Skip to main content

Sustainable Public Debt: Theory and Empirical Evidence

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Public Debt, Sustainability and Economic Growth

Abstract

Modern research on sustainability of debt policies that applies statistical tests has started with the contribution by Hamilton and Flavin (1986) who analyzed whether the series of public debt in the USA contains a bubble term. Since then a great many papers have been written that try to answer the question of whether given debt policies can be considered as sustainable. The interest in that question is in part due to the fact that the latter question is not only of academic interest but that it has practical relevance, too. Hence, if tests reach the conclusion that given debt policies cannot be considered as sustainable governments should undertake corrective actions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Strictly speaking, B should be real public net debt.

  2. 2.

    In this book we consider deterministic economies. Sustainability of public debt with an additive stochastic term is briefly discussed in the appendix to this chapter.

  3. 3.

    For the Data see OECD (2009), base year 2000.

  4. 4.

    In Germany the fiscal year equals the calendar year. In Japan and in the United States a fiscal year lasts from April until March and from October until September, respectively. Whenever necessary, data have been adjusted.

  5. 5.

    For the data see Japan Statistics Bureau (2009). We also have to thank Toichiro Asada for helping us understand particularities of the Japanese government account system.

  6. 6.

    See also for example Asako et al. (1991), pp. 452 and 453 and Ihori et al. (2001) especially sec. 1. For the tax revenue statistics of the selected economies see for example OECD (2009a).

  7. 7.

    See Asako et al. (1991) also for additional characterizations of the Japanese deficits.

  8. 8.

    See also Ihori et al. (2001) sec. 1.

  9. 9.

    For a comparison of General government gross financial liabilities data see OECD (2009a).

  10. 10.

    For the data see SVR (2008) and Statistisches Bundesamt (2008).

  11. 11.

    See United States Government (2008) for the data.

  12. 12.

    This is computed by applying the Hodrick-Prescott-Filter (HP-Filter) to the real GDP series.

  13. 13.

    All graphics and estimations have been performed with R (Version 2.5.0). The estimations were done with the package mgcv (Version 1.3–28) and for the unit root tests we used the package urca.

  14. 14.

    For the data see Japan Statistics Bureau (2009) and International Statistical Yearbook (2009). Please notice that for the primary surplus only the tax revenue is used and the social security payments have been subtracted from total expenditures in order to get reliable data.

  15. 15.

    See also Wood (2001) especially p. 23.

  16. 16.

    For the net debt data see OECD (2009a) general government net financial liabilities, available from 1970 onwards. Apart from that, all other source are retained from the other estimations for Japan.

  17. 17.

    See OECD (20032009a) and International Statistical Yearbook (2009) for the data. From 1991 on, data for the united Germany are used. The estimations have been done without the data for 2000 since the primary surplus is biased in that year due to exceptional revenues from the UMTS auction.

  18. 18.

    The data have been obtained from United States Government (2008).

  19. 19.

    For the data see OECD (20032009a), United States Government (2008), Japan Statistics Bureau (2009) and International Statistical Yearbook (2009). Please note that exceptionally we refer to calendar year data here and due to availability the periods do not always cover those of the estimations.

  20. 20.

    See also Enders (2004) for example.

  21. 21.

    See again for instance Enders (2004).

  22. 22.

    Concerning the data, the same sources as above have been used and the estimation periods are maintained.

  23. 23.

    For the critical values see for example Fuller (1976) table 8.5.2 on page 373 and Dickey and Fuller (1981) tables IV, V and VI on page 1063.

  24. 24.

    The data and the R-codes leading to the estimation results of this section can be downloaded from the website of the book on Springer.com in the box ‘ADDITIONAL INFORMATION’.

  25. 25.

    See European Union (1992) Title VI Chap. 1, Art. 104c, Sect. 2. and Protocol 5 on the excessive deficit procedure.

  26. 26.

    The data are taken from IMF (2010) and from OECD (2010).

  27. 27.

    All equations have been estimated with R (Version 2.9.0) with the package mgcv (Version 1.6–1).

  28. 28.

    The edf give the estimated number of parameters for the smooth term. A value of 1 indicates that the coefficient does not depend on time.

  29. 29.

    For the reaction coefficient as a function of time and for a plot of the data see again the appendix to this chapter.

  30. 30.

    That is also observed with data up to 2006. For 1975–2006, Greiner and Fincke (2009) obtain a significantly positive estimate which differs from the outcome in Greiner and Kauermann (2008) who took data from 1975 to 2003.

  31. 31.

    See World Bank (2013) and Government of Gibraltar (2013) for the data. Numbers have been converted to US $.

  32. 32.

    Cf. IMF (2013) for the data, authors’ calculations. All estimations and plots have been implemented in R 2.9.0.

  33. 33.

    See OECD (2013) and IMF (2013) for the data, authors’ calculations.

  34. 34.

    See OECD (2013) and IMF (2013) for the data. Estimations were performed with package mgcv.

  35. 35.

    See Tables 2.28 and 2.29 in the appendix for the results. A similar result is also obtained by Haskamp (2013), who analyses Spain’s fiscal policy with the Bohn test from 1965 to 2010 finding sustainability.

  36. 36.

    According to the ‘World Bank Atlas Method’ classification, see World Bank (2008b).

  37. 37.

    For detailed information see again Enders (2004), for example.

  38. 38.

    Due to data availability the data for Botswana have been taken from International Statistical Yearbook (2006).

  39. 39.

    See Government of Botswana (2008) for further information.

  40. 40.

    See World Bank (2008a) for the data.

  41. 41.

    For the critical values see for example Fuller (1976) table 8.5.2 on page 373 and Dickey and Fuller (1981) tables IV, V and VI on page 1063. Here the critical values of a sample size of 25 are applied.

  42. 42.

    Here it is not required since the null hypothesis can be rejected.

  43. 43.

    For information on the Box-Ljung test see for example Enders (2004), especially chapter 2. Critical values can be taken from a χ 2 table.

  44. 44.

    See for instance Minkner-Buenjer (1999) especially pages 170 et seqq.

  45. 45.

    See for example Minkner-Buenjer (1999) page 168.

  46. 46.

    For the data see World Bank (2008a).

  47. 47.

    See for example Paul (1987), especially page 24.

  48. 48.

    ibidem.

  49. 49.

    See for example Embassy of the Republic of Mauritius (2008).

  50. 50.

    See World Bank (2008a).

  51. 51.

    See also International Monetary Fund (1995).

  52. 52.

    See also World Bank (2008a).

  53. 53.

    See also International Monetary Fund (2008), for example.

  54. 54.

    See also World Bank (2008a).

  55. 55.

    Without the 1994 observation, as above.

  56. 56.

    See for example Stork (1990) especially page 7.

  57. 57.

    See also Nsouli et al. (1993), especially page 1 et seqq.

  58. 58.

    For the estimation without GVar, ψ is significant at the 10 % level.

  59. 59.

    See also World Bank (2008a).

  60. 60.

    But even that does not guarantee that the critical debt to GDP ratio may be reached before the debt to GDP ratio has converged to its limiting value.

  61. 61.

    See also Tanner (2013) who argues that sustainability analyses should be more than mere mechanical estimation exercises.

  62. 62.

    Equation (2.18) illustrates that a government can grow out of debt when g > r holds with ϕ > 0.

Data Sources

  • Government of Gibraltar. (2013). Information services, statistics, key Indicators http://www.gibraltar.gov.gi/statistics, last access January 8, 2013.

  • International Statistical Yearbook. (2006). IMF database. DSI data service & information.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Statistical Yearbook. (2009). IMF database, via StatistikNetz.de, January 2009. DSI data service & information.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2010). International statistical yearbook, IMF’s international financial statistics, via StatistikNetz.de, DSI data service and information.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. (2013). International financial statistics, via StatistikNetz.de, DSI data service and information.

    Google Scholar 

  • Japan Statistics Bureau. (2009). Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications, Japan; Historical Statistics of Japan, http://www.stat.go.jp/english/data/chouki/index.htm, last access January 15, 2009, extended by Japan Statistical Yearbook 2009 data.

  • OECD. (2003). OECD economic outlook statistics and projections, Databasis: OECD economic outlook 73, June 2003, especially all “Government Account” Data.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD. (2009). Gross domestic product in National Account Data. http://www.oecd.org/statsportal/0,3352,en_2825_293564_1_1_1_1_1,00.html, last access April 20, 2010.

  • OECD. (2009a). OECD databases, OECD Publications, via StatistikNetz.de, October 2009. DSI Data Service & Information.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD Databases. (2010). “Economic outlook statistics and projections” also “fiscal positions and business cylcles (historical ed.),” via StatistikNetz.de, DSI data service and information.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD Databases. (2013). “Economic outlook statistics and projections” also “fiscal positions and business cylcles (historical ed.),” via StatistikNetz.de, DSI data service and information.

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisches Bundesamt. (2008). Statistisches Jahrbuch 2008 Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen, Bruttoinlandsprodukt. Wiesbaden: Statistisches Bundesamt.

    Google Scholar 

  • SVR. (2008). Sachverstaendigenrat zur Begutachtung der gesamtwirtschaftlichen Lage, Lange Reihen zum Downloaden, Nationale Tabellen, Öffentliche Finanzen, Verschuldung der öffentlichen Haushalte, http://www.sachverstaendigenrat-wirtschaft.de/timerow/tabdeu.php, last access January 16, 2009.

  • United States Government. (2008). Office of management and budget. Historical tables, budget of the United States Government, fiscal year 2009. Washington: U.S. Government Printing Office. Access via www.gpoaccess.gov

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2008a). Data & statistics, country at a glance tables, 9/28/07, http://go.worldbank.org/3516WI4UM0, last access on September 9, 2008.

  • World Bank. (2008b). Data & statistics, country classification, http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/DATASTATISTICS/0,,contentMDK:20420458~menuPK:64133156~pagePK:64133150~piPK:64133175~theSitePK:239419,00.html, last access on March 13, 2008.

  • World Bank. (2013). Worldbank selection data, via StatistikNetz.de, DSI data service and information.

    Google Scholar 

  • Afonso, A. (2005). Fiscal sustainability: the unpleasant European case. Finanzarchiv, 61, 19–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asako, K., Ito, T., & Sakamoto, K. (1991). The rise and fall of deficit in Japan, 1965–1990. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 5, 451–472.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bajo-Rubio, O., Diaz-Roldan, C., & Esteve, V. (2004). Searching for threshold effects in the evolution of budget deficits: An application to the Spanish case. Economic Letters, 82, 239–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ballabriga, F. C., & Martinez-Mongay, C. (2005). Sustainability of EU public finances. European Economy. Economic Papers, 225. Brussels: European Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O. J., & Fischer, S. (1989). Lectures on macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohn, H. (1995). The sustainability of budget deficits in a stochastic economy. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27, 257–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bohn, H. (1998). The behavior of U.S. public debt and deficits. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 949–963.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohn, H. (2008). The sustainability of fiscal policy in the United States. In R. Neck & J.-E. Sturm (Eds.), Sustainability of public debt (pp. 15–50). Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Canzoneri, M. B., Cumby, R. E., & Diba, B. T. (2001). Is the price level determined by the needs of fiscal solvency? American Economic Review, 91, 1221–1238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickey, D. A., & Fuller, W. A. (1981). Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root? Econometrica, 49, 1057–1072.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Embassy of the Republic of Mauritius. (2008). Economy of Mauritius. Last access on September 3, 2008, http://www.mauritius-embassy.de/economy.php

  • Enders, W. (2004). Applied econometric time series (2nd ed.). Hoboken: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Union. (1992). Treaty on European Union. Last access November 27, 2007, http://europa.eu.int/eur-lex/lex/en/treaties/dat/11992M/htm/11992M.html

  • European Union. (1997). Consolidated version of the treaty on European Union. Official Journal of the European Communities, C 340, 10. November 1997. Access via: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/en/treaties/index.htm html version. Last access June 1, 2011.

  • Fincke, B. (2013). Sustainable debt policies despite the crisis? Empirical evidence for Iberian economies (Bielefeld Working Papers in Economics and Management No. 16–2013). Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2323323

  • Fincke, B., & Greiner, A. (2008). How to assess debt sustainability? Some theory and empirical evidence for selected euro area countries. Applied Economics, 44, 3717–3724.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fincke, B., & Greiner, A. (2009). Do governments in developing countries pursue sustainable debt policies? Empirical evidence for selected countries in Africa and Latin America. Journal of Development Studies, 46, 745–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fincke, B., & Greiner, A. (2011a). Do large industrialized economies pursue sustainable debt policies? A comparative study for Japan, Germany and the United States. Japan and the World Economy, 23, 202–213.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fincke, B., & Greiner, A. (2011b). Debt sustainability in selected euro area countries. Empirical evidence estimating time-varying parameters. Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics, 15(3), article 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, W. A. (1976). Introduction to statistical time series. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Government of Botswana. (2008) Economic information. Last access on September 3, 2008, http://www.gov.bw/index.php?option=com_content&task=view&id=63&Itemid=74

  • Granger, C. W. J. (2008). Non-linear models: Where do we go next – Time varying parameter models? Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics, 12(3), article 1: 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A. (2008a). Sustainability of public debt: Some theoretical considerations. Economics Bulletin, 33, 2357–2364.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A. (2013a). How to test for debt sustainability? Some theoretical reflections on an empirical test. Economics Bulletin, 33, 2357–2364.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A., & Fincke, B. (2009). Public debt and economic growth. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A., & Kauermann, G. (2008). Debt policy in euro-area countries: Empirical evidence for Germany and Italy using penalized spline smoothing. Economic Modelling, 25, 1144–1154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greiner, A., Köller, U., & Semmler, W. (2007). Debt sustainability in the european monetary union: Theory and empirical evidence for selected countries. Oxford Economic Papers, 59, 194–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, J. D., & Flavin, M. (1986). On the limitations of government borrowing: A framework for empirical testing. The American Economic Review, 76, 808–819.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haskamp, U. (2013). Was Spanish fiscal policy sustainable? Empirica, 1–14. doi: 10.1007/s10663-013-9211-5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hastie, T. J., & Tibshirani, R. J. (1990). Generalized additive models. London: Chapman and Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ihori, T., Doi, T., & Kondo, H. (2001). Japanese fiscal reform: Fiscal reconstruction and fiscal policy. Japan and the World Economy, 13, 351–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund. (1995). IMF approves stand-by credit for Panama (IMF Press Release No. 95/60). Last access on September 3, 2008, http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/pr/1995/pr9560.htm

  • International Monetary Fund. (2008). Heavily indebted poor countries (HIPC) debt initiative all publications. Last access on September 5, 2008, http://www.imf.org/external/np/hipc/index.asp

  • Martin, G. M. (2000). US deficit sustainability: A new approach based on multiple endogenous breaks. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 15, 83–105.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minkner-Buenjer, M. (1999). Costa Rica: Internationalisierung der Wirtschaft mit Bananen und Mikroprozessoren. Brennpunkt Latainamerika. Politik Wirtschaft Gesellschaft, Institut für Iberoamerika-Kunde Hamburg, 19, 162–172.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neck, R., & Sturm, J.-E. (2008). Sustainability of public debt. Introduction and overview. In R. Neck & J.-E. Sturm (Eds.). Sustainability of public debt (pp. 1–14). Cambridge: MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nsouli, S. M., Eken, S., Duran, P., Bell, G., & Yucelik, Z. M. (1993). The path to convertibility and growth the tunisian experience. (IMF Occasional Paper 109).

    Google Scholar 

  • Paul, E. C. (1987). Fisheries development and the food needs of Mauritius. Rotterdam: A.A. Balkema.

    Google Scholar 

  • Payne, J. E., Mohammadi, H., & Cak, M. (2008). Turkish budget deficit sustainability and the revenue-expenditure nexus. Applied Economics, 40, 823–830.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruppert, R., Wand, M. P., & Carroll, R. J. (2003). Semiparametric regression. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sawada, Y. (1994). Are the heavily indebted countries solvent?: Tests of intertemporal borrowing constraints. Journal of Development Economics, 45, 325–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stork, J. (1990). Europe’s other frontier: North Africa faces the 1990s. Middle East Report, 163(44), 4–8.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanner, E. (2013). Fiscal sustainability: A 21st century guide for the perplexed (IMF Working Paper No. WP/13/89).

    Google Scholar 

  • Trehan, B., & Walsh, C. E. (1991). Testing intertemporal budget constraints: theory and applications to U.S. Federal budget and current account deficits. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 23, 206–223.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westerlund, J., & Prohl, S. (2010). Panel cointegration tests of the sustainability hypothesis in rich OECD countries. Applied Economics, 42, 1355–1364.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilcox, D. W. (1989). The sustainability of government deficits: Implications of the present-value borrowing constraint. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 21, 291–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, S. N. (2001). mgcv: GAM’s and generalized ridge regression for R. R News, 1(2), 20–25.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

2.1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

To prove that proposition we note that the evolution of public debt is given by Eq. (2.3). Integrating that equation and multiplying the resulting expression by \(e^{-\int _{0}^{t}r(\mu )d\mu }\) to get present values gives,Footnote 62

$$\displaystyle{ e^{-C_{1}(t)}B(t) = e^{-C_{3}(t)}B(0) - Y (0)e^{-C_{3}(t)}\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{-C_{1}(\mu )+C_{2}(\mu )+C_{3}(\mu )}\phi (\mu )d\mu,\; }$$
(2.18)

with

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & \int _{0}^{t}r(\mu )d\mu =: C_{ 1}(t),\int _{0}^{\mu }r(\nu )d\nu =: C_{ 1}(\mu ),\int _{0}^{\mu }g(\nu )d\nu =: C_{ 2}(\mu ), {}\\ & & \qquad \int _{0}^{\mu }\psi (\nu )d\nu =: C_{ 3}(\mu ). {}\\ \end{array}$$

For \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C_{3}(t) =\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\nu )d\nu = \infty\), the first term on the right hand side in (2.18), that is \(e^{-C_{3}(t)}\,B(0)\), converges to zero.

The second term on the right hand side in (2.18) can be written as

$$\displaystyle{\frac{Y (0)\int _{0}^{t}e^{-C_{1}(\mu )+C_{2}(\mu )+C_{3}(\mu )}\phi (\mu )d\mu } {e^{C_{3}(t)}} =: K_{1}(t).}$$

Since | ϕ | <  we can set ϕ Y (0) = 1. If \(\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-C_{1}(\mu )+C_{2}(\mu )+C_{3}(\mu )}d\mu\) remains bounded \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C_{3}(t) = \infty\) guarantees that K 1 converges to zero. If \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}e^{-C_{1}(\mu )+C_{2}(\mu )+C_{3}(\mu )}\)  = , applying l’Hôpital gives the limit of K 1 as

$$\displaystyle{\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }K_{1}(t) =\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\frac{e^{-C_{1}(t)+C_{2}(t)}} {\psi (t)} \,,}$$

where we have set ϕ Y (0) = 1 since | ϕ(t) | is bounded. Since \(-C_{1}(t) + C_{2}(t) <0\) we can find a constant k > 0 such that K 1 ≤ e ktψ(t). The right hand side in the former inequality does not converge to zero if ψ(t) converged to zero exponentially. However, in that case \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\mu )d\mu <\infty\) would hold. Consequently, in case that \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\mu )d\mu = \infty\) holds, ψ(t) cannot decline exponentially, and K 1(t) converges to zero.

These considerations demonstrate that the intertemporal budget constraint holds for \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\mu )d\mu = \infty\) which means that the reaction coefficient ψ(t) is positive on average.

The debt ratio is obtained from (2.5) as

$$\displaystyle{b(t) = e^{(C_{1}(t)-C_{2}(t)-C_{3}(t))}b(0) - e^{(C_{1}(t)-C_{2}(t)-C_{3}(t))}\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu )-C_{3}(\mu ))}\phi (\mu )d\mu.}$$

That expression shows that the debt to GDP ratio diverges to plus or minus infinity in the case of \(\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\mu )d\mu \leq \int _{0}^{t}\left (r(\mu ) - g(\mu )\right )d\mu,\) while it remains constant or converges in all other cases. □ 

2.1.1.1 Proof of Proposition 3

To prove that proposition we note that the present value of public debt is now obtained from (2.6) as

$$\displaystyle{e^{-C_{1}(t)}B(t) = B(0) - mY (0)\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu.}$$

The intertemporal budget constraint is fulfilled for \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }e^{-C_{1}(t)}B(t) = 0\) which implies \(b(0) = m\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu\). If the initial debt to GDP ratio, b(0), is larger than \(m\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu\) sustainability of public debt is excluded.

The debt to GDP ratio is obtained from (2.7) as

$$\displaystyle{b(t) = e^{(C_{1}(t)-C_{2}(t))}\left (b(0) - m\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu \right ).}$$

If the intertemporal budget constraint holds we have \(b(0)\,=\,m\int _{0}^{\infty }e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu\) giving \(b(t) = -m\int _{\infty }^{t}e^{-(C_{1}(\mu )-C_{2}(\mu ))}d\mu /e^{-(C_{1}(t)-C_{2}(t))}\). Using l’Hôpital gives \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }b(t) = m/(r - g)\) for asymptotically constant values of r and g. □ 

2.1.1.2 Public Debt Accumulation with a Stochastic Disturbance

Assume that the evolution of public debt is described by a stochastic differential equation with an additive noise. Equation (2.3), then, can be written as,

$$\displaystyle{\mathit{dB}_{t} = \left (h(t)B_{t} -\phi (t)Y (t)\right )\mathit{dt} +\sigma _{d}\,\mathit{dW }_{t},}$$

with h(t): = r(t) −ψ(t) and W is a Wiener process with constant diffusion σ d which is set equal to one, σ d  = 1. Solving that equation yields

$$\displaystyle{B_{t} = e^{\int _{0}^{t}h(\tau )d\tau }\left (B_{0} -\int _{0}^{t}e^{-\int _{0}^{\tau }h(\mu )d\mu }\phi (\tau )Y (\tau )d\tau +\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{-\int _{0}^{\tau }h(\mu )d\mu }\mathit{dW }_{\tau }\right )}$$

with B 0 public debt at time t = 0. Multiplying both sides by the discount factor \(e^{-\int _{0}^{t}r(\tau )d\tau }\) and rewriting gives

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} e^{-C_{1}(t)}B_{ t}& =\ & e^{-C_{3}(t)}B_{ 0} - Y _{0}e^{-C_{3}(t)}\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{C_{2}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\phi (\tau )d\tau + \\ & & e^{-C_{3}(t)}\int _{ 0}^{t}e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\mathit{dW }_{\tau } {}\end{array}$$
(2.19)

with

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & \int _{0}^{t}\psi (\tau )d\tau =: C_{ 3}(t),\int _{0}^{\tau }\psi (\mu )d\mu =: C_{ 3}(\tau ),\int _{0}^{\tau }g(\mu )d\mu =: C_{ 2}(\tau ), {}\\ & & \qquad \int _{0}^{\tau }r(\mu )d\mu =: C_{ 1}(\tau ), {}\\ \end{array}$$

where g gives the growth rate of Y. The first two terms are as in Eq. (2.18) above so that we do not have to consider them again.

The third term on the right hand side in (2.19) is stochastic with the expected value equal to zero. Defining the third term as \(X_{t}(\omega ):= e^{-C_{3}(t)}\int _{0}^{t}e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\mathit{dW }_{\tau }(\omega ),\) the second moment can be written as

$$\displaystyle{E[X_{t}^{2}(\omega )] = E\left [\left (\frac{\int _{0}^{t}e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\mathit{dW }_{\tau }(\omega )} {e^{C_{3}(t)}} \right )^{2}\right ] = \left (\frac{\int _{0}^{t}E\left [e^{2C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-2C_{1}(\tau )}\right ]d\tau } {e^{2C_{3}(t)}} \right ),}$$

because \(E\left [\left (\int _{0}^{t}e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\mathit{dW }_{\tau }(\omega )\right )^{2}\right ] =\int _{ 0}^{t}E\left [\left (e^{C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-C_{1}(\tau )}\right )^{2}\right ]d\tau.\)

Since the mean of the realized real interest rate is strictly positive, we can find a constant \(\bar{r}> 0\) so that \(-C_{1}(\tau ) = -\int _{0}^{\tau }r(\mu )d\mu \leq -\int _{0}^{\tau }\bar{r}\,d\mu.\) Then, we can write

$$\displaystyle{\frac{\int _{0}^{t}e^{2C_{3}(\tau )}E\left [e^{-2C_{1}(\tau )}\right ]d\tau } {e^{2C_{3}(t)}} \leq \frac{\int _{0}^{t}e^{2C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-2\,\bar{r}\,\tau }d\tau } {e^{2C_{3}(t)}} \,.}$$

If \(\int _{0}^{t}e^{2C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-2\,\bar{r}\,\tau }d\tau\) remains bounded and if \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C_{3}(t) = \infty\) holds, the expression converges to zero. If \(\int _{0}^{t}e^{2C_{3}(\tau )}e^{-2\,\bar{r}\,\tau }d\tau\) diverges, applying l’Hôpital gives the right hand side as \(e^{-2\,\bar{r}\,t}/2\psi (t)\) showing that ψ(t) must not converge to zero faster than \(e^{-2\,\bar{r}\,t}\) if that term is to converge to zero asymptotically. Now, assume that ψ(t) declines exponentially. This would imply that \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C_{3}(t) =\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }\int _{0}^{t}\psi (\tau )d\tau <\infty\) holds. Consequently, if \(\lim _{t\rightarrow \infty }C_{3}(t) = \infty\) holds, ψ(t) cannot decline exponentially so that the expression E[X t 2(ω)] converges to zero. □ 

2.1.1.3 Time-Varying Reaction Coefficients and Plots of the Data Used

The following figures show plots of the variables used in the estimations as well as the smooth term sm(t) giving the deviation of the reaction coefficient from its average value (Figs. 2.412.46).

Fig. 2.41
figure 41

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for France

Fig. 2.42
figure 42

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for Ireland

Fig. 2.43
figure 43

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for Portugal

Fig. 2.44
figure 44

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for Spain

Fig. 2.45
figure 45

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for Greece

Fig. 2.46
figure 46

Plot of variables and smooth term sm(t) for Italy

2.1.1.4 Additional Regressions for Spain

The subsequent tables summarize the regression outcomes for Eq. (2.15) for Spain once the sample only consists of observations until 2010 and 2011, respectively.

As these tables show, for a shorter time period the coefficient of interest, i.e. the reaction coefficient in the second line, shows a statistically significant and positive value indicating fiscal sustainability for Spain. The other significant variables possess the expected signs and the diagnostics suggest that the model is suited to replicate the data generating process. Concerning the plots of the smooth term, their shape remains similar as depicted in Fig. 2.15.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Greiner, A., Fincke, B. (2015). Sustainable Public Debt: Theory and Empirical Evidence. In: Public Debt, Sustainability and Economic Growth. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-09348-2_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics