Skip to main content

Economic Theories of Deflation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
In Defense of Deflation

Part of the book series: Financial and Monetary Policy Studies ((FMPS,volume 41))

  • 1020 Accesses

Abstract

Many economists have written about deflation or touched upon the subject in passing while focusing on their development of related monetary theories. My aim in this chapter is not to comment on every reference concerning the subject of falling prices. This endeavor would be virtually impossible. Rather, I provide an overview of the main currents and changes in economic theories of deflation. This overview aids in explaining how and when theories of deflation in economic thought were formed and why views on deflation have changed. To explain why certain theories of deflation and deflation phobia have emerged, I place special emphasis on the circumstances and backgrounds of these deflation theorists. My exposition of the theories of deflation proceeds mainly in chronological order; however, at times I will group theorists with similar views together, though they may not be contemporaries of each other.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    For example, John Locke argued that the money supply was irrelevant as any amount of money would be sufficient for the needs of trade (Locke [1691] 1824, p. 48).

  2. 2.

    Viner ([1937] 1975, p. 6).

  3. 3.

    See Viner ([1937] 1975, pp. 36–37). These two authors, not surprisingly, were also advocates of paper money. Concerning two strands of mercantilists, see p. 40; See Rothbard concerning Law (2006a, p. 330) and concerning Potter’s opposition to hoarding and of Potter as proposing one of the most odd theories of price deflation (p. 328). In one of the most curious lines of reasoning in the history of economic thought, Potter claimed that an increase in the amount of money could stimulate production to an extent that prices would fall. He obviously, did not see any problems in a price deflation stemming from monetary inflation.

  4. 4.

    Manley (1669, p. 53).

  5. 5.

    (Viner [1937] 1975, pp. 45–46); Later, when mercantilism was already in retreat, David Hume would still condemn state hoarding as “a practice which we should all exclaim against as destructive, namely, the gathering of large sums into a public treasure, locking them up, and absolutely preventing their circulation” ([1752] 1826b, p. 361).

  6. 6.

    (Viner [1937] 1975, pp. 8–9, 23–24, 26, 49); Even though neither were mercantilists, both Richard Cantillon and Jacob Vanderlint advised the king to hoard money in order to keep prices low and competitive. See Rothbard (2006a, pp. 333–334).

  7. 7.

    “The doctrine of thrift also led to emphasis on the importance of a favorable balance of trade through another chain of reasoning” (Viner 1975, p. 30) Viner explains that “[t]he disparagement of consumption and the exaltation of frugality and thrift were common doctrines of the period, not wholly dependent upon economic reasoning but deriving much of their vitality from moral and religious principles and class prejudices. The Puritans disapproved of luxury…” (p. 26).

  8. 8.

    (Cantillon [1755] 1959, pp. 159–199); Cantillon wrote his treatise around 1730, but it was not published until 1755.

  9. 9.

    Hume ([1752] 1826a, pp. 326–327).

  10. 10.

    Hume ([1752] 1826a, p. 329).

  11. 11.

    (Hume [1752] 1826b, p. 351); Hume’s reasoning that prices would fall proportionately must be criticized. Even though all individuals would lose nominal money proportionately they might react quite differently to that incident. He does not concentrate on the dynamic processes that are caused by reductions or injections of money in the real world but only on the long run price equilibria.

  12. 12.

    Hume ([1752] 1826a, p. 324).

  13. 13.

    Hume ([1752] 1826a, pp. 324–325).

  14. 14.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 218).

  15. 15.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 219).

  16. 16.

    This is, of course, not necessarily so, but might be valid as a historical judgment for many individual cases.

  17. 17.

    See Humpfrey (2004, p. 17).

  18. 18.

    Smith ([1776] 1976), Book I Ch. I.

  19. 19.

    Smith ([1776] 1976), Book II, Introduction.

  20. 20.

    Smith ([1776] 1976, p. 356).

  21. 21.

    Ricardo ([1817] 1973), Chap. VII.

  22. 22.

    Ricardo [1817] 1973), Chap. XXI.

  23. 23.

    Ricardo ([1817] 1973), Chap. XXXI.

  24. 24.

    Ricardo ([1817] 1973), Chap. XXX, XXXI.

  25. 25.

    See Rothbard (2006b, pp. 203–205).

  26. 26.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 204).

  27. 27.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 205).

  28. 28.

    Bankers fear price deflation because it may lead to defaults of their clients on loans and, thereby, losses.

  29. 29.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 205).

  30. 30.

    See Fetter (1964, p. Viii).

  31. 31.

    David Laidler (2000, p. 17) comes to a similar conclusion and explains the deflation aversion by Thomas Attwood and interest groups with ties to steel and agriculture as follows: “Agriculture was faced with foreign competition again [after the end of the Napoleonic Wars], while small arms manufacturing and the metal working trades associated with it saw a precipitous decline in demand for their output. In view of this, it was perhaps to be expected that the representatives of agricultural interests in Parliament were sometimes found attempting to obstruct the restoration of convertibility and the deflation that had to accompany it. Nor, since metal working was concentrated around Birmingham, is it surprising that this important city became the centre of a dissenting and, for its time, quite radical body of economic thought. The principal, and certainly the most able spokesman of so-called Birmingham School at this time was the banker Thomas Attwood.” (Italics in the original)

  32. 32.

    Again, Attwood is speaking here in his own economic interest as he was himself a debtor. As Fetter, states: “As early as 1836, when the elder Matthias Attwood died, not only did the Attwoods have no net capital in the bank, but they were heavily in debt to it” (1964, Xxvii).

  33. 33.

    Quoted in Viner (1975, p. 186); italics in the original.

  34. 34.

    See Humpfrey (2004, p. 28).

  35. 35.

    See Viner (1975, p. 187).

  36. 36.

    Similar sticky price arguments are employed by C.C. Western, George Julius Poulett Scrope (1797–1876), Thomas R. Malthus (1766–1834) and Henry Thornton (1769–1815). For the first three, see Viner (1975, p. 187), fn. 3. See also Thornton ([1802] 1978, p. 119).

  37. 37.

    See Fetter (1942, pp. 358, 361).

  38. 38.

    Wheatley (1816), A Letter to Lord Grenville on the Distress of the Country, p. 29 as quoted in Fetter (1942, p. 374).

  39. 39.

    See Humpfrey (2004, pp. 20–22).

  40. 40.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 175). In the famous Bullion Report, Thornton also argues for a devaluation of the pound to prevent a price deflation. See Rothbard (2006b, p. 195).

  41. 41.

    George Julius Poulett Scrope, a son of a merchant, also married into an aristocratic family.

  42. 42.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 209).

  43. 43.

    As indicated above, Ricardo, in his theoretical long-term analysis, is not deflation-phobic. Only when it comes to practical policies in his time, does he become somewhat deflation-phobic.

  44. 44.

    See Rothbard (2006b, p. 207).

  45. 45.

    Ricardo ([1821] 2004, p. 73).

  46. 46.

    Also, Jean-Baptiste Say opposed the return to the old parity. He uses a legal argument, stating that debtors had to pay more than they owed if they had to pay back with the old parity. See Rist (1966, p. 184).

  47. 47.

    See Humphrey (2004, pp. 23–24).

  48. 48.

    Concerning manufacturing and agricultural interest groups, see Rothbard (2006b, p. 206). For instance, the landed aristocrat, the Earl of Carnavon denounced the Resumption Act of 1819, as well as lower farming prices, calling for monetary expansion and fiscal policies as a remedy.

  49. 49.

    See Humphrey (2004, pp. 38–39).

  50. 50.

    Mill ([1848] 1965), Book I, Chap. VIII.

  51. 51.

    Mill ([1848] 1965), Book I, Chap. IX.

  52. 52.

    Mill ([1848] 1965), Book IV, Chap. II.

  53. 53.

    Marshall (1920), Book VI, Chaps. XII and XIII.

  54. 54.

    Concerning Wicksell’s treatment of deflation, see Bioanovsky (1998).

  55. 55.

    An announced deflation cannot be gradual according to Gustav Cassel who argued that when a central bank would announce such a policy, demand would immediately contract and accelerate the fall in prices. The central bank would lose the control of the pace of the process. See Bioanovsky (1998, p. 248).

  56. 56.

    See Boianovsky (1998).

  57. 57.

    See Selgin (1995, p. 707).

  58. 58.

    This implies that the productivity norm goes back to times of classical economics. It is discussed in this paragraph because in neoclassical economics, the productivity norm still plays a prominent role.

  59. 59.

    See Selgin (1995, pp. 708–709).

  60. 60.

    See Selgin (1995).

  61. 61.

    See Selgin (1995, pp. 714–715).

  62. 62.

    See Selgin (1995, p. 717).

  63. 63.

    Pigou plays another important role in respect to deflation theories as the “Pigou-effect” is named after him. In a 1943 article “The Classical Stationary State,” Pigou argues that if the price level falls, real wealth, defined as government bonds and money supply divided by the price level, increases. Feeling richer (“wealth effect”), economic agents would increase consumption and thereby stimulating output and employment. The Pigou-effect was intended as a critique of Keynes’ General Theory. Through price deflation and the “wealth effect” an economy would be self-correcting when aggregate demand falls.

  64. 64.

    See the second edition of Prices and Production (von Hayek 1939, p. 124). Concerning the evolution of Hayek on this point from a proponent of a constant money supply to a proponent of policies which advocate adjusting the money supply to changes in the velocity of money, see Selgin (1999).

  65. 65.

    See Selgin (1995). The list given by Selgin must be considered with caution. It is true that the mentioned authors saw no problems in a price deflation caused by economic growth. However, not all of them explicitly follow Selgin in his view that changes in the demand for money must be necessarily counteracted by monetary policy. As one example, see Hayek in his earlier works.

  66. 66.

    See Selgin (1995, p. 705). According to Hülsmann (2006, p. 72), St. Thomas Aquinas was the first philosopher who postulated a stable purchasing power of money.

  67. 67.

    See Selgin (1995, pp. 706–707) and Dowd (1995).

  68. 68.

    Josiah Stamp is such a case (Stamp 1932).

  69. 69.

    See Rothbard (2002, pp. 453–456).

  70. 70.

    Another case is Clark Warburton. See Cargill (1979, pp. 439–440). Warburton argues that prices are sticky in the short run, especially wages. A decrease in the money supply or a failure to adopt the money supply to decreases in the velocity of circulation means a decrease in spending. Due to sticky wages, this leads to a decrease in business profits and, thus, to a further fall in total spending.

  71. 71.

    The concept of the liquidity trap was formalized in Hicks’ (1937) classic article “Mr. Keynes and the ‘Classics:’ A Suggested Interpretation.” The term liquidity trap, however, was first coined by Dennis Robertson, although in a different context. See Boianovsky (2004, p. 92).

  72. 72.

    (Keynes [1923] 2000, p. 143); Italics are in the original.

  73. 73.

    (Keynes [1923] 2000, p. 39); Italics are in the original.

  74. 74.

    See Keynes ([1923] (2000, p. 143); See also Keynes ([1925] 1963, p. 247).

  75. 75.

    See Keynes ([1923] 2000, p. 40); Italics are in the original. See also p. 4.

  76. 76.

    Keynes ([1936] 1964, p. 271, 291).

  77. 77.

    See Skidelsky (2002, p. 99).

  78. 78.

    See Keynes (1964, pp. 344–345).

  79. 79.

    See Keynes (1964, p. 30).

  80. 80.

    See Keynes (1964, p. 207). Later this concept became famously known or described as the liquidity trap. For Keynes, the liquidity preference and propensity to hoard are essentially the same thing (1964, p. 208).

  81. 81.

    See Friedman (1968, p. 3) or Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 407).

  82. 82.

    This is the difference of Selgin’s position as compared to the view of the zero inflationists who advocate reducing any change in the general price level no matter what its cause is.

  83. 83.

    For a book of selected essays that stand in this tradition, see Burdekin and Siklos (2004a). Good deflation is caused by a positive supply shock and bad deflation by a negative demand shock. In particular, see the Burdekin and Siklos (2004b) and Bordo and Redish (2004).

  84. 84.

    See Kumar and colleagues (2003, p. 5 or p. 9). On p. 12, these authors state that temporary price declines due to economic growth may not entail significant costs. This seems to imply that even with a positive supply shock, significant costs might exist.

  85. 85.

    See Kumar et al. (2003, p. 13); Krugman (1998, p. 137).

  86. 86.

    See Krugman (1998), Goodfriend (2000), Svensson (2003), and Leigh (2004).

  87. 87.

    Svensson (2003, p. 147); It should be pointed out that by criticizing the negative consequences of deflation, Svensson takes a stand against all kinds of deflation. For instance, a positive supply shock, or more specifically, continuous economic growth, might cause a prolonged price deflation also.

  88. 88.

    For example, Svensson (2000, p. 30), justifies an inflation targeting of 2 % instead of 0 % by the allegedly negative effects of price deflation. Krugman (1998, p. 161), even argues that when an economy is in a liquidity trap, it is stuck there, because the “economy needs inflation.” He, p. 181, suggests a price inflation rate of 4 % for 15 years for Japan.

  89. 89.

    See Bordo et al. (2004, p. 15). This is the main difference between the two groups. The liquidity trap group does not differentiate between causes of price deflation, but, in contrast, states that “[d]eflation is, in almost all cases, a side effect of a collapse of aggregate demand—a drop in spending so severe that producers must cut prices on an ongoing basis in order to find buyers” (Bernanke 2002, p. 2).

  90. 90.

    Rational expectation theorists like Sargent and Wallace (1976, p. 175) argue that fully anticipated price changes would not have any effect on the real economic activity. This implies that a fully anticipated price deflation would have no adverse effect on economic activity. The public’s expectations are “rational” if they “are formed using the appropriate data and objective probability distributions” (p. 175). The view that an expected deflation would be “neutral” to the economic progress is widely held today.

  91. 91.

    See Bordo and Filardo (2004, p. 7); and (2005, p. 1).

  92. 92.

    See Sect. 5.1.7.

  93. 93.

    See also Bordo and Filardo (2005, p. 811).

  94. 94.

    Those economists regard price stability as dangerous for monetary policy due to the liquidity trap problematic. They argue for a positive inflation rate. See Goodfriend (2000, p. 1007).

References

  • Attwood T [1819] (1964) A letter to the earl of liverpool on the reports of the committies of the two houses of parliament on the questions of the bank restriction act. In: Fetter FW (ed) Selected economic writings of Thomas Attwood. The London School of Economic and Political Science, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Bagus P (2003) Deflation—when Austrians become interventionists. Quart J Aust Econ 6(4):19–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS (2002) Deflation: making sure ‘It’ Doesn’t Happen Here, speech before the National Economists Club, November 21. Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Boianovsky M (1998) Wicksell on deflation in the early 1920s. Hist Polit Econ 30(2):219–275

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boianovsky M (2004) The IS-LM model and the liquidity trap concept: from Hicks to Krugman. Hist Polit Econ 36(Annual Suppl): 92–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MD, Filardo AJ (2005) Deflation and monetary policy in a historical perspective: remembering the past or being condemned to repeat it? Econ Policy 20(44):799–844

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MD, Redish A (2004) Is deflation depressing? Evidence from the classical gold standard. In: Burdekin RCK, Siklos PL (eds, 2004a) Deflation: current and historical perspectives. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 197–217

    Google Scholar 

  • Bordo MD, Lane JL, Redish A (2004) Good versus bad deflation: lesson from the gold standard era. NBER working paper no. 10329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Borio C, Filardo AJ (2004) “Back to the future? Assessing the deflation record.” BIS working papers no. 152

    Google Scholar 

  • Burdekin RCK, Siklos PL (2004a) Deflation: current and historical perspectives. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Burdekin RCK, Siklos PL (2004b) Fears of deflation and the role of monetary policy: some lessons and an overview. In: Burdekin RCK, Siklos PL (eds, 2004a) Deflation: current and historical perspectives. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 1–27

    Google Scholar 

  • Cantillon R [1755] (1959) Essai sur la nature du commerce en général (trans. and ed: Higgs H). Frank Cass & Company, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Cargill TF (1979) Clark Warburton and the development of monetarism since the great depression. Hist Polit Econ 11(3):425–449

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiernin PN [1761] (1971) Lectures on the high price of foreign exchange in Sweden (trans. and ed: Eagly RV). American Philosophical Society, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Emerick CF (1896) An analysis of agricultural discontent in the United States I. Polit Sci Quart 11(3):433–463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fetter FW (ed) (1964) Selected economic writings of Thomas Attwood. The London School of Economics and Political Science, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1945) 100% money, 3rd edn. City Printing Co., New Haven, CT

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1968) The role of monetary policy. Am Econ Rev 58(1):1–17

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1969) The optimum quantity of money. In: Friedman M (ed) The optimum quantity of money and other essays. Aldine, Chicago, pp 1–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1990) The crime of 1873. J Polit Econ 98(6):1159–1194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garrison R (2001) Time and money. the macroeconomics of capital structure. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodfriend M (2001) Financial stability, deflation, and monetary policy. Working paper 01-01. Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

    Google Scholar 

  • Gossweiler K (1971) Großbanken, Industriemonopole, Staat—Ökonomie und Politik des staatsmonopolistischen Kapitalismus in Deutschland 1914-1932. VEB Deutscher Verlag der Wissenschaften, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Hahn AL (1956) Common sense economics. Abelard-Schumann, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoppe H-H (2009) “The yield of money held” Reconsidered. Mises.org. Daily article. May 14th

    Google Scholar 

  • von Hayek FA (1939) Prices and production, 2nd edn. Routledge, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Huerta de Soto J (2006a) Money, bank credit, and economic cycles. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Hülsmann JG (2006) The ethics of money production. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume D [1752] (1826a) Of money. In: The philosophical works of David Hume, including all the essays, and exhibiting the more important alterations and corrections in the successive editions published by the author, vol III. Adam Black, William Tait and Charles Tait, Edinburgh, pp 317–332

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume D [1752] (1826b) Of the balance of trade. In: The philosophical works of David Hume, including all the essays, and exhibiting the more important alterations and corrections in the successive editions published by the author, vol III. Adam Black, William Tait and Charles Tait, Edinburgh, pp 348–367

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey TM (2004) Classical deflation theory. Federal Res Bank Richmond Econ Quart 90(1):11–32

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM [1923] (2000) A tract on monetary reform. Prometheus Books, Amherst, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM [1925] (1963) The economic consequences of Mr. Churchill. Reprinted in Essays in persuasion. W.W. Norton & Company, New York, pp 244–270 (The original essay was printed in pamphlet form, with eds. Leonard Woolf and Virginia Woolf at the Hogarth Press)

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM [1930] (1971) A treatise on money. In Two Volumes. 1 The Pure Theory of Money. In The collected writings of John Maynard Keynes, vol 22. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM [1931] (1963) The consequences to the banks of the collapse of money values. In Essays in persuasion. W.W. Norton & Company, New York, pp 168–178

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM [1936] (1964) The general theory of employment, interest, and money. Harcourt, Brace & World, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman PR (1998) It’s Baaack: Japan’s slump and the return of the liquidity trap. Brook Pap Econ Act 29(2):137–187

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar MS, Baig T, Decressin J, Faulkner-MacDanagh C, Feyziogulu T (2003) Deflation: determinants, risks, and policy options. Occasional paper 221. IMF

    Google Scholar 

  • Laidler D (2000) Highlights of the bullionist controversy. Working paper 20002. University of Western Ontario

    Google Scholar 

  • Leigh D (2004) Monetary policy and the dangers of deflation: lessons from Japan. Economics working paper archive 511. The Johns Hopkins University

    Google Scholar 

  • Locke J [1691] (1824) Economic writings and two treatises of government (I). Vol. 4 of the works of John Locke, 12th edn. Rivington, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Manley T (1669) Usury at six per cent examined. London.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall A [1890] (1920) Principles of economy, 8th edn. Macmillan, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill JS (1844) The currency question. Westminst Rev 41:579–98

    Google Scholar 

  • Mill JS [1848] (1965) Principles of political economy with some of their applications to social philosophy, Bk. 1-5. University of Toronto Press, Toronto

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D [1810] (2004) The high price of Bullion. In: The works and correspondence of David Ricardo: Pamphlets and papers 1809-1811, vol 3, ed. Piero Sraffa with the collaboration of M.H. Dobb. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN, pp 47–127

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D [1816] (2004) Proposals for an economical and secure currency. In: The works and correspondence of David Ricardo: Pamphlets and papers 1815-1823, vol 4, ed. Piero Sraffa with the collaboration of M.H. Dobb. Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, IN, pp 43–141

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D [1817] (1973) On the principles of political economy and taxation. Dent & Sons, Dutton

    Google Scholar 

  • Rist C (1966) History of monetary and credit theory: from John Law to the present day. (trans: Degras J). Augustus M. Kelley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2006a) Economic thought before Adam Smith: an Austrian perspective of economic thought, vol I. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2006b) Classical economics. An Austrian perspective on the history of economic thought, vol II. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Sargent T, Wallace N (1976) Rational expectations and the theory of economic policy. J Monet Econ 2(2):169–183

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Say J-B (1845) A treatise on political economy: of the production, distribution and consumption of wealth (transl. from the 4th French ed. by C.R. Princep). Grigg & Elliot, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Scrope PG [1833] (1969) Principles of political economy. Deduced from the natural laws of social welfare and applied to the present state of Britain. Augustus M. Kelley, New York (reprint)

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1995) The “Productivity Norm” versus zero inflation in the history of economic thought. Hist Polit Econ 27(4):705–735

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1997) Less than zero: the case for a falling price level in a growing economy. The Institute for Economic Affairs, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1999) Hayek versus Keynes on how the price level ought to behave. Hist Polit Econ 31(4):699–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skidelsky R (2002) The Great Depression: Keynes’s Perspective. In: Harold J (ed) The interwar depression in an international context. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich, pp 99–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith A [1776] (1976) An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations. In: Campbell RH, Skinner AS (eds) The glasgow edition. Liberty Press, Indianapolis, IN

    Google Scholar 

  • Stamp J (1932) Papers on gold and the price level. P.S. King & Son, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (2003) Escaping from a liquidity trap and deflation: the foolproof way and others. J Econ Perspect 17(4):145–166

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Svensson LEO (2000) How should monetary policy be conducted in an era of price stability? NBER working paper 7516. Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Thornton H [1802] (1978) An enquiry into the nature and effects of the paper credit of Great Britain. Augustus M. Kelley, New Jersey, NY (reprint)

    Google Scholar 

  • Torrens R (1834/1970) On wages and combinations. Reprints of economic classics. A.M. Kelley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner J (1975) Studies in the theory of international trade. August M. Kelley, Clifton, NJ (reprint)

    Google Scholar 

  • Warren GF, Pearson FA (1933) Prices. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell K [1898] (1968) Geldzins und Güterpreise: Eine Studie über die den Tauschwert des Geldes bestimmenden Ursachen. Scientia Verlag, Aalen (Corrected reprint)

    Google Scholar 

  • Yeager LB (1986) The significance of monetary disequilibrium. Cato J 6(2):369–399

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bagus, P. (2015). Economic Theories of Deflation. In: In Defense of Deflation. Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, vol 41. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-13428-4_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics