Advertisement

Wage and Fertility Gaps in Dual Economies

  • Sibabrata Das
  • Alex Mourmouras
  • Peter C. RangazasEmail author
Chapter
  • 1.6k Downloads
Part of the Springer Texts in Business and Economics book series (STBE)

Abstract

This chapter begins our analysis of two-sector models where markets may be missing. Here, we focus on the fact that wages are lower and fertility is higher in the traditional sector than in the modern sector of economies. This has important consequences for economic growth for two reasons. First, the wage gap suggests that the allocation of labor may be inefficient—the movement of labor from the traditional sector to the modern sector should raise average labor productivity. Second, if fertility falls as households move from the traditional sector to the modern sector, then population growth will decline making it easier to increase physical capital per worker.

Keywords

Human Capital Marginal Product Family Production Child Labor Family Farm 
These keywords were added by machine and not by the authors. This process is experimental and the keywords may be updated as the learning algorithm improves.

References

  1. Acemoglu D, Robinson J (2012) Why nations fail. The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. Crown Publishers, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  2. Acemoglu D, Johnson S, Robinson J (2003) An African success story: Botswana. In: Rodrik D (ed) In search of prosperity. Princeton University Press, PrincetonGoogle Scholar
  3. Alston L, Hatton T (1991) The earnings gap between agricultural and manufacturing laborers, 1925–1941. J Econ Hist 51(1):83–99CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Au C, Henderson J (2006) How migration restrictions limit agglomeration production in China. J Dev Econ 80(2):350–388CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Banerjee A, Duflo E (2011) Poor economics. Public Affairs, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  6. Basu K (1991) Agrarian structure and economic underdevelopment. Harwood Academic Publishers, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  7. Bertocchi G (2006) The law of primogeniture and the transition from landed aristocracy to industrial democracy. J Econ Growth 11(1): 43–70Google Scholar
  8. Bosworth B, Collins S (2008) Accounting for growth: comparing China and India. J Econ Perspect 22(1):45–66CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Calvo G (1978) Urban unemployment and wage determination in LDCs: trade unions in the Harris-Todaro model. Int Econ Rev 19(1):65–81CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  10. Caselli F (2005) Accounting for cross-country income differences. In: Aghion D, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 679–741Google Scholar
  11. Caselli F, Coleman W (2001) The US structural transformation and regional convergence: a reinterpretation. J Polit Econ 109(3):584–616CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  12. Chanda A, Dalgaard CJ (2008) Dual economies and international total factor productivity differences: channeling the impact from institutions, trade, and geography. Economica 75(300):629–661CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Collier P, Radwan S, Wangwe S (1986) Labour and poverty in rural Tanzania: Ujameen and rural development in the United Republic of Tanzania. Oxford University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  14. Cordoba J, Ripoll M (2006) Agriculture, aggregation, wage caps, and cross-country income differences. Working paper 246, University of Pittsburgh, Department of EconomicsGoogle Scholar
  15. Cunningham H (1990) The employment and unemployment of children in England c. 1680–1851. Past Present 126:115–150CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. David P (1967) The growth of real product in the United States before 1840: new evidence, controlled conjectures. J Econ Hist 27(2):151–197Google Scholar
  17. David P (2005) Real income and economic welfare growth in the early republic. Stanford University Department of Economics working paper 06–001Google Scholar
  18. Doepke M (2004) Accounting for the fertility decline during the transition to growth. J Econ Growth 9(3):347–383CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  19. Drazen A, Eckstein Z (1988) On the organization of rural markets and the process of development. Am Econ Rev 78(3):431–443Google Scholar
  20. Ely R, Wehrwein G (1940) Land economics. Macmillan Co., New YorkGoogle Scholar
  21. Feder G, Just D, Zilberman D (1982) Adoption of agricultural innovation in developing countries: a survey. World Bank staff working paper 542. World Bank, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
  22. Field E (2007) Entitled to work: urban property rights and labor supply in Peru. Quart J Econ 122(4):1561–1602CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Foster A, Rosenzweig M (1996) Technical change and human capital returns and investments: evidence from the green revolution. Am Econ Rev 86(4):931–953Google Scholar
  24. French H, Hoyle R (2003) English individualism refuted and asserted: the land market of Earls Coline (Essex), 1550–1750. Econ Hist Rev 56(4):595–622CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  25. Galor O (2005) From stagnation to growth: a unified growth theory. In: Aghion P, Durlauf S (eds) Handbook of economic growth. North Holland, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  26. Galor O, Weil DN (2000) Population, technology, and growth: from Malthusian stagnation to the demographic transition and beyond. Am Econ Rev 90(4):806–828CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Galor O, Moav O, Vollrath D (2009) Inequality in land ownership, the emergence of human capital promoting institutions, and the great divergence. Rev Econ Stud 76(1):143–179CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Gardner B (2002) American agriculture in the twentieth century. Harvard University Press, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  29. Gollin D (2002) Getting income shares right. J Polit Econ 110(2): 458–474Google Scholar
  30. Goldin C, Katz L (2000) Education and income in the early 20th century: evidence from the prairies. J Econ Hist 60(3):782–818CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Gollin D, Lagakos D, Waugh M (2014) The agricultural productivity gap. Quart J Econ 129(2):939–993CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Gollin D, Parente S, Rogerson R (2004) Farmwork, homework, and international income differences. Rev Econ Dyn 7(4):827–850CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Greenwood J, Seshadri A (2002) The US demographic transition. Am Econ Rev 92(2):153–159CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Haines M (2000) The population of the United States 1790–1920. In: Engerman S, Gallman R (eds) The Cambridge economic history of the United States. Cambridge University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  35. Hansen G, Prescott E (2002) Malthus to solow. Am Econ Rev 92(4):1205–1218CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Harris B (1972) Innovation adoption in Indian agriculture: the high-yielding variety programs. Mod Asian Stud 6:71–98Google Scholar
  37. Harris J, Todaro M (1970) Migration, unemployment, and development: a two-sector analysis. Am Econ Rev 60(1):126–142Google Scholar
  38. Hayashi F, Prescott E (2008) The depressing effect of agricultural institutions on the prewar Japanese economy. J Polit Econ 116(4):573–632CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Hazan M, Berdugo B (2002) Child labor, fertility, and economic growth. Econ J 112(482):810–878CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. Henderson V (2010) Cities and development. J Reg Sci 50(1):515–540CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Herrendorf B, Schoellman T (2013) Why is measured productivity so low in agriculture? Arizona State University working paper. http://www.public.asu.edu/~tschoell/papers/AgricultureSubmissionNovember2013.pdf
  42. Herrendorf B, Schoellman T (2014) Wages, human capital, and the allocation of labor across sectors. Arizona State University Working Paper. In: Society for Economic Dynamics 364, 2014 Meeting Papers. https://www.economicdynamics.org/meetpapers/2014/paper_364.pdf
  43. Horrell S, Humphries J (1995) The exploitation of little children: child labor and the family economy in the industrial revolution. Explor Econ Hist 32(4):485–516CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Hudson P, King S (2000) Two textile townships, c. 1660–1820: a comparative demographic analysis. Econ Hist Rev 53(4):706–741CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Jenkins C, Knight J (2002) The economic decline of Zimbabwe. Palgrave Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  46. Jerven M (2013) Poor numbers. Cornell University Press, IthacaGoogle Scholar
  47. Jones C (2001) Was an industrial revolution inevitable? Economic growth over the very long run. B.E. J Macroecon 1(2):1–45Google Scholar
  48. La Porta R, Shleifer A (2014) Informality and development. J Econ Perspect 28(3):109–126CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Lewis W (1954) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. Manchester Sch 22(2): 139–191Google Scholar
  50. Lord W, Rangazas P (2006) Fertility and development: the roles of schooling and family production. J Econ Growth 11(3):229–261CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. Macfarlane A (1978a) The origins of English individualism: the family, property, and social transition. Oxford University Press, OxfordGoogle Scholar
  52. Macfarlane A (1978b) The origins of English individualism: some surprises. Theor Soc 6(2):255–277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Mazumdar D (1989) Microeconomic issues of labor markets in developing countries: analysis and policy implications. EDI Seminar Paper No. 40. World Bank, Washington DCGoogle Scholar
  54. McMillan M, Rodrik D (2011) Globalization, structural change, and productivity growth. In: Bacchetta M, Jansen M (eds) Making globalization sustainable. International Labour Organization and World Trade Organization, GenevaGoogle Scholar
  55. Miguel E (2009) Africa’s turn? MIT Press, BostonGoogle Scholar
  56. Moav O (2005) Cheap children and the persistence of poverty. Econ J 115(500):88–110CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  57. Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2007) Wage gaps and development: lessons from U.S. history. IMF working paper 07/105. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DCGoogle Scholar
  58. Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2009) Reconciling Kuznets and Habbakuk in a unified growth model. J Econ Growth 14(2):149–181CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2013a) Efficient urban bias. J Econ Geogr 13(3):451–471CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  60. Mourmouras A, Rangazas P (2013b) Wage and fertility gaps in dual economies. Eurasian Econ Rev 3(1):59–83Google Scholar
  61. Mueller E (1984) The value and allocation of time in rural Botswana. J Dev Econ 15(3) 329–360Google Scholar
  62. Munshi K, Rosenweig M (2009) Why is labor mobility in India so low? Social insurance, inequality, and growth. NBER working paper 14850. National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  63. Myint A (2001) International trade and domestic institutional framework. In: Meier G, Stiglitz J (eds) Frontiers of development economics. Oxford University Press, New YorkGoogle Scholar
  64. Qian N (2013) Quantity-quality and the one child policy: the only-child disadvantage in school enrollment in rural China. Yale University Working PaperGoogle Scholar
  65. Rangazas P (2000) Schooling and growth: a King-Rebelo experiment with human capital. J Monetary Econ 46(2):397–416CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  66. Rangazas P (2002) The quantity and quality of schooling and U.S. labor productivity growth (1870–2000). Rev Econ Dyn 5(4):932–964CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  67. Ranis G, Fei J (1961) A theory of economic development. Am Econ Rev 51(4):533–565Google Scholar
  68. Restuccia D, Yang D, Zhu X (2008) Agriculture and aggregate productivity: a quantitative cross-country analysis. J Monetary Econ 55(2):234–250CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  69. Rosenzweig M (1988) Labor markets in low-income countries. In: Chenery HB, Srinivasan TN (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 6. Elsevier, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  70. Rosenzweig M, Zhang J (2009) Do population control policies induce more human capital investment? Twins, birth weight and China’s one-child policy. Rev Econ Stud 76(3):1149–1174CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  71. Schultz T (1964) Transforming traditional agriculture. Yale University Press, New HavenGoogle Scholar
  72. Shapiro D, Gebreselassie T (2008) Fertility transitions in sub-Saharan Africa: falling and stalling. Afr Population Stud 23(1):3–23Google Scholar
  73. Sokoloff K, Dollar D (1997) Agricultural seasonality and the organization of manufacturing in early industrial economics: the contrast between England and the United States. J Econ Hist 57(2):288–321CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Stiglitz J (1974) Wage determination and unemployment in LDCs. Quart J Econ 88(2):194–227CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  75. Stiglitz J (1988) Economic organization, information, and development. In: Chenery HB, Srinivasan TN (eds) Handbook of development economics, vol 6. Elsevier, AmsterdamGoogle Scholar
  76. Temple J (2005) Dual economy models: a primer for growth economists. Manchester Sch 73:435–478CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  77. Temple J, Woessmann E (2006) Dualism and cross-country growth regressions. J Econ Growth 11(3):187–228CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. The Economist (2014) Economic convergence: the headwinds return. Sept 14Google Scholar
  79. Vollrath D (2009a) How important are dual economy effects for aggregate productivity? J Dev Econ 88(2):325–334CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  80. Vollrath D (2009b) The dual economy in long-run development. J Econ Growth 14(4):287–312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  81. Vollrath D (2013) Measuring aggregate agricultural labor effort in dual economies. Eurasian Econ Rev 3(1):39–58Google Scholar
  82. Vollrath D (2014) The efficiency of human capital allocations in developing countries. University of Houston working paper 201307956Google Scholar
  83. Wang X, Piesse J (2010) Inequality and the urban-rural divide in China: effects of regressive taxation. China World Econ 18(6):36–55CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  84. Wang X, Piesse J (2011) The micro-foundations of dual economy models. Manchester Sch 81:80–101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  85. Woods R (2000) The demography of victorian England and Wales. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  86. World Bank (2013) Global monitoring report 2013: rural-urban dynamics and the millennium development goals. World Bank, WashingtonCrossRefGoogle Scholar
  87. Young A (1992) A tale of two cities: Factor accumulation and technical change in Hong Kong and Singapore. In: Blanchard O, Fisher S (eds) NBER macroeconomic annual. MIT Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, CambridgeGoogle Scholar
  88. Young A (1995) The tyranny of numbers: confronting the statistical reality of the east Asian growth experience. Quart J Econ 110(3):641–680CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  89. Young A (2012) The African growth miracle. J Polit Econ 120(4):696–739CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Young A (2013) Inequality, the urban-rural gap, and migration. Quart J Econ 128(4):1727–1785CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2015

Authors and Affiliations

  • Sibabrata Das
    • 1
  • Alex Mourmouras
    • 2
  • Peter C. Rangazas
    • 3
    Email author
  1. 1.International Monetary FundWashingtonUSA
  2. 2.Asia and Pacific DepartmentInternational Monetary FundWashingtonUSA
  3. 3.Indiana University-Purdue University Indianapolis (IUPUI)IndianapolisUSA

Personalised recommendations