Skip to main content

Government Debt and Human Capital Formation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1766 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, we focus on another important source of sustained growth, namely human capital formation. Therefore, we study two endogenous growth models with human capital accumulation that is the result of public spending. The government hires teachers and finances additional expenditures for human capital formation. As in the last section, it may run deficits but sets the primary surplus again such that it is a positive function of public debt.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Note that we again omit the time argument t if no ambiguity arises.

  2. 2.

    The denotes BGP values and we exclude the economically meaningless BGP \(h^{\star } = c^{\star } = 0 = b^{\star }\).

  3. 3.

    It was also that mechanism that generated ongoing growth in the models presented in Chap. 3.

  4. 4.

    A more formal reason is that knowledge is a purely public good that requires human capital for its formation, see the next subsection for details.

  5. 5.

    Recall that in this case public debt B would be negative.

  6. 6.

    The denotes the values on the BGP. We exclude \(x^{\star } = z^{\star } = 0\) and q  = 0 is not feasible since it would imply division by zero in \(\dot{h}/h\).

  7. 7.

    Equation (5.34) shows that case (i) is obtained with ϕ = 0 and ψ = (1 −τ)r, case (ii) is obtained for ϕ = 0 and ψ < (1 −τ)r. Further, in case (ii) ρ < ψ must hold so that \(\dot{C}/C <\dot{ B}/B\) on the BGP.

  8. 8.

    The public debt to GDP is given by \(p^{\star }/(z^{\star }u)^{\alpha }\).

  9. 9.

    The results are given in the appendix to this chapter.

  10. 10.

    The parameters ϕ and \(\varphi\) are \(\phi = -0.01,\ \varphi = 0.05\) in scenario (iii), \(\phi = 0,\ \varphi = 0.05\) in scenario (ii), and \(\phi = 0,\ \varphi = (1-\tau )r\) in scenario (i).

Data Sources

  • Arrow, K. J. (1962). The economic implications of learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 29, 155–173.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J. (1990). Government spending in a simple model of endogenous growth. Journal of Political Economy, 98, S103–S125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R. J., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (2003). Economic growth (2nd ed.). Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beauchemin, K. R. (2001). Growth or stagnation? The role of public education. Journal of Development Economics, 64, 389–416.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blankenau, W. F., & Simpson, N. B. (2004). Public education, expenditures and growth. Journal of Development Economics, 73, 583–605.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cooley, J. F., Greenwood, J., & Yorukoglu, M. (1997). The replacement problem. Journal of Monetary Economics, 40, 457–499.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeLong, B. J., & Summers, L. H. (1991). Equipment investment and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 445–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Futagami, K., Morita, Y., & Shibata, A. (1993). Dynamic analysis of an endogenous growth model with public capital. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 95, 607–625.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B. (1992). Public versus private investmentin human capital: Endogenous growth and income distribution. Journal of Political Economy, 100, 818–834.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glomm, G., & Ravikumar, B. (1997). Productive government expenditures and long-run growth. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 21, 183–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., & Krusell, P. (1997). Long-run implications of investment specific technological change. American Economic Review, 87, 342–362.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A. (2008c). Human capital formation, public debt and economic growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 30, 415–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A. (2012c). Human capital formation, learning by doing and the government in the process of economic growth. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 51, 71–89.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A., Gong, G., & Semmler, W. (2005). The forces of economic growth: A time series perspective. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A. B., & Lindahl, M. (2001). Education for growth: Why and for whom? Journal of Economic Literature, 39, 1101–1136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levhari, D. (1966). Extensions of arrow’s learning by doing. Review of Economic Studies, 33, 117–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levine, R., & Renelt, D. (1992). A sensitivity analysis of cross-country growth regressions. American Economic Review, 82, 942–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22, 3–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ni, S., & Wang, X. (1994). Human capital and income taxation in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Macroeconomics, 16, 493–507.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rebelo, S. (1991). Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 99, 500–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. M. (1986). Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Uzawa, H. (1965). Optimum technical change in an aggregative model of economic growth. International Economic Review, 6, 18–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

5.1.1 Proof of Proposition 29

The balanced growth rate is given by Eq. (5.23) as \(g =\dot{ c}/c = -\rho + (1-\tau )(1-\alpha )z^{\alpha }u^{\alpha }\) with z = z . Solving Eqs. (5.41), (5.44) and (5.42) with respect to x, p and q leads to x = x(z, ⋅ ),  p = p(z, ⋅ ) and q = q(p(z, ⋅ ), z, ⋅ ), respectively. Inserting that x, p, and q in Eq. (5.43) gives \(\dot{z}\) as function of z. Dividing \(\dot{z}\) by z leads to the function f 1 given by

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} f_{1}(\cdot )& =& \rho -(1-\tau )(1-\alpha )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha } + z^{\alpha (1-\beta )-1}\varphi \cdot C_{ 1}^{1-\beta }\cdot {}\\ & &\left (\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho } {\xi } \right )^{- \frac{1-\beta } {1-\beta _{h}} }, {}\\ \end{array}$$

with

$$\displaystyle{ C_{1} = \left ( \frac{\alpha (1-\tau )(u - 1) + u\tau } {u^{1-\alpha }(1 - u)^{\beta _{h}/(\beta _{h}-1)}} + \frac{\phi \rho u} {u^{1-\alpha }(1 - u)^{\beta _{h}/(\beta _{h}-1)}(\psi -\rho )}\right ) }$$

On a BGP we must have f 1(⋅ ) = 0.

Differentiating f 1(⋅ ) with respect to z leads to

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} \frac{\mathit{df }_{1}(\cdot )} {\mathit{dz}} & =& (1-\tau )(\alpha -1)\alpha z^{\alpha -1}u^{\alpha } -\varphi z^{-2}C_{ 1}^{1-\beta }\left (\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho } {\xi } \right )^{ \frac{1-\beta } {1-\beta _{h}} } {}\\ & +& \frac{\alpha (\beta -1)\varphi C_{1}^{1-\beta }\left (\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho } {\xi } \right )^{- \frac{1-\beta } {1-\beta _{h}} }(\rho (1 -\beta _{h}) +\beta _{h}(1-\tau )(1-\alpha )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha })} {(1 -\beta _{h})z^{2}((1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho )} {}\\ \end{array}$$

Existence of BGP implies \(C_{1}^{1-\beta }((1\,-\,\alpha )(1\,-\,\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }/\xi -\rho /\xi )^{- \frac{1-\beta } {1\,-\,\beta _{h}} }\,>\,0,(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho> 0\) so that \(\lim _{z\rightarrow \infty }f_{1}(\cdot ) = -\infty\) and \(\lim _{ z\searrow u^{-1}\rho ^{1/\alpha }((1-\alpha )(1-\tau ))^{-1/\alpha }}f_{1}(\cdot ) = +\infty\), where \(z \searrow u^{-1}\rho ^{1/\alpha }((1-\alpha )(1-\tau ))^{-1/\alpha }\) means that z approaches that value from above. We can restrict the range of z to \(z> u^{-1}\rho ^{1/\alpha }((1-\alpha )(1-\tau ))^{-1/\alpha }\) because otherwise there would be no positive balanced growth rate. Further, for \(z \in \left (u^{-1}\rho ^{1/\alpha }((1-\alpha )(1-\tau ))^{-1/\alpha },\infty \right )\) we have df 1(⋅ )∕dz < 0 so that there is a unique z that solves f 1(⋅ ) = 0 and, thus, a unique BGP. □ 

5.1.2 Proof of Lemma 3

From the proof of Proposition 29 we know that f 1(⋅ ) = 0 must hold on the BGP. Solving (5.41) with respect to x leads to x = x(z, ⋅ ). Inserting that x in Eq. (5.44) and solving the resulting equation with respect to p yields

$$\displaystyle{ p = -u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }\left ( \frac{\phi } {\psi -\rho }\right ) \leftrightarrow \frac{\phi } {\psi -\rho } = \frac{-p} {u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }} }$$

Substituting ϕ∕(ψρ) in f 1(⋅ ) = 0 (from the proof of Proposition 29) leads to

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} f_{2}(\cdot )& =& \rho -(1-\tau )(1-\alpha )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha } +\varphi \cdot \left (\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho } {\xi } \right )^{- \frac{1-\beta } {1-\beta _{h}} }. {}\\ & & \left (z^{\alpha -1/(1-\beta )} \frac{\alpha (1-\tau )(u - 1) + u\tau } {u^{1-\alpha }(1 - u)^{\beta _{h}/(\beta _{h}-1)}} + \frac{\rho u} {u(1 - u)^{\beta _{h}/(\beta _{h}-1)}}z^{-1/(1-\beta )}(-p)\right )^{1-\beta } {}\\ \end{array}$$

The function f 2(⋅ ) is continuous in x and p and this function has the following properties, \(\lim _{z\searrow u^{-1}\rho ^{1/\alpha }((1-\alpha )(1-\tau ))^{-1/\alpha }}f_{2}(\cdot ) = +\infty,\ \lim _{z\rightarrow \infty }f_{2}(\cdot ) = -\infty\). From Proposition 29 we know that existence of a BGP implies that it is unique so that \(\partial \,f_{2}(\cdot )/\partial \,z <0\) holds for f 2(⋅ ) = 0. Further, f 2(⋅ )∕p < 0 is immediately seen. Implicitly differentiating f 2(⋅ ) then gives

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\mathit{dz}} {\mathit{dp}} = -\frac{\partial \,f_{2}(\cdot )/\partial \,p} {\partial \,f_{2}(\cdot )/\partial \,z} <0. }$$

Since the balanced growth rate rises with z the balanced growth rate and the debt ratio are negatively correlated. □ 

5.1.3 Proof of Proposition 31

The balanced growth rate is given by \(g =\dot{ c}/c = -\rho + (1-\tau )(1-\alpha )z^{\alpha }u^{\alpha }\). A deficit financed increase in educational spending can be modeled by a decline in ϕ which is immediately seen from Eqs. (5.35) and (5.34). Differentiating g with respect to −ϕ gives

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\partial \,g} {\partial \,(-\phi )} = (1-\tau )(1-\alpha )u^{\alpha }\alpha z^{\alpha -1} \frac{\partial \,z} {\partial \,(-\phi )}, }$$

with z evaluated on the BGP, that is, at z = z .

The derivative \(\partial \,z/\partial \,(-\varphi )\) is obtained by implicit differentiation of f 1(⋅ ) (from the proof of Proposition 29) as

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\partial \,z} {\partial \,(-\phi )} = -\frac{\partial \,f_{1}(\cdot )/\partial \,(-\phi )} {\partial \,f_{1}(\cdot )/\partial \,z} = \frac{z^{\alpha (1-\beta )-1}\varphi (1-\beta )C_{1}^{-\beta }\left (\frac{(1-\alpha )(1-\tau )u^{\alpha }z^{\alpha }-\rho } {\xi } \right )^{- \frac{1-\beta } {1-\beta _{h}} }\rho u^{\alpha }} {(1 - u)^{\beta _{h}/(\beta _{h}-1)}(\psi -\rho )(\partial \,f_{1}(\cdot )/\partial \,z)}. }$$

Because of f 1(⋅ )∕z < 0 for all relevant z (see the proof of Proposition 29) we get

$$\displaystyle{ \frac{\partial \,z} {\partial \,(-\phi )}> (<)0\quad \text{for}\ \psi <(>)\rho }$$

 □ 

5.1.4 Proof of Proposition 32

To prove that proposition we note that \(\dot{c}/c =\dot{ k}/k\) implies \(\dot{k}/k = -\rho + (1-\tau )r\). Using this, the debt to physical capital ratio evolves according to \(\dot{p}/p = (\rho -\psi ) -\phi (y/k)p^{-1}\). Thus, the differential equation describing the evolution of public debt relative to physical capital is obtained as

$$\displaystyle{ \dot{p} = p(\rho -\psi ) -\phi \left (\frac{y} {k}\right ), }$$

where \(y/k = u^{\alpha }(v/k)^{\alpha }\) is constant if knowledge v and physical k grow at the same rate. Setting \(\dot{p} = 0\), the debt to physical capital ratio on the BGP is computed as \(p^{\star } = (y/k)\phi /(\rho -\psi )\).

For p  > 0 we have ϕ < ( > )0 for ρ < ( > )ψ. In addition, ϕ < ( > )0 gives \(\dot{p}> (<)0\) for p = 0. Further, \(\partial \,\dot{p}/\partial \,p =\rho -\psi <(>)0\) for ρ < ( > )ψ. This demonstrates that p converges to the unique p ( > 0) if and only if ρ < ψ.

For p  < 0 we have \(\varphi> (<)0\) for ρ < ( > )ψ. Further, ϕ > ( < )0 yields \(\dot{p} <(>)0\) for p = 0. Again we have \(\partial \,\dot{p}/\partial \,p =\rho -\psi <(>)0\) for ρ < ( > )ψ so that p converges to the unique p ( < 0) if and only if ρ < ψ. □ 

5.1.5 Transition Dynamics

Since the initial conditions with respect to q, z, and p are given, that is, q(0) = q 0, z(0) = z 0 and p(0) = p 0, the economy is saddle point stable if the Jacobian matrix of the differential equation system (5.41)–(5.44) has three negative eigenvalues or three eigenvalues with negative real parts. In that case, there exists a unique value for x(0) such that the economy converges to the BGP.

Table 5.7 gives the balanced growth rate, the debt to capital ratio on the BGP and the signs of the eigenvalues of the Jacobian for different values of ψ and ϕ with the benchmark parameter values used in Sect. 5.2.2.

Table 5.7 suggests that the threshold of the reaction coefficient ψ, which determines whether the economy is stable or unstable, is determined by the subjective discount rate ρ such that for values of ψ larger (smaller) ρ the economy is stable (unstable). It should also be noted that ϕ must not become too small (large) so that a BGP exists in the case of ψ > ( < )ρ. In our example underlying Table 5.7, existence of a BGP is given for ϕ > −0. 04(ϕ < 0. 027) in case of ψ = 0. 05 > ρ(ψ = 0. 025 < ρ).

Table 5.7 Balanced growth rate, g, debt to capital ratio on the BGP, b , and the signs of the eigenvalues of the Jacobian for different values of ψ and ϕ

Table 5.8 gives the result for the situation where public debt grows but less than GDP, case (ii) in Definition 9, and the situation of a balanced government budget, case (i) in Definition 9.

Table 5.8 Balanced growth rate, g, growth rate of public debt, g b , and the signs of the eigenvalues of the Jacobian for ϕ = 0 and for different values of ψ

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Greiner, A., Fincke, B. (2015). Government Debt and Human Capital Formation. In: Public Debt, Sustainability and Economic Growth. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-09348-2_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics