Skip to main content

Welfare Impact of Changes in the Scope of the USO

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Postal and Delivery Innovation in the Digital Economy

Part of the book series: Topics in Regulatory Economics and Policy ((TREP,volume 50))

Abstract

Estimating the cost of the Universal Service Obligation (USO) is becoming increasingly important in the regulation of the postal business. At least 13 Member States have calculated or are calculating the net cost of USO (Frontier Economics 2013). Out of the six countries reporting that the net cost of the USO was an unfair burden (CZ, EE, ES, IT, LT, NO), in four of them (ES, IT, PL, NO) public funding was used to finance the net cost (WIK 2013). When funded with revenues from the industry, one can argue that postal users are paying for the costs of the USO. When funded externally, the taxpayer is foregoing the provision of other public services.

The opinions expressed here are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of Frontier Economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    It may look somehow inconsistent that the authors find that removing Saturday delivery would reduce welfare but reducing delivery to 3 days a week would increase welfare. However if the cost savings of moving to 3 days delivery are much bigger than the cost savings of removing Saturday delivery (the authors find that they are around 3 times larger), this could actually be the case. In addition, one could expect that the benefit from Saturday delivery is different from that of other weekdays for senders (weekend promotions, targeted marketing, etc.) and receivers (physical presence on delivery).

  2. 2.

    We use two ways to present the net USO costs. When presenting the results of our scenario we’re using the common measure of the net USO cost relative to the total cost. When comparing against the WTP, we’re converting to a unit cost per mail item.

  3. 3.

    The different directions of the impact are the result of two effects. As the share of the population in rural areas increases, the number of delivery points in the counterfactual required to cover this area increases. For 100 m, the number of delivery points is reduced by 97 % in the case of 3 % rural population while it is only reduced by 82 % when 60 % of the population lives in rural areas. For 1,000 m the difference in the decrease of delivery points when the share of the rural population increases from 3 to 60 % is only 0.15 % points (i.e. 99.97 and 99.82 % respectively). This implies that the 1,000 m counterfactual scenario does not face significant extra costs for covering the increased rural area that would counterbalance the saving from moving to that scenario in more rural countries.

  4. 4.

    Under uniform pricing, a postal operator may not be able to fully recover the cost of the change in the USO scope due to some customers with WTP below the average not being willing to pay the average WTP. Recoverability therefore depends on the difference between WTP and net USO costs (a large difference suggests that costs can be recovered through charging less than the WTP) or the ability of the postal operator to price discriminate.

  5. 5.

    The WTP for an increase from 3 to 6 days is calculated as the sum of the WTP of 3 to 5 days and 5 to 6 days.

  6. 6.

    We note that in the following charts we have selected the lower bound of the WTP for delivery location. WTP estimates for this USO feature can be as high as 0.7€/item for delivery at home with respect to delivery at 100 m and 0.9€/item to avoid delivery at 1,000 m. With these alternative estimates, the WTP would be above the NUC.

References

  • Accent. (2008). Postal universal service obligation: Value to the citizen. Prepared for Postwatch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carslake, I., Houpis, G., & Strobel, C. (2014). The net cost of the USO under the profitability cost approach: Implications of labor market conditions for the net cost calculation. In M. A. Crew & T. J. Brennan (Eds.), The role of postal service in a digital age. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cazals, C., Florens, J.-P., & Roy, B. (2001). An analysis of some specific cost drivers in the delivery activity. In M. A. Crew & P. R. Kleindorfer (Eds.), Future direction in postal reform (Topics in regulatory economics and policy, pp. 197–212). Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Copenhagen Economics. (2010). Main developments in the postal sector (2008–2010). Prepared for Internal Market and Services DG MARKET (EC).

    Google Scholar 

  • Crew, M. A., & Kleindorfer, P. R. (1998). Efficient entry, monopoly, and the universal service obligation in postal service. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 14(2), 103–125.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frontier Economics. (2013). Study on the principles used to calculate the net costs of the postal USO. A report prepared for the European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hearn, J., Cigno, M., Forslund, L., Grazell, J., Knott, G., Penris, W., Rosenstok, J., & Waller, J. (2010). Allocating the cost of delivery to postal products: principles and practice. 18th conference on postal and delivery economics, Porvoo, Finland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jaag, C., & Trinkner, U. (2011). The future of the USO – Economic rationale for universal services and implications for a future-oriented USO. Swiss Economics Working Paper 0026.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindhjem, H., & Pedersen, S. (2012). Should publicly funded postal services be reduced? A cost-benefit analysis of the universal service obligation in Norway. Review of Network Economics, 11(2) Article 3.

    Google Scholar 

  • List, J. A., & Gallet, C. A. (2001). What experimental protocol influence disparities between actual and hypothetical stated values? International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 20, 241–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murphy, J. J., Allen, P. G., Stevens, T. H., & Weatherhead, D. (2005). A meta-analysis of hypothetical bias in stated preference valuation. International Review of Environmental and Resource Economics, 30, 313–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • NERA. (1998). Costing and financing of universal service obligations in the postal sector in the European Union. Final report for DG XIII. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • NERA. (2004). Economics of postal services: Final report. Prepared for the European Commission DG-MARKT.

    Google Scholar 

  • RAND Europe. (2011). Study on appropriate methodologies to better measure consumer preferences for postal services. Prepared for Internal Market and Services DG MARKT (EC).

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, B. (1999). Technico-economic analysis of the costs of outside work in postal delivery. In M. A. Crew & P. R. Kleindorfer (Eds.), Emerging competition in postal and delivery services. Boston: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veruete-McKay, L., Sheldon, R., Burge, P., & Lawrence, A. (2013). Electronic substitution and postal price elasticities: a customer market approach. In M. A. Crew & P. R. Kleindorfer (Eds.), Reforming The Postal Sector In The Face Of Electronic Competition. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • WIK Consult. (2013). Main developments in the postal sector (2010–2013). Internal Market and Services DG MARKT (EC).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to George Houpis .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Houpis, G., Rodríguez, J.M., Strobel, C. (2015). Welfare Impact of Changes in the Scope of the USO. In: Crew, M., Brennan, T. (eds) Postal and Delivery Innovation in the Digital Economy. Topics in Regulatory Economics and Policy, vol 50. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12874-0_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics