: Duncker & Humblot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huber, E., Ragin, C., & Stephens, J. D. (1993). Social democracy, Christian democracy, constitutional structure, and the welfare state. Towards a resolution of quantitative studies. American Journal of Sociology, 99(3), 711–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Huber, E., & Stephens, J. D. (2012). Democracy and the left. Social policy and inequality in Latin America. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Köppl, S., & Kranenpohl, U. (Eds.) (2012). Konkordanzdemokratie: Ein Demokratietyp der Vergangenheit? Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (1967). Proporzdemokratie: Politisches System und politische Kultur in der Schweiz und in Österreich. Tübingen: Mohr (Siebeck).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (1987). Proporzdemokratie nach zwanzig Jahren. Überlegungen zur Theoriebildung in der komparatistischen Forschung über politische Strategien in der Schweiz. Unpublished manuscript, Konstanz.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (1992). Konkordanzdemokratie. In M. G. Schmidt (Ed.), Die westlichen Länder. Lexikon der Politik (Vol. 3, pp. 206–211). München: C.H.Beck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (1996). Die korporative Verhandlungsdemokratie in Westmitteleuropa. Schweizerische Zeitschrift für Politische Wissenschaft, 2(4), 19–41.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (2000). Parteienwettbewerb im Bundesstaat. Regelsysteme und Spannungslagen im politischen System der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (2003). Verhandlungsdemokratie. Beiträge zur vergleichenden Regierungslehre. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G. (2012). Die Entwicklung der vergleichenden Politikforschung und die Entdeckung der Konkordanzdemokratie: eine historisch-institutionelle Perspektive. In S. Köppl & U. Kranenpohl (Eds.), Konkordanzdemokratie: Ein Demokratietyp der Vergangenheit? (pp. 33–50). Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lehmbruch, G., & Schmitter, P. C. (Eds.) (1982). Patterns of corporatist policy-making. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1977). Democracy in plural societies. A comparative exploration. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1984). Democracies. Patterns of majoritarian and consensus government in twenty-one countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (1999). Patterns of democracy. Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (2008a). Introduction: Developments in power sharing theory. In A. Lijphart (Ed.), Thinking about democracy. Power sharing and majority rule in theory and practice (pp. 3–22). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (2008b). Consociational democracy. In A. Lijphart (Ed.), Thinking about democracy. Power sharing and majority rule in theory and practice (pp. 25–41). London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. (2012). Patterns of democracy. Government forms and performance in thirty-six countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luhmann, N. (1989). Legitimation durch Verfahren. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Norris, P. (2012). Making democratic governance work. How regimes shape prosperity, welfare, and peace. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R., & Davies, P. L. (1984). Inheritance in public policy: Change without choice in Britain. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, F. W. (1997). Games real actors play. Actor-centered Institutionalism in policy research. Boulder, CO: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, F. W., Reissert, B., & Schnabel, F. (1976). Politikverflechtung: Theorie und Empirie des kooperativen Föderalismus in der Bundesrepublik. Kronberg im Taunus: Scriptor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, M. G. (1996). When parties matter: A review of the possibilities and limits of partisan influence on public policy. European Journal of Political Research, 30(2), 155–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, M. G. (2010a). Parties. In F. G. Castles, S. Leibfried, J. Lewis, H. Obinger, & C. Pierson (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the welfare state (pp. 211–226). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, M. G. (2010b). Demokratietheorien. Eine Einführung. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, M. G., Ostheim, T., Siegel, N. A., & Zohlnhöfer, R. (2007). Der Wohlfahrtsstaat. Eine Einführung in den historischen und internationalen Vergleich. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitter, P. C., & Lehmbruch, G. (Eds.) (1979). Trends toward corporatist intermediation. Beverly Hills: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Siaroff, A. (1999). Corporatism in 24 industrial democracies: Meaning and measurement. European Journal of Political Research, 36(2), 175–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swank, D. (2010). Globalization. In F. G. Castles, S. Leibfried, J. Lewis, H. Obinger, & C. Pierson (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of the welfare state (pp. 318–332). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • UC San Diego. (2014). Homepage Arend Lijphart. Accessed May 29, 2014, from http://polisci.ucsd.edu/faculty/lijphart.html

  • Vatter, A. (2009). Lijphart expanded: Three dimensions of democracy in advanced OECD countries? European Political Science Review, 1(1), 125–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Manfred G. Schmidt .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

Table 3 Structures of democracy according to Lijphart (2012: 305–309)
Table 4 Review of Lijphart’s explanatory approach with indicators of the partisan composition of governments (1945–2010a)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Schmidt, M.G. (2015). The Four Worlds of Democracy: Commentary on Arend Lijphart’s Revised Edition of Patterns of Democracy (2012). In: Schneider, V., Eberlein, B. (eds) Complex Democracy. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-15850-1_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics