Skip to main content

Social and Economic Network Formation: A Dynamic Model

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Combinatorial Optimization and Applications (COCOA 2014)

Part of the book series: Lecture Notes in Computer Science ((LNTCS,volume 8881))

Abstract

We study the dynamics of a game-theoretic network formation model that yields large-scale small-world networks. So far, mostly stochastic frameworks have been utilized to explain the emergence of these networks. On the other hand, it is natural to seek for game-theoretic network formation models in which links are formed due to strategic behaviors of individuals, rather than based on probabilities. Inspired by Even-Dar and Kearns’ model [8], we consider a more realistic framework in which the cost of establishing each link is dynamically determined during the course of the game. Moreover, players are allowed to put transfer payments on the formation and maintenance of links. Also, they must pay a maintenance cost to sustain their direct links during the game. We show that there is a small diameter of at most 4 in the general set of equilibrium networks in our model. We achieved an economic mechanism and its dynamic process for individuals which firstly; unlike the earlier model, the outcomes of players’ interactions or the equilibrium networks are guaranteed to exist. Furthermore, these networks coincide with the outcome of pairwise Nash equilibrium in network formation. Secondly; it generates large-scale networks that have a rational and strategic microfoundation and demonstrate the main characterization of small degree of separation in real-life social networks. Furthermore, we provide a network formation simulation that generates small-world networks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The principle that individuals are all linked by short chains of connections and acquaintances.

  2. 2.

    The pairwise stability is the major notion of stability that assumes myopic players and has been studied in related literature. In a linking game with transfers, it was first introduced as an extension in [15] and then developed in [2, 3].

  3. 3.

    Computing the best responses of players in Nash equilibria within some similar models [9, 18] are proved to be NP-hard.

  4. 4.

    See [24, 11].

  5. 5.

    It can be seen that the condition for ruling out the potential cycles from [13] can be adapted in our linking game with transfers.

  6. 6.

    This assumption is reasonable in our framework, since the formation of other links cannot hurt the utility of non-involved players with respect to the distance-based structure of our utility function in (1).

  7. 7.

    See e.g. [3, 9, 15] for some application instances of distance-based payoff structures.

  8. 8.

    See [1, 10] for some instances of study in the case of bargaining between players on network. In fact, despite the rich literature in general for bargaining between players, bargaining on networks is in its early attempts.

  9. 9.

    This condition is denoted as exact pairwise monotonicity by Jackson and Watts.

  10. 10.

    Note that although the existence of stable networks and convergence to the Nash outcomes would not be guaranteed in this assumption, we achieved a set of link stable networks by implementing many trials for different sets of \(\alpha \) and \(c\).

References

  1. Bayati, M., Borgs, C., Chayes, J., Kanoria, Y., Montanari, A.: Bargaining dynamics in exchange networks. In: ACM-SIAM Symposium on Discrete Algorithms, pp. 1518–1537 (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  2. Bloch, F., Jackson, M.O.: Definitions of equilibrium in network formation games. Int. J. Game Theory 34(3), 305–318 (2006)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  3. Bloch, F., Jackson, M.O.: The formation of networks with transfers among players. J. Econom. Theory 133(1), 83–110 (2007)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  4. Calvó-Armengol, A., Ilkiliç, R.: Pairwise-stability and nash equilibria in network formation. Int. J. Game Theory 38(1), 51–79 (2009)

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  5. Chakrabarti, S., Gilles, R.: Network potentials. Rev. Econom. Des. 11(1), 13–52 (2007)

    MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  6. Daraghmi, E.Y., Yuan, S.: We are so close, less than 4 degrees separating you and me!. Comput. Hum. Behav. 30, 273–285 (2014)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. de Martí, J., Zenou, Y.: Social networks. IFN Working Paper No. 816 (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  8. Even-Dar, E., Kearns, M.: A small world threshold for economic network formation. Adv. Neural Inf. Process. Syst. 19, 385–392 (2007)

    Google Scholar 

  9. Fabrikant, A., Luthra, A., Maneva, E.N., Papadimitriou, C.H., Shenker, S.: On a network creation game. In: 22nd Annual ACM Symposium on Principles of Distributed Computing, pp. 347–351 (2003)

    Google Scholar 

  10. Gallo, E.: Essays in the economics of networks. Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Oxford (2011)

    Google Scholar 

  11. Hellman, T.: On the existence and uniqueness of pairwise stable networks. Int. J. Game Theory 42, 211–237 (2012)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  12. Jackson, M.O.: Social and Economic Networks. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ (2008)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  13. Jackson, M.O., Watts, A.: The existence of pairwise stable networks. Seoul J. Econom. 14(3), 299–321 (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  14. Jackson, M.O., Watts, A.: The evolution of social and economic networks. J. Econom. Theory 106, 265–295 (2002)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  15. Jackson, M.O., Wolinsky, A.: A strategic model of social and economic networks. J. Econom. Theory 71, 44–74 (1996)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  16. Kleinberg, J.: The small-world phenomenon: An algorithmic perspective. In: 32nd Annual ACM Symposium on the Theory of Computing, pp. 163–170 (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  17. Milgram, S.: The small world problem. Psychol. Today 1, 61–67 (1967)

    Google Scholar 

  18. Myerson, R.: Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA (1991)

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  19. Watts, A.: A dynamic model of network formation. Games Econom. Behav. 34, 331–341 (2001)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  20. Watts, D., Strogatz, S.: Collective dynamics of small-world networks. Nature 393, 440–442 (1998)

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Omid Atabati .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix: Omitted Proofs

Appendix: Omitted Proofs

Proof of Lemma 2

The proof is inspired by the arguments in [10]. First, we show the related inequality in Definition 5 holds for the case when the subset \(l_i(G)\) consists of two distinct links \(ij\) and \(ik\), which is indicated in below inequality.

$$\begin{aligned} mu_i(G, ij+ik) \ge mu_i(G, ij) + mu_i(G, ik) \end{aligned}$$
(5)

If we consider any player such as u in network \(G\), the distance between \(i\) and u (\(d_G(i,u)\)) contributes to the distance expenses in \(i\)’s utility. It is important to note that removing any link such as \(ij\) or \(ik\) from the network \(G\) cannot decrease this distance, however if the removed link belongs to the shortest path between \(i\) and u in \(G\), then the distance would be increased. This argument can be extended to removing two links such as \(ij\) and \(ik\) from \(G\).

$$\begin{aligned} d_G(i,u) \le d_{G-ij}(i,u) \le d_{G-ij-ik}(i,u) \end{aligned}$$
(6)
$$\begin{aligned} d_G(i,u) \le d_{G-ik}(i,u) \le d_{G-ij-ik}(i,u) \end{aligned}$$
(7)

In computing the marginal utilities of networks \(G-ik, G-ij\), and \(G-ij-ik\), we should note that the link-prices of removed links cannot be refunded for player \(i\).

$$\begin{aligned} mu_i(G, ij) = - \sum _{u \ne i} ( d_{G}(i,u) - d_{G-ij}(i,u) ) - c_{ij} - t_{ij}^i \end{aligned}$$
(8)
$$\begin{aligned} mu_i(G, ik) = - \sum _{u \ne i} ( d_{G}(i,u) - d_{G-ik}(i,u) ) - c_{ik} - t_{ik}^i \end{aligned}$$
(9)
$$\begin{aligned} mu_i(G, ij+ik) = - \sum _{u \ne i} ( d_{G}(i,u) - d_{G-ij-ik}(i,u) ) - c_{ij} - c_{ik} - t_{ij}^i - t_{ik}^i \end{aligned}$$
(10)

According to Inequalities (6) and (7), we can simply imply the Inequality (5). Moreover, we can easily extend this argument for any subset of links \(l_i(G)\).       \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 4

The set \(S_i^d\) consists of players in the neighborhood of \(i\) within a distance at most \(d\). Furthermore, for each of these players such as \(k\) in the set \( S_i^d\), according to Lemma 3, we consider the set \(T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)\). All players outside of this set should use one of players such as \(k\) in their shortest path to \(i\). As a result, we can cover all players outside the set \(S_i^d\) by allocating a set \(T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)\) to \(i\) for all players in set \(S_i^d\). By doing so, an upper bound of \(|T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)||S_i^d| + |S_i^d|\) for the number players in network (\(n\)) is achieved.

In order to obtain an upper bound for the set \(T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)\) in wide range of different possible choices for \(i\) and \(k\), we define \(c\) to be the maximum maintenance cost for all possible links in network. According to Remark 1, this is an upper bound for the all possible direct transfer payments in network as well, hence, \(|T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)|\le \dfrac{d^\alpha + 2c}{d-1}\). By substituting the upper bounds of \(T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)\) and \(S_i^d\) in \(|T_{G(\mathbf t )}(i,k)||S_i^d|+|S_i^d|\ge n\), the desired inequality can be achieved.       \(\square \)

Proof of Lemma 5

Let \(G\) be an arbitrary instance from the set of equilibrium networks in our model, which are the set of pairwise stable networks with transfer (\(G\in PS^t(u)\)), given the utility function \(u(.)\) in (1). Also, let \(\mathbf t \) be the profile of strategies for players that forms \(G\). Further, assume that the largest distance between any two players (or diameter) in network \(G\) exists between two players \(i\) and \(j\). We denote \(\Delta \) to be the size this distance. Note that the pair of \(i\) and \(j\) is not necessarily unique.

Based on the stable state, we can imply that creation \(ij\) is not beneficial for neither \(i\) nor \(j\). If \(j\) wants to establish a link to \(i\), the left side of Inequality (12) is a lower bound for the \(j\)’s benefit that comes from the reduced distances to players in \(S_i^2\). This set includes \(i\) itself and two subsets of players that are in distance 1 (type 1) and 2 (type 2) from \(i\). First, let \(k\) represents players in \(S_i^2\) such that their distances to \(j\) can be reduced by adding \(ij\), as a fraction with respect to all players in \(|S_i^2|\). Moreover, let \(h_1\) represents player \(i\) itself as a fraction with respect to all players in \(|S_i^2|\). By establishing \(ij\), \(j\)’s distance to \(i\) reduced by \(\Delta -1\).

Furthermore, let \(h_2\) and \(h_3\) represent the fractions of the number of type 1 players and type 2 players, respectively, in \(S_i^2\). Their reduced distances for \(j\) is computed according to the initial distances of these two types of players in \(S_i^2\) from \(j\). Among the type 1 players, there are two subsets of players that \(g_1\) and \(g_2\) are their fractions with distance of \(\Delta -1\) and \(\Delta \) from \(j\), respectively. Furthermore, in type 2 players, there are three subsets of players in terms of their distance from \(j\) with fractions of \(f_1, f_2, f_3\) that are in distance of \(\Delta -2, \Delta -1, \Delta \) from \(j\), respectively.

$$\begin{aligned} k|S_i^2|\bigg (h_1(\Delta -1)&+ h_2\Big (g_1 (\Delta -3) + g_2(\Delta -2)\Big ) + h_3\Big (f_1 (\Delta -5) + f_2(\Delta -4) + f_3 (\Delta -3)\Big )\bigg )\nonumber \\&\le \Delta ^ \alpha + c_{ji} + t_{ij}^{j} \le \Delta ^ \alpha + 2c \end{aligned}$$
(11)
$$\begin{aligned} \implies |S_i^2| \le \Delta ^ \alpha + 2c \Big / k\bigg ( \Delta - \Big ( h_1+h_2(g_1 + 2)+h_3 (2f_1 + f_2 + 3) \Big ) \bigg ) \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where

$$\begin{aligned} 0<f_1+f_2+f_3=g_1+g_2=h_1+h_2+h_3=1, \text { and } 0\le k, f_i, g_i, h_i\le 1. \end{aligned}$$
(13)

      \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this paper

Cite this paper

Atabati, O., Farzad, B. (2014). Social and Economic Network Formation: A Dynamic Model. In: Zhang, Z., Wu, L., Xu, W., Du, DZ. (eds) Combinatorial Optimization and Applications. COCOA 2014. Lecture Notes in Computer Science(), vol 8881. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12691-3_43

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-12691-3_43

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-12690-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-12691-3

  • eBook Packages: Computer ScienceComputer Science (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics