Skip to main content

Impact of Tax and Expenditure Limitations on Local Government Savings

  • Chapter
Local Government Budget Stabilization

Part of the book series: Studies in Public Budgeting ((SIPB,volume 2))

Abstract

Local governments serve a pivotal role in the delivery of public services. However, since the late 1970s, their ability to deliver essential public services has been curtailed by widespread adoption of limits on taxing and/or spending authority. Studies show these limits fundamentally altered the fiscal landscape of municipal governments. Using data on county governments for the period 1970–2004, this analysis shows TELs had a negative impact on unrestricted cash reserves. This has wide-ranging implications on fiscal performance including the government’s ability to cope with negative revenue and expenditure shocks and their ability to retain resources for strategic purposes.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Of the 50 states, six do not report any limits on local government taxing or spending authority. They include Maine, New Hampshire, Tennessee, Virginia and Vermont (Anderson 2006; Mullins and Wallin 2004). Utah has the least stringent TEL—that is the full disclosure or truth in taxation requirement. Research shows the full disclosure requirement has resulted in uniformity in assessed values in Utah (Cornia and Walters 2005).

  2. 2.

    Municipal governments in New York may override their expenditure caps for one-time needs (e.g., legal settlements, limited pension growth) with a 60 % majority vote. For more, see: http://governor.ny.gov/citizenconnects/reforminggovernment/guide-to-the-property-tax (accessed July 28, 2014).

  3. 3.

    See summary of scope of data in the existing literature in Sect. 8.2.3.

  4. 4.

    In its annual survey of government finances, the Census Bureau collects data on cash and security holdings held for debt service purposes, as proceeds of bond issues, as liquid assets in trust systems, and unrestricted cash holdings. In this study, I have developed a proxy measure of reserves using the unrestricted cash holdings together with the proceeds of a bond issue (pending disbursement).The measure, previously explored in Gore (2009), has been found to be correlated with widely used measures of slack resources.

  5. 5.

    In the fund statements, fund balance represents the difference in reported assets and liabilities. Fund assets generally include cash, short-term investments, receivables, inventory, and prepaid expenses. Fund liabilities include accounts payable, employee compensation payable, any deferred revenue, short-term loans and long-term obligations due in the next 12 months. If assets exceed liabilities, the government will report a positive fund balance. If assets are less than reported liabilities, the government will report a negative fund balance and is generally considered to be cash insolvent. Fund balance is also a long-term measure of budget solvency. Governments reporting revenues that exceed expenditures for prior budget periods generally report a positive fund balance, particularly if their liabilities do not relate to short-term borrowing for cash flow purposes.

  6. 6.

    The Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB) recently amended fund balance categories to include non-spendable, restricted, committed, assigned, and unassigned. Non-spendable fund balances include assets that are precluded from conversion to cash (e.g., inventories, permanent funds). Restricted includes funds restricted by enabling legislation. Committed includes funds restricted by those with the highest level of decision-making authority. Assigned represents current commitments already made by management while unassigned includes amounts available for any purpose (GASB 2009).

  7. 7.

    Liquidity here includes the proportion of fund balance reported as cash and cash equivalents. For a full discussion of GFOA recommendations see http://www.gfoa.org/determining-appropriate-level-unrestricted-fund-balance-general-fund (accessed July 28, 2014).

  8. 8.

    See https://www.census.gov/econ/overview/go0400.html (accessed October 31, 2014). Specifically (also see http://www2.census.gov/govs/class06/ch_7.pdf accessed July 18, 2014).

  9. 9.

    Unlike Gore (2009), proceeds of bond issues pending disbursement are included in the measure of cash reserves. Data shows bond proceeds were limited to a small portion of the sample. Excluding bond proceeds, cash reserves as a percent of total expenditures were 35.82 %. Including bond proceeds, cash reserves were 39.26 %. Since funds would inevitably be available for operating purposes (e.g., capital outlays) they were included in all the analyses. Capital outlays were included in the model as an explanatory variable.

  10. 10.

    Gianakis and Snow (2007) found free cash flows were correlated with budget stabilization funds. However, in an economic downturn, governments were more likely to draw on their free cash flows first, before (re)allocating resources in their budget stabilization funds.

  11. 11.

    Data used in this study is that of county governments. Of all general purpose governments, county governments are the fastest growing (Lobao and Kraybill 2005). They have long been an important administrative arm of state governments responsible for essential services including public assistance, law enforcement, court systems, voter registration, etc. (Benton et al. 2007). They have also been assigned discretion over the administration of essential programs (Lobao and Kraybill 2005). Counties have also evolved to provide a wider menu of services that were traditionally the responsibility of smaller governments (Benton et al. 2007). Given the dynamic nature of their responsibility and the static nature of the geographical boundaries, county governments offer an interesting environment to test the impact of TELs on cash reserves. Excluded from the sample are county governments in Connecticut and Rhode Island which exist strictly for statistical and geographical purposes. Counties in Alaska were excluded because the state is generally considered to be an outlier.

  12. 12.

    Because the Census Bureau does not collect any data on liabilities, I define this measure as a gross measure of free cash flows. In other words, the measure is net of restrictions (i.e., sinking funds or trust funds) but would likely include cash flows designated for budget period liability payments (e.g., accounts payable) or designated for certain activities (e.g., pay-as-you-go spending). The measure is also more limited than the traditional measure of fund balance as it excludes receivables due from other funds, other governments, and taxpayers.

  13. 13.

    Months of cash is a measure often used to assess duration of operations if all sources of revenue were delayed, exhausted, or currently unavailable and all expected expenditures were incurred as budgeted.

  14. 14.

    Another form of slack that is not adequately addressed in the TEL literature is the difference between the rate or caps and actual property tax rates or property tax revenues. For example, if the current rate is far below the cap, the local government has slack taxing capacity. Gianakis and Snow (2007), for example, found the presence of this form of slack was correlated with budget stabilization funds—the relationship between the TEL slack and the free cash flows was weak.

  15. 15.

    The direct legislation provisions enable voters to directly or indirectly amend their state constitutions or statutes. Direct legislation includes a broad array of provisions including statutory and constitutional direct and indirect initiatives, legislative referendums and popular referendums. For the purposes of the model specified in this paper, I limit my interest to voter initiative provisions - whether direct or indirect, statutory or constitutional (Boehmke 2005; Kioko and Martell 2012; Waters 2003).

  16. 16.

    Kioko and Martell (2012) found voter initiative provisions were not valid instruments in their study of the impact of state-level TELs. They argue initiative processes have been used to alter the direction of state and local government policies (Waters 2003), as such voter initiative provisions were an important explanatory variable that could be used to not only explain the presence of the endogenous variable, but also have an independent effect on taxing and spending levels. While initiatives have been shown to have a substantive impact on taxing and spending levels, I do not expect them to have any impact on reserves. In other words, voters have approved measures that would alter the course of government taxing and spending levels, but there are no measures that have been proposed to alter the level of reserves.

  17. 17.

    The index infers the ideological position of the electorate from the distribution of votes in congressional races as well as the Americans for Democratic Action (ADA) and AFL-CIO Committee on Political Education (COPE) score for members of congress.

  18. 18.

    Results from the first stage regressions are available from the author.

  19. 19.

    The fixed effects model was specified as follows \( {Y}_{it}={\beta}_0+{\beta}_1{X}_{it}+{\beta}_2{\mathrm{TEL}}_{it}+{\mathrm{CD}}_i+{\mathrm{TD}}_t+{\varepsilon}_{it} \)

    where X it is our vector of explanatory variables (R, D), TEL it is the policy variable of interest that is suspected to be endogenous, CD i and TD i are the county and time fixed effects, and ε it is the error term.

  20. 20.

    For example, if when reporting to the Census Bureau the government aggregates unrestricted cash of governmental activities together with cash reserves for their business-type activities. Alternatively, cash reserves could include designated purposes which we are unable to clearly identify relative to fund-based data.

References

  • Anderson NB (2006) Property tax limitations: an interpretative review. Natl Tax J 59(3):685–694

    Google Scholar 

  • Baum CF, Schaffer ME, Stillman S (2003) Instrumental variables and GMM: estimation and testing. Department of Economics, Boston College, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennett J, DiLorenzo TJ (1982) Off-budget activities of local government: the bane of the tax revolt. Public Choice 39(3):333–342

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson ED, Marks BR (2010) Dueling revenue caps and municipal bond yields: the case of Houston, Texas. Public Budg Finance 30(2):112–133

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benton JE (2005) An assessment of research on American counties. Public Adm Rev 65(4):462–474

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benton JE, Byers J, Cigler BA, Klase KA, Menzel DC, Salant TJ, Streib G, Svara JH, Waugh WL (2007) Conducting research on counties in the 21st century: a new agenda and database considerations. Public Adm Rev 67(6):968–983

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berry WD, Ringquist EJ, Fording RC, Hanson RL (1998) Measuring citizen and government ideology in the American states. Am J Polit Sci 42(1):327–348

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boehmke FJ (2005) The indirect effects of direct legislation: how institutions shape interest group systems. The Ohio State University Press, Columbus

    Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury KL, Mayer CJ, Case KE (2001) Property tax limits, local fiscal behavior, and property values: evidence from Massachusetts under Proposition 21/2. J Public Econ 80:287–311

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan G, Buchanan JM (1979) The logic of tax limits: alternative constitutional constraints on the power to tax. Natl Tax J 32:11–22

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr JB (2006) Local government autonomy and state reliance on special district governments: a reassessment. Polit Res Q 59(3):481–492

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll DA (2005) Are state governments prepared for fiscal crises? A look at revenue diversification during the 1990’s. Public Finance Rev 33(5):603–633

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll DA, Johnson T (2010) Examining small town revenues: to what extent are they diversified? Public Adm Rev 70(2):223–235

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clingermayer JC, Dan Wood B (1995) Disentangling patterns of state debt financing. Am Polit Sci Rev 89(1):108–120

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cornia GC, Walters LC (2005) Full disclosure: unanticipated improvements in property tax uniformity. Public Budg Finance 25(3):106–123

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye RF, McGuire TJ, McMillen DP (2005) Are property tax limitations more binding over time. Natl Tax J 58(2):215–225

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitch (2002) The 12 habits of highly successful finance officers. Fitch Ratings, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • GASB (2009) Fund balance reporting and governmental fund type definitions. Governmental Accounting Standards Board

    Google Scholar 

  • Gianakis G, Snow D (2007) The implementation and utilization of stabilization funds by local governments in Massachusetts. Public Budg Finance 27(1):86–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gordon TM, Rueben K (2010) The best of times or the worst of times? How alternative revenue structures are changing local government. In: Ingram GK, Hong Y-H (eds) Municipal revenues and land policies. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Gore AK (2009) Why do cities hoard cash? Determinants and implications of municipal cash holdings. Account Rev 84(1):183–207

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendrick R (2006) The role of slack in local government finances. Public Budg Finance 26(1):14–46

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoene C (2004) Fiscal structure and the post-Proposition 13 fiscal regime in California cities. Public Budg Finance 24(4):51–72

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou Y (2003) What stabilizes state general fund expenditures in downturn years—budget stabilization fund or general fund unreserved undesignated balance? Public Budg Finance 23(3):64–91

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou Y (2004) Budget stabilization fund: structural features of the enabling legislation and balance levels. Public Budg Finance 24(3):38–64

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hou Y (2005) Fiscal reserves and state own-source expenditure in the downturn years. Public Finance Rev 33(1):117–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson CL, Kriz KA (2005) Fiscal institutions, credit ratings and borrowing costs. Public Budg Finance 25(1):84–103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kioko SN, Martell CR (2012) Impact of state-level tax and expenditure limits (TELs) on government revenues and aid to local governments. Public Finance Rev 40(6):736–766

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kioko SN, Zhang P (2014) Impact of tax and expenditure limits (TELS) on local government debt burdens. Association of Budgeting and Financial Management, Grand Rapids

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight B (2000) Supermajority voting requirements for tax increases: evidence from the states. J Public Econ 76:41–67

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lobao L, Kraybill DS (2005) The emerging roles of county governments in metropolitan and nonmetropolitan areas: findings from a national survey. Econ Dev Q 19(3):245–259

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maher CS, Deller SC (2013) Measuring the impact of TELs on municipal financial condition. In: Levine H, Justice JB, Scorsone EA (eds) Handbook of local government fiscal health. Jones and Bartlett Learning, Burlington

    Google Scholar 

  • Marlowe J (2005) Fiscal slack and counter-cyclical expenditure stabilization: a first look at the local level. Public Budg Finance 25(3):48–75

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marlowe J (2011) Beyond 5 percent: optimal municipal slack resources and credit ratings. Public Budg Finance 31(4):93–108

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marlowe J (2013) Fiscal slack, reserves, and rainy day funds. In: Levine H, Justice JB, Scorsone EA (eds) Handbook of local government fiscal health. Jones & Bartlett Learning, Burlington, pp 321–341

    Google Scholar 

  • McCubbins MD, Moule E (2010) Making mountains of debt out of molehills: the pro-cyclical implications of tax and expenditure limitations. Natl Tax J 63(3):603–622

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moody’s (2004) The six critical components of strong municipal management. Moody’s Investors Service, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Moody’s (2014) Rating methodology: US local government general obligation debt. Moody’s Investor Services, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mullins DR, Joyce PG (1996) Tax and expenditure limitations and state and local fiscal structure: an empirical assessment. Public Budg Finance 16(1):75–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mullins DR, Wallin BA (2004) Tax and expenditure limitations: introduction and overview. Public Budg Finance 24(4):2–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murray MP (2006) Avoiding invalid instruments and coping with weak instruments. J Econ Perspect 20(4):111–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plummer E, Hutchison PD, Patton TK (2007) GASB No. 34’s governmental financial reporting model: evidence in information relevance. Account Rev 82(1):205–240

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Poterba JM, Rueben KS (2001) Fiscal news, state budget rules, and tax-exempt bond yields. J Urban Econ 50:537–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pridgen AK, Wilder WM (2013) Relevance of GASB No. 34 to financial reporting by municipal governments. Account Horiz 27(2):175–204

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose S, Smith DL (2012) Budget slack, institutions, and transparency. Public Adm Rev 72(2):187–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rubin I (1998) Class, tax, and power: municipal budgeting in the United States. Chatham House, Chatham

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rueben KS (1997) The effect of tax and expenditure limitations on state and local governments, economics. Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston

    Google Scholar 

  • S&P (2013) U.S. local governments general obligation ratings: methodology and assumptions. Standard and Poor’s Rating Services, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Saxton GD, Hoene CW, Erie SP (2001) Fiscal constraints and the loss of home rule: the long term impacts of California’s post-Proposition 13 fiscal regime. Am Rev Public Adm 32(4):423–454

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shadbegian RJ (1999) The effect of tax and expenditure limitations on the revenue structure of local government, 1962–87. Natl Tax J 52(2):221–238

    Google Scholar 

  • Shelton M, Tyer C (2000) Local government reserve funds and fund balance. Munic Finance J 21(1):1–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Skidmore M (1999) Tax and expenditure limitations and the fiscal relationships between state and local governments. Public Choice 99(1):77–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sokolow AD (2000) The changing property tax in the west: state centralization of local finances. Public Budg Finance 20(1):85–104

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart LSM (2009) Examining factors that impact Mississippi counties’ unreserved fund balance during relative resource abundance and relative resource scarcity. Public Budg Finance 29(4):45–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Yogo M (2005) Testing for Weak Instruments in Linear IV Regression. In Identification and Inference for Econometric Models: Essays in Honor of Thomas Rothenberg, edited by Donald W K Andrews and James H Stock. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press

    Google Scholar 

  • Sun R (2012) Reevaluating the effect of tax and expenditure limitations: an instrumental variable approach. Public Finance Rev 42(1):92–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Suyderhoud JP (1994) State-local revenue diversification, balance, and fiscal performance. Public Finance Rev 22(2):168–194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaiprasert N, Faulk D, Hicks MJ (2010) The economic effects of Indiana’s property tax rate limits. Center for Business and Economic Research, Ball State University, Muncie

    Google Scholar 

  • Thompson F, Green MT (2004) Vox populi? Oregon tax and expenditure limitation initiatives. Public Budg Finance 24(4):73–87

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wagner GA (2004) The bond market and fiscal institutions: have budget stabilization funds reduced borrowing costs? Natl Tax J 57(4):785–804

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagner GA, Elder EM (2005) The role of budget stabilization funds in smoothing government expenditures over the business cycle. Public Finance Rev 33(4):439–465

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wang W, Hou Y (2012) Do local governments save and spend across budget cycles? Evidence From North Carolina. Am Rev Public Adm 42(2):152–169

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waters MD (2003) Initiative and referendum almanac. Carolina Academic Press, Durham

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildasin DE (2010) Intergovernmental transfers to local governments. In: Ingram GK, Hong Y-H (eds) Municipal revenues and land policies. Lincoln Institute of Land Policy, Cambridge, pp 47–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolkoff M (1987) An evaluation of municipal rainy day funds. Public Budg Finance 7(2):52–63

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sharon N. Kioko .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Results from the OLS regression (1970–2004)

Appendix: Results from the OLS regression (1970–2004)

 

Expectation

Model A

Model B

Model C

Model D

Model E

Property tax rate limits

+/−

−0.318 (0.882)

    

Property tax levy limits

+/−

 

−0.613 (0.759)

   

Limit on assessed values

+/−

  

−0.867 (1.126)

  

Binding limit (rate and assessment, levy and cap)

+/−

   

−1.876* (0.974)

 

Property tax limit (rate, levy, or assessment)

+/−

    

−0.414 (0.835)

Population (log)

5.054*** (1.807)

4.990*** (1.799)

5.113*** (1.801)

5.129*** (1.802)

5.024*** (1.800)

Density

+

0.0152*** (0.00533)

0.0152*** (0.00534)

0.0153*** (0.00536)

0.0153*** (0.00538)

0.0152*** (0.00534)

Total expenditures (per capita)

−0.0290*** (0.00476)

−0.0290*** (0.00475)

−0.0290*** (0.00475)

−0.0290*** (0.00476)

−0.0289*** (0.00476)

Income (per capita)

−0.000149 (0.000203)

−0.000151 (0.000203)

−0.000158 (0.000202)

−0.000161 (0.000203)

−0.000145 (0.000203)

Hirschman–Herfindahl index (HHI)

+

0.157*** (0.0201)

0.157*** (0.0203)

0.158*** (0.0202)

0.158*** (0.0201)

0.157*** (0.0202)

Property tax revenue (per capita)

+

0.0279*** (0.00672)

0.0278*** (0.00670)

0.0278*** (0.00669)

0.0276*** (0.00665)

0.0279*** (0.00672)

Sales tax revenue (per capita)

+

0.0602*** (0.0108)

0.0599*** (0.0106)

0.0603*** (0.0106)

0.0602*** (0.0106)

0.0599*** (0.0109)

Income tax revenue (per capita)

+

0.0166 (0.0183)

0.0170 (0.0183)

0.0158 (0.0183)

0.0140 (0.0183)

0.0171 (0.0182)

User charges and fees (per capita)

+

0.0167*** (0.00464)

0.0167*** (0.00464)

0.0167*** (0.00464)

0.0168*** (0.00464)

0.0167*** (0.00464)

Federal aid (as a % of total revenues)

+/−

0.173*** (0.0517)

0.171*** (0.0518)

0.172*** (0.0519)

0.174*** (0.0518)

0.172*** (0.0519)

State aid (as a % of total revenues)

+/−

0.0176 (0.0305)

0.0180 (0.0305)

0.0171 (0.0306)

0.0165 (0.0306)

0.0173 (0.0305)

Full-faith and credit Debt (per capita)

0.000564 (0.000587)

0.000563 (0.000586)

0.000561 (0.000584)

0.000558 (0.000582)

0.000563 (0.000586)

Short-term debt (per capita)

+/−

0.0229** (0.0109)

0.0229** (0.0108)

0.0229** (0.0109)

0.0230** (0.0109)

0.0229** (0.0109)

Capital outlays (as a % of total expenditures)

+

0.105*** (0.0251)

0.105*** (0.0251)

0.105*** (0.0251)

0.105*** (0.0251)

0.105*** (0.0251)

Utility (per capita)

+

0.0246*** (0.00877)

0.0247*** (0.00881)

0.0247*** (0.00885)

0.0251*** (0.00888)

0.0246*** (0.00878)

Administrative costs (% of total expenditures)

+

0.610*** (0.0644)

0.608*** (0.0643)

0.609*** (0.0646)

0.608*** (0.0645)

0.611*** (0.0643)

Complexity in service delivery

+

1.654*** (0.263)

1.667*** (0.264)

1.653*** (0.263)

1.649*** (0.263)

1.656*** (0.263)

Constant

 

−32.16* (18.62)

−31.56* (18.58)

−32.87* (18.60)

−32.92* (18.61)

−31.80* (18.60)

County fixed effects

 

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Time dummies

 

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes

Observations

 

75,917

75,917

75,917

75,917

75,917

Adjusted R-squared

 

0.033

0.033

0.033

0.033

0.033

Heteroscedastic-consistent standard errors reported in parentheses.

*p < 0.10, **p < 0.05, ***p < 0.01

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kioko, S.N. (2015). Impact of Tax and Expenditure Limitations on Local Government Savings. In: Hou, Y. (eds) Local Government Budget Stabilization. Studies in Public Budgeting, vol 2. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-15186-1_8

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics