Skip to main content

Why Do We Need Responsive Regulation and Behavioural Research in EU Internal Market Law?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
European Perspectives on Behavioural Law and Economics

Part of the book series: Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship ((EALELS,volume 2))

Abstract

Due to its intrinsic need to establish an internal market even against the nation states’ will, EU law has always had to rely on the responsiveness of its peoples in order to make the establishment of the internal market a success. As to this need, top-down macro-economic regulation without a social bottom-up backup by the peoples of Europe has mostly failed. This creates a “legitimacy market failure” of the EU internal market, which needs to be cured by responsive regulation. Data gained from behavioural research are the right tools to cure such a market failure in EU internal market law. The provision of hard data from behavioural research is the most promising way to do so as it leaves room for Member States to behave opportunistically only if they present more convincing data. By combining responsive regulation and behavioural economics, the EU is able to first listen to its people and second incentivize Member States to act in the best interest for its peoples and the internal market.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See e.g. European Governance—A white paper, COM(2001) 428 final; Mandelkern Group on Better Regulation, Final Report, 13 November 2001 and the articles in S. Weatherill (ed.) Better Regulation (Oxford 2007); as well as Allio 2011; McColm 2011; Radaelli 2007; Wiener 2006.

  2. 2.

    Ackermann 2007, p. 9.

  3. 3.

    See Nourse and Shaffer 2009, pp. 61–138; Miles and Sunstein 2013, p. 81; critical Leiter 2013.

  4. 4.

    Nourse and Shaffer 2009, pp. 88–90.

  5. 5.

    Nourse and Shaffer 2009, pp. 76–77.

  6. 6.

    See Macneil 2000, p. 697.

  7. 7.

    Simon 2006.

  8. 8.

    Black and Baldwin 2010. The link between new governance theories and responsive regulation was also illustrated by Walker and de Búrca: “New Governance is seen as a highly pragmatic and flexible approach to and modality of regulation, a method for ensuring maximum responsiveness and adaptability, with an emphasis on open-ended and provisional goals, and ensuring revisability and corrigibility,” see Walker and de Búrca 2007.

  9. 9.

    Bizer and Führ 2002, p. 5.

  10. 10.

    Nourse and Shaffer 2009, p. 77.

  11. 11.

    Nourse and Shaffer 2009, p. 77.

  12. 12.

    This distinction is, of course, a simplification. (Neo-) classical law and economics likewise knows a number of market failures which enable “social” regulation, which also translate into internal market law, see Franck and Purnhagen 2014, p. 332.

  13. 13.

    Jolls and Sunstein 2007.

  14. 14.

    See on the term and the parameters affiliated with it Black and Baldwin 2010.

  15. 15.

    The difference between input and output legitimacy date back to the work of Easton 1965 and have been advanced mainly by Scharpf 1970; Scharpf 1997; Scharpf 1999.

  16. 16.

    Scharpf 1999, p. 7.

  17. 17.

    Scharpf 1999, p. 7.

  18. 18.

    Bekkers and Edwards 2007, p. 35.

  19. 19.

    See on the term “domain” Dyson 2014, pp. 115–137.

  20. 20.

    See especially Danielsson-Tham et al. 2004, p. 153. There are also studies which have proven that these threats may also come from consuming pasteurized milk, see Koch et al. 2010, p. 1581.

  21. 21.

    See especially Art. 3 of Council Directive 92/46/EEC of 16 June 1992 laying down the health rules for the production and placing on the market of raw milk, heat-treated milk and milk-based products. See for the USA FDA, The Dangers of Raw Milk: Unpasteurized Milk Can Pose a Serious Health Risk, available at http://www.fda.gov/downloads/Food/FoodborneIllnessContaminants/UCM239493.pdf.

  22. 22.

    See Art. 3 of Council Directive 92/46/EEC of 16 June 1992 laying down the health rules for the production and placing on the market of raw milk, heat-treated milk and milk-based products.

  23. 23.

    See Downes 2014, p. 113.

  24. 24.

    See for a comprehensive study on the the regulative practice at that time Joerges et al. 1988, 252 et seqq.

  25. 25.

    See Tricker 2000, p.  1; Hey, Jacob and Volkery 2007, p. 1861.

  26. 26.

    McGee and Weatherill 1990, p. 583.

  27. 27.

    McGee and Weatherill 1990, p. 582.

  28. 28.

    Purnhagen 2014b, p. 318.

  29. 29.

    See for further assessment into the challenges of regulation of new technology products van der Meulen et al. 2014, pp. 1–2.

  30. 30.

    van der Meulen et al. 2014, pp. 1–2.

  31. 31.

    van der Meulen et al. 2014, pp. 1–2.

  32. 32.

    See for a more thorough analysis Grossman 2012.

  33. 33.

    Office of Science and Technology Policy (OSTP), Coordinated Framework for Regulation of Biotechnology Products, 51 Fed. Reg. 23,302 (26 June 1986), p. 23.

  34. 34.

    Some States such as Maine currently consider enacting special requirements of labelling law.

  35. 35.

    See for an old (and therefore with regards to the legal regulations largely outdated), but on the substance still valid observation Lynch and Vogel 2001; for a more recent one Pollack and Shaffer 2009, pp. 45–77.

  36. 36.

    Pollack and Shaffer 2009, pp. 45–52.

  37. 37.

    Krystallis et al. 2007.

  38. 38.

    See Valletta 2010.

  39. 39.

    In political science, this has been investigated as a gap between input and output legitimacy, see Skogstad 2003, p. 321.

  40. 40.

    Eberlein 2004, pp. 153–155.

  41. 41.

    Weiler 2005.

  42. 42.

    See Weiler 2005.

  43. 43.

    Patterson and Afilalo 2008, pp. 148–160.

  44. 44.

    Lenaerts 2004.

  45. 45.

    Eberlein 2004, pp. 153–155.

  46. 46.

    Binding and Purnhagen 2011, p. 187.

  47. 47.

    By that time admittedly mainly preliminary forms of the Internet making use of distance communication such as Teletext existed.

  48. 48.

    See for an overview over the debate Keller 2004, pp. 1, 10–16; Marsden 2011, pp. 47–50.

  49. 49.

    See on the relationship between Member State inaction and EU policy in the area of consumer protection, Micklitz 2001.

  50. 50.

    Directive 97/7/EC has meanwhile been replaced by the Directive on Consumer Rights 2011/83/EC. As this argument draws from the historical right to withdrawal in Directive 97/7/EC, I will nonetheless build my argument on the outdated Directive.

  51. 51.

    Recently, scholars start to investigate whether the withdrawal right could be justified under recourse of the classical free-will theory by relying on a failure in the formation of the contract, see Hoffmann 2012, p. 1156. I will not recall the reservations against classical free will theory here, it shall suffice to hint at J. Schapp’s argument that “will” is legally only valid insofar as the law grants it validity, see Schapp 1986, p. 8 et seqq. To justify a legal provision with a will of the person is hence quite tautological.

  52. 52.

    See Purnhagen 2013.

  53. 53.

    Cooter 1989, pp. 385–386.

  54. 54.

    See for a more developed analysis on rules of freedom from contract Ben-Shahar 2004.

  55. 55.

    Schwartz 2008; Posner 1998.

  56. 56.

    Cooter 1989, p. 386.

  57. 57.

    Franck and Purnhagen 2014, p. 332.

  58. 58.

    Eisenberg 1995.

  59. 59.

    See on this phenomenon Afilalo et al. 2014, p. 287.

  60. 60.

    Eisenberg 1982, p. 773.

  61. 61.

    Ogus 1994, p. 41.

  62. 62.

    van den Bergh 2003, p. 83.

  63. 63.

    Flume 2000; Hammen 2010; Reich 2000, p. 261.

  64. 64.

    Patterson and Afilalo 2008, pp. 99–100.

  65. 65.

    Micklitz 2009, p. 3.

  66. 66.

    See recently Case C-508/12, 5. 12. 2013, Vapenik v Thurner [2014] ECR I-0000, para 26.

  67. 67.

    Reich 2000, p. 261.

  68. 68.

    See e.g. Avgouleas 2009, p. 440.

  69. 69.

    Tröger 2012; general Stigler 1971.

  70. 70.

    See e.g. Avgouleas 2009, p. 440.

  71. 71.

    Securities Act of 1933, 15 U.S.C. § 77a to 77 mm (1994).

  72. 72.

    Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78a to 78mm (1994).

  73. 73.

    Avgouleas 2009, p. 440.

  74. 74.

    Samuelson 1965. In a little less draconic way Fama 1970, p. 383.

  75. 75.

    Spindler 2011.

  76. 76.

    Avgouleas 2009, p. 440.

  77. 77.

    Purnhagen 2014a.

  78. 78.

    See Usher 2001, p. 151 et seqq.; Steindorff 1996, p. 195.

  79. 79.

    Steindorff 1996, pp. 195–196.

  80. 80.

    See to the relations of both concepts Purnhagen 2014b.

  81. 81.

    The consolidated Capital Requirements Directive comprises European Parliament and Council Directive (EC) 2006/48 for the Taking up and Pursuit of the Business of Credit Institutions [2006] OJ L 177/1 and European Parliament and Council Directive (EC) 2006/49 on the Capital Adequacy of Investment Firms and Credit Institutions [2006] OJ L 177/201.

  82. 82.

    Franck and Purnhagen 2014, p. 336; Steindorff 1996, pp. 195–196.

  83. 83.

    The President‘s Working Group on Financial Markets (PWGFM), Policy Statement on Financial Market Developments’, March 2008.

  84. 84.

    Avgouleas 2009.

  85. 85.

    See in respect of the financial architecture Van Gestel and van Golen 2014.

  86. 86.

    Stigler 1971.

  87. 87.

    See with an assessment Torreblanca et al. 2013.

Bibliography

  • Ackermann, Thomas. 2007. Der schutz des negativen interesses. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Afilalo, Ari, Dennis Patterson, and Kai Purnhagen. 2014. Statecraft, the market state and the development of European legal culture. In Towards a European legal culture, ed. Geneviève Helleringer and Kai Purnhagen, 277–302. Baden-Baden: C. H. Beck/Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allio, Lorenzo. 2011. On the smartness of smart regulation—A brief comment on the future reform agenda. European Journal of Risk Regulation 2:19–20.

    Google Scholar 

  • Avgouleas, Emilios. 2009. The global financial crisis and the disclosure paradigm on European financial regulation: The case for reform. European Company and Financial Law Review 6 (4): 440–475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bekkers, V., and A. Edwards. 2007. Legitimacy and democracy: A conceptual framework for assessing governance practices. In Governance and the democratic deficit: Assessing the democratic legitimacy of governance practices, eds. V. Bekkers, G. Dijkstra, A. Edwards, and M. Fenger, 35–60. Aldershot Hampshire: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ben-Shahar, Omri. 2004. Freedom from contract. Wisconsin Law Review 261–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binding, Jörg, and Kai Purnhagen. 2011. Regulations on e-commerce consumer protection rules in China and Europe compared—Same same but different? Journal of Intellectual Property, Information Technology and E-Commerce Law 2:186–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bizer, Kilian, and Martin Führ. 2002. Responsive Regulierung. Anforderungen an die interdisziplinäre Gesetzesfolgenforschung. In Responsive Regulierung, eds. Kilian Bizer, Martin Führ, and Christoph Hütting, 5. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Black, Julia, and Robert Baldwin. 2010. Really responsive risk-based regulation. Law & Policy 32:181–213.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cooter, Thomas. 1989. Cognitive imperfections and the economic analysis of law. Hamline Law Review 12:385.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danielsson-Tham M. L., E. Eriksson, S. Helmersson, M. Leffler, L. Lüdtke, M. Steen, S. Sørgjerd, and W. Tham. 2004. Causes behind a human cheese-borne outbreak of gastrointestinal listeriosis. Foodborne Pathogens and Disease 1 (3): 153–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Downes, Chris. 2014. The impact of WTO SPS Law on EU food regulations. Dordrecht: Springer

    Google Scholar 

  • Dyson, Matthew. 2014. Divide and conquer: Using legal domains in comparative legal studies. In Towards a European legal culture, eds. Geneviève Helleringer and Kai Purnhagen, 115–137. Baden-Baden: C. H. Beck/Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easton, David. 1965. A system analysis of political life. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eberlein, Burkard. 2004. Formal and informal governance in single market regulation. In Informal governance in the European Union, eds. Thomas Christiansen and Simona Piattoni, 150–172. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenberg, Melvin. 1982. The bargain principle and its limits. Harvard Law Review 773.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eisenberg, Melvin. 1995. The limits of cognition and the limits of contract. Stanford Law Review 47:211–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama, Eugene. 1970. Efficient capital markets: A review of theory and empirical work. Journal of Finance 25:383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flume, Werner. 2000. Vom Beruf unserer Zeit für Gesetzgebung. Zeitschrift für Wirtschaftsrecht 1427.

    Google Scholar 

  • Franck, Jens-Uwe, and Kai Purnhagen. 2014. Homo economicus, behavioural sciences, and economic regulation—On the concept of man in internal market regulation and its normative basis. In Law and economics in Europe—Foundations and applications, ed. Klaus Mathis, 329–365. Heidelberg: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, Margaret Rosso. 2012. Genetically modified crops and their products in the united states: A review of the regulatory system. In Jahrbuch des Agrarrechts, ed. José Martìnez, 69–95. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammen, Horst. 2010. Zerschlagt unsere Gesetzestafeln nicht! Zeitschrift für Wirtschafts- und Bankrecht 1357.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffmann, Jan F. 2012. Verbraucherwiderruf bei Stellvertretung. Juristenzeitung, 1156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hey, B., K. Jacob, and A. Volkery. 2007. Better regulation by new governance hybrids? Governance models and the reform of European chemicals policy. Journal of Cleaner Production 15:1861.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Joerges, Christian, Jürgen Falke, Hans-Wolfgang Micklitz, and Gert Brüggemeier. 1988. Die Sicherheit von Konsumgütern und die Entwicklung der Europäischen Gemeinschaft. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jolls, Christine, and Cass Sunstein. 2007. Debiasing through Law. Journal of Legal Studies 35:199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keller, Moritz. 2004. Lessons for the hague: Internet jurisdiction in contract and tort cases in the European community and the united states. The John Marshall Journal of Information Technology and Privacy Law 23:1–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koch, J., R. Dworak, R. Prager, B. Becker, S. Brockmann, A. Wicke, H. Wichmann-Schauer, H. Hof, D. Werber, and K. Stark. 2010. Large listeriosis outbreak linked to cheese made from pasteurized milk, Germany 2006/2007. Foodborne Pathogens and Disease 7 (12): 1581–1584.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krystallis, A., L. Frewer, G. Rowe, J. Houghton, O. Kehagia, and T. Perrea. 2007. A perceptual divide? Consumer and expert attitudes to food risk management in Europe. Health Risks and Society 9:407–424.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leiter, Brian. 2013. Legal realism, old and new. Valparaiso Law Review 48. (Forthcoming).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenaerts, Koen. 2004. “In the union we trust”: Trust-enhancing principles of community law. Common Market Law Review 41:317–343.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lynch, Diahanna, and David Vogel. 2001. The regulation of GMOs in Europe and the United States: A case-study of contemporary European regulatory politics, council on foreign relations press. http://www.cfr.org/agricultural-policy/regulation-gmos-europe-united-states-case-study-contemporary-european-regulatory-politics/p8688. Accessed 13 Oct 2014.

  • Macneil, Ian. 2000. Other sociological approaches. In Encyclopedia of law & economics, eds. Boudewijn Bouckaert and Gerrit De Geest, 694 et seqq. Cheltenham: Edward Egar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mann, Dennis-Jonathan. 2009. Ein Gebilde sui generis? Die Debatte um das Wesen der Europäischen Union im Spiegel der „Nature of the Union“-Kontroverse in den USA. In Die Verfassung Europas, eds. Frank Decker and Marcus Höreth, 319. Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsden, Christopher. 2011. Internet co-regulation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McColm, Helen. 2011. Smart regulation: The European commission’s updated strategy. European Journal of Risk Regulation 2:9–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • McGee, Andrew, and Stephen Weatherill. 1990. The evolution of the single market: Harmonisation or liberalisation. The Modern Law Review 53:578.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Micklitz, Hans-Wolfgang. 2001. A comment on party autonomy and consumer regulation in the European community—A plea for consistency. In Party Autonomy and the Role of Information in the Internal Market, eds. Stefan Grundmann, Wolfgang Kerber, and Stephen Weatherill, 197–204. Berlin: Walter de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Micklitz, Hans. 2009. The visible hand of European regulatory private law—The transformation of European private law from autonomy to functionalism in competition and regulation. Yearbook of European Law 2010, 3–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miles, Thomas, and Cass Sunstein. 2008. The new legal realism. The University of Chicago Law Review 75:831–851.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nourse, Victoria, and Gregory Shaffer. 2009. Varieties of new legal realism: Can a new world order prompt a new legal theory? Cornell Law Review 95:61–138.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ogus, Anthony. 1994. Legal form and economic theory. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, Dennis, and Ari Afilalo. 2008. The new global trading order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pollack, Mark, and Gregory Shaffer. 2009. When cooperation fails. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, Richard. 1998. Rational choice, behavioral economics, and the law. Stanford Law Review 50:1551–1575.

    Google Scholar 

  • Purnhagen, Kai. 2013. The Architecture of post-national European contract law from a phenomenological perspective—A question of comparative institutional analysis. The Rabel Journal of Comparative and International Private Law 77:592–619.

    Google Scholar 

  • Purnhagen, Kai. 2014a. Never the twain shall meet?—A critical perspective on cultural limits between internal continental dogmatism and consequential us-style law and economics theory. In Law and economics in Europe—Foundations and applications, ed. Klaus Mathis, pp. 3–21. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Purnhagen, Kai. 2014b. The virtue of cassis de Dijon 25 years later—It is not dead, it just smells funny. In Varieties of European economic law and regulation, ed. Kai Purnhagen and Peter Rott, pp. 315–342. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Radaelli, Claudio. 2007. Whither better regulation for the Lisbon agenda? Journal of European Public Policy 14:190–207.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reich, Norbert. 2000. Das Phantom “Verbraucher” (endlich!?) im Gral des BGB!, Verbraucher und Recht 261.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, Paul. 1965. Proof that properly anticipated prices fluctuate randomly 6. Industrial Management Review 6:41

    Google Scholar 

  • Schapp, Jan. 1986. Grundfragen der Rechtsgeschäftslehre. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, Friedrich W. 1970. Demokratietheorie zwischen Utopie und Anpassung. Konstanz: Konstanzer Universitätsverlag.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, Friedrich W. 1997. Games real actors play. Actor-centered institutionalism in policy research. Boulder: Westview.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf, Friedrich W. 1999. Governing in Europe: Effective and democratic? Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, Allan. 2008. How much irrationality does the market permit? Journal of Legal Studies 37:131–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, William. 2006. Toyota jurisprudence: Legal theory and rolling rule regimes. In Law and new governance in the EU and the US, eds. Grainne de Búrca and Joan Scott, 57. Oxford: Hart.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skogstad. 2003. Legitimacy and/or policy effectiveness?: Network governance and GMO regulation in the European Union. Journal of European Public Policy 10:321–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spindler, Gerald. 2011. Behavioural finance and investor protection regulations. Journal of Consumer Policy 34:315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Steindorff, Ernst. 1996. EG-Vertrag und Privatrecht. Baden-Baden: Nomos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, George. 1971. The theory of economic regulation. Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science 2:3–21.

    Google Scholar 

  • Torreblanca, J. I., M. Leonard, H. Kudnani, U. Guéerot, and T. Klau. 2013. The remarkable rise of continental Euroscepticism, theguardian.com. http://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2013/apr/24/continental-euroscepticism-rise. Accessed 24 April 2013. (20.09 BST2013).

  • Tricker, Ray. 2000. CE conformity marking and new approach directives. Oxford: Butterworth-Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tröger, Tobias. 2012. Organizational choices of banks and the effective supervision of transnational financial institutions. Texas International Law Journal 48:177–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Usher, John. 2001. Disclosure rules (information) as a primary tool in the doctrine on measures having an equivalent effect. In Party autonomy and the role of information in the internal market, eds. Stefan Grundmann, Wolfgang Kerber, and Stephen Weatherill. Berlin: de Gruyter.

    Google Scholar 

  • Valletta, Marco. 2010. Consumer perception and GMOs in the European Union, policy responses to societal concerns in food and agriculture: Proceedings of an OECD workshop. http://www.oecd.org/tad/agricultural-policies/46838061.pdf. Accessed 13 Oct 2014.

  • Van den Bergh, Roger. 2003. De richtlijn consumentenkoop in rechtseconomisch perspectief. In De richtlijn consumentenkoop in perspectief, ed. Jan Smits. Den Haag: Boom Juridische Uitgaven.

    Google Scholar 

  • van der Meulen, Bernd, Harry Bremmers, Kai Purnhagen, Nidhi Gupta, Hans Bouwmeester, and Leon Geyer. 2014. Governing nano foods. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Gestel, Rob, and Thomas van Golen. 2014. Enforcement by the new European supervisory agencies: Quis custodiet ipsos custodes? In Varieties of European economic law and regulation, eds. Kai Purnhagen and Peter Rott, pp. 757–780. Dordrecht: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, Neil, and Grainne de Búrca. 2007. Reconceiving law & new governance. Columbia Journal of European Law 13:522.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weiler, Joseph. 2005. The transformation of Europe. Yale Law Journal 100:2403.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wiener, Jonathan. 2006. Better regulation in Europe. Current Legal Problems 9:447–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgement

I would like to thank Hans Micklitz, Jeff Rachlinski, Harm Schepel, Anne-Lise Sibony, and Avishalom Tor for valuable comments on an earlier version of this piece.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Kai Purnhagen .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Purnhagen, K. (2015). Why Do We Need Responsive Regulation and Behavioural Research in EU Internal Market Law?. In: Mathis, K. (eds) European Perspectives on Behavioural Law and Economics. Economic Analysis of Law in European Legal Scholarship, vol 2. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-11635-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics