Skip to main content

Introduction: The End of an Era

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Beyond GDP

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Energy ((LNEN,volume 26))

  • 813 Accesses

Abstract

We are entering a new era in which biophysical limits related to natural resource extraction rates and the biosphere's waste assimilation capacity are becoming binding constraints on mature economies. Unfortunately, the data needed for policy-makers to understand and manage economic growth in the new era are not universally available. In this chapter, we discuss the problems that arise from relying solely on the Solow growth model to describe an economy that is, in reality, deeply interconnected with the biosphere. We point out that mainstream economists forecast low growth rates for mature economies for the foreseeable future, because traditional drivers of economic growth (growth rates of capital and labor productivity) have plateaued. Unfortunately, mainstream policy recommendations to reinvigorate growth, based on the Solow growth model, ignore three critical realities: the economy is tightly coupled to the biosphere, there exist real and binding physical and technological limits to the rate at which materials and energy can be extracted from the biosphere, and today’s emplacement of manufactured capital locks in tomorrow’s material and energy demands from the biosphere. As such, mainstream policy recommendations are likely to fail in the long run: today’s expansion of the stock of capital in the economy in the hopes of enhancing consumption can contribute to the slowdown of economic growth by bringing us ever-closer to biophysical limits. The chapter ends by noting that we need a new way to understand our economy, and we suggest that detailed information about materials, energy, embodied energy, and energy intensity be routinely gathered and analyzed and disseminated from a centralized location to provide markets and policymakers with more-complete knowledge of the biophysical economy.

However, a firm theoretical underpinning is needed before proceeding along this new path, and the remainder of this book provides a rigorous theoretical framework for a better system of national accounts, one that goes beyond GDP and one that is relevant to the age of resource depletion.

Where there is no reliable accounting and therefore no competent knowledge of the economic and ecological effects of our lives, we cannot live lives that are economically and ecologically responsible. It is futile to plead and protest and lobby in favor of public ecological responsibility while, in virtually every act of our private lives, we endorse and support an economic system that is by intention, and perhaps by necessity, ecologically irresponsible. [1, p. 26]

—Wendell Berry

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The mainstream model for economic growth is encapsulated in the Cobb–Douglas production function, which takes the mathematical form

    $$ y = A k^{\alpha} l^{1-\alpha},$$

    where y is the economic output, A is the technological progress, k is the capital stock, l is the labor, α is the factor share of capital, and \(1-\alpha\) is the factor share for labor.

  2. 2.

    Natural areas provide ecosystem services such as water purification, carbon sequestration, and erosion control.

  3. 3.

    In this context, we are using the term “biophysical factors” to indicate any factor related to the extraction, transport, processing, manipulation, and disposal of the physical (as opposed to financial) manifestation of any material or energy resource in the economy.

  4. 4.

    Of course, mainstream economics discusses prices of raw materials, goods, and services. And, to the extent that biophysical factors affect prices, it could be said that mainstream economic discussions involve biophysical factors. However, biophysical factors are rarely acknowledged as causal for establishing the prices of goods and services and the raw materials of which they are comprised.

  5. 5.

    The mathematical definition of elasticity of supply (E s ) is

    $$ E_s \equiv \frac{\frac{1}{Q}\frac{\partial Q}{\partial t}} {\frac{1}{P}\frac{\partial P}{\partial t}},$$

    where Q is quantity of production, P is price, and t is time.

  6. 6.

    That is, a 1 % change in the oil price will generate only a 0.04 % increase in oil supply. A price elasticity of 0.04 is extremely low (inelastic). For comparison, agricultural output is also considered fairly price inelastic in the short-run, but Pandey, et al. estimate the short-run (2-year) price elasticity of supply of Australian agricultural output to be around 0.30 [23, p. 215].

  7. 7.

    Mathematically, energy cost share (f E ) is defined as

    $$ f_E \equiv \frac{1}{GDP} \displaystyle\sum_i P_i Q_i,$$

    where the subscript i indicates types of energy (electricity, gasoline, natural gas, etc.), P indicates the price of energy, Q indicates the quantity of energy purchased within the economy, and GDP is gross domestic product.

  8. 8.

    Note that “destruction of energy demand” is accomplished through recession in the short run.

  9. 9.

    Like increasing oil production, increasing energy efficiency also has physical and technological limits. Improving energy efficiency is a medium- to long-term process.

  10. 10.

    Embarking on an economic growth path appears to reduce the energy cost share in an economy from very high values (indicating that nearly all economic activity is focused on procuring energy) to small values that remain within a stable range. For example, Sweden’s energy cost share has stabilized at 12 % since 1970, although it was nearly 100 % in 1800 [26].

  11. 11.

    Energy return on investment (EROI soc ) at the societal level is defined as

    $$ EROI_{soc} \equiv \frac{\dot{E}_a}{\dot{E}_c},$$

    where \(\dot{E}_a\) is the rate of energy made available to society in MJ/year and \(\dot{E}_c\) is the rate of energy consumed in the energy production process in MJ/year. Note that this definition of EROI soc is flow based. Other definitions of EROI are accounted over the full lifetime of a project, e.g., comparing the lifetime electricity generation of a wind turbine to the energy required in its manufacture (including extraction of raw materials), installation, operation, and decommission.

  12. 12.

    Of course, in any deck of cards there are two Red Queens. In Sect. 8.2.2, we discuss the need to increasingly divert production to maintain levels of capital stock.

  13. 13.

    Nuclear, conventional hydroelectric power, wood and waste biomass, geothermal, solar/photovoltaic, and wind.

  14. 14.

    Coal, petroleum, natural gas, and other gasses.

  15. 15.

    Free cash flow is defined as the cash produced by a firm’s operations less the cost of expanding its asset base. Free cash flow is different from profit, and is thought to be a more-reliable indicator of the ability of a firm to produce profit.

  16. 16.

    See Chap. 5 for more details on embodied energy.

  17. 17.

    See Chap. 7 for more details on energy intensity.

  18. 18.

    More on the problematic nature of this oversight can be found in Chap. 2.

  19. 19.

    Manufactured capital presupposes the existence of sufficient levels of human and social capital.

  20. 20.

    Energy consumption rates are routinely published by the US Energy Information Agency (EIA) and the International Energy Agency (IEA).

  21. 21.

    See Sect. 8.2 for our suggested remedy.

References

  1. Berry W. The whole horse: agrarianism is a culture at the same time as it is an economy. Resurgence. May/June 1998;(188):26–31.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Organisation for Economic Co-Operation and Development OECD economic outlook, Vol. 2014, Issue 1, volume 2014 of OECD economic outlook. OECD Publishing; June 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  3. Congressional Budget Office. The budget and economic outlook: 2014 to 2024. Technical Report 4869; February 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  4. World Bank. GDP per capita (current US$). URL. Accessed 24 August 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Simon J. The state of humanity, 1 edn. Wiley-Blackwell; January 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  6. Cowen T. The great stagnation: how America ate all the low-hanging fruit of modern history, got sick, and will(eventually) feel better. Dutton Adult; June 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Lindsey B. Why growth is getting harder. Technical report, Cato Institute. October 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  8. Ayres RU, Warr BS. The economic growth engine: how energy and work drive material propserity. Cheltenham:Edward Elgar; 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  9. Boulding KE. The economics of the coming spaceship earth. Environ qual grow Econ. 1966;2:3–14.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Boyd R. Energy and the financial system: what every economist, financial analyst, and investor needs to know. New York:Springer; 2013.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  11. Cleveland CJ, Costanza R, Hall CAS. Energy and the US Economy: a biophysical perspective. Science. 1984;225(31 August):890–97.

    Google Scholar 

  12. Daly HE. Steady-state economics. San Francisco;1977.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Fix B. Rethinking growth theory from a biophysical perspective. (In press). New York:Springer; 2014.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Hall CAS, Klitgaard KA. Energy and the wealth of nations: understanding the biophysical economy. New York:Springer; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Kopits S. Oil: what price can America afford? Research note, Douglas-Westwood Energy Business Analysts, New York; 22 June 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Fischer-Kowalski M, Hüttler W. Society’s metabolism. J Ind Ecol. 1999;2(4):107–36.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  17. Ayres RU. Turning point: the end of the growth paradigm. Working Paper 96/49/EPS, INSEAD’s Centre for the Management of Environmental Resource; July 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  18. United Nations, European Commission, International Monetary Fund, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, and World Bank. System of national accounts 2008. United Nations, New York; 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  19. United Nations University International Human Dimensions Programme and United Nations Environment Programme. Inclusive wealth report 2012: measuring progress toward sustainability. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge; July 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Falconer D. Gasoline shortage 06/1973. http://arcweb.archives.gov/arc/action/ExternalIdSearch?id=548053. June 1973.

  21. Hamilton JD. Oil prices, exhaustible resources, and economic growth. In Handbook on energy and climate change. Edward Elgar; 2013. p. 29–63.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Energy Information Administration. International Energy Statistics. Technical report, US Energy Information Administration; 2014. http://www.eia.gov/countries. Accessed 17 April 2014.

  23. Pandey S, Piggott RR, MacAulay TG. The elasticity of aggregate australian agricultural supply: estimates and policy implications. Aust J Agric Econ. 1982;26(3):202–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Bashmakov I. Three laws of energy transitions. Energy Policy. July 2007;35(7):3583–94.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Murphy DJ, Hall CAS. Energy return on investment, peak oil, and the end of economic growth. Ann New York Acad Sci. February 2011;1219(1):52–72.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Stern DI, Kander A. The role of energy in the industrial revolution and modern economic growth. Energy J. July 2012;33(3):125–52.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Ayres RU, van den Bergh JCJM, Lindenbergerf D, Warr B. The underestimated contribution of energy to economic growth. Struct Chang Econ Dyn. 2013;27:79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  28. Cleveland CJ. Natural resource quality. In: Costanza R, editor, The encyclopedia of Earth. Energy; 2008.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Dale MAJ. Global energy modeling: a biophysical approach (GEMBA). University of Canterbury, Christchurch, New Zealand; 2010

    Google Scholar 

  30. Hall CAS, Cleveland CJ, Kaufman R. Energy and resource quality: the ecology of the economic process. John Wiley & Sons; 1986.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Mudd GM. The environmental sustainability of mining in australia: key mega-trends and looming constraints. Resour Policy. 2010;35(2):98–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Brandt AR. Oil depletion and the energy efficiency of oil production: the case of california. Sustainability. 2011;3(10):1833–54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Guilford MC, Hall CAS, Connor PO, Cleveland CJ. A new long term assessment of energy return on investment (EROI) for U.S. oil and gas discovery and production. Sustainability. October 2011;3(10):1866–87.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Gagnon N, Hall CAS, Brinker L. A preliminary investigation of energy return on energy investment for global oil and gas production. Energies. July 2009;2:490–503.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Ross JE. The red queen syndrome: running faster–going nowhere? Environment and Development: Building Sustainable Societies. Lectures from the1987 Summer Forum at the University of Wisconsin-Madison; 1988. 67 p.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Heun MK, de Wit M. Energy Return on (Energy) Invested (EROI), Oil Prices, and Energy Transitions. Energy Policy. January 2012;40(C):147–58.

    Google Scholar 

  37. King CW and Hall CAS. Relating Financial and Energy Return on Investment. Sustainability, October 2011;3(10):1810–32.

    Google Scholar 

  38. Pelli M. The Elasticity of Substitution between Clean and Dirty Inputs in the Production of Electricity. In Proceedings of the Conference on Sustainable Resource Use and Economic Dynamics (SURED 2012), Ascona, Switzerland; 4–7 June 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  39. de Wit M, Heun MK, Crookes D. An overview of salient factors, relationships, and values to support integrated energy-economic systems dynamic modelling. Working Paper 02/13, Department of Economics and the Bureau for Economic Research at the University of Stellenbosch, Stellenbosch, South Africa; February 2013.

    Google Scholar 

  40. US Energy Information Agency. As cash flow flattens, major energy companies increase debt, sell assets. Today In Energy; 2014. http://www.eia.gov/todayinenergy/detail.cfm?id=17311. Accessed 22 Jan 2015.

  41. Krauss C. Despite slumping prices, no end in sight for (U.S.) oil production boom, The New York Times. 17 October 2014;B3.

    Google Scholar 

  42. Krauss C. (U.S.) Oil producers cut rigs as price declines, The New York Times. 8 January 2015;B1.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Corkery M and Eavis P. As oil prices fall, banks serving the energy industry brace for a Jolt, New York Times. 12 January 2015;B1.

    Google Scholar 

  44. Vlasic B and Trop J. Vehicle Fuel Efficiency Reaches a High, Nearing Goal for 2016. New York Times. http://www.nytimes.com/2013/09/11/business/energy-environment/fuel-economy-hits-six-year-high.html. Accessed 11 Sept. 2013.

  45. Bullard CW and Herendeen RA. The energy cost of goods and services. Energy Policy. 1975;3(4):268–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Carnegie Mellon University Green Design Institute. Economic Input-Output Life Cycle Assessment (EIO-LCA) US 1997 Industry Benchmark model. http://www.eiolca.net. Accessed 1 Jan 2014.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Matthew Kuperus Heun .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Heun, M., Carbajales-Dale, M., Haney, B. (2015). Introduction: The End of an Era. In: Beyond GDP. Lecture Notes in Energy, vol 26. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12820-7_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12820-7_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-12819-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-12820-7

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics