Skip to main content

Predicting the Outcome of the Government Formation Process: A Fuzzy Two-Dimensional Public Choice Model

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 440 Accesses

Part of the book series: Studies in Fuzziness and Soft Computing ((STUDFUZZ,volume 318))

Abstract

Under the most basic of assumptions of Euclidean preferences, majority rule erupts into cycling in two or more dimensional space, and no alternative remains undefeated. The resulting McKelvey’s Chaos TheoremMcKelvey’s Chaos theorem (McKelvey 1976) forces scholars to reconsider basic assumptions about the rational behavior of political actors and their attempts to form coalitions. The government formation literature remains divided on how to best solve the problem. More recently, proposed models either assume cabinet ministers are virtual dictators over their policy jurisdiction (Laver and Shepsle 1996) or rely on complex game-theoretic arguments, which do not lend themselves to empirical verification (Baron 1991; Diermeier and Merlo 2000). This chapter builds on the fuzzy maximal set model developed in Chap. 4. It presents a fuzzy maximal set multi-dimensional model to predict the outcome of the government formation process. We conclude by comparing the predictions made by the model using CMP against actual governments formed after European Parliamentary elections between 1945–2002.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Formally, an actor \(i\) possesses thick indifference if for \(a,b\in X\), \(a\ne b \nRightarrow aP_{i}b\) or \(bP_{i}a\) where \(P_{i}\) is the strict preference relation for player \(i\).

  2. 2.

    See Laver and Hunt (1992) and Laver and Shepsle (1996).

  3. 3.

    In \(k\)-dimensional Euclidean space, \(A_{i}\) would be a \(k\times k\) matrix.

  4. 4.

    The reader should note there does not exist any \(n\)-tuple in Fig. 6.3 where \(\sigma _{i}>0\) for all three players.

  5. 5.

    See Schofield (1993) for an important exception.

  6. 6.

    When the maximal set is empty under thick indifference, Mordeson et al. (2011) propose using a fuzzy uncovered set. Nonetheless, the fuzzy uncovered set is a less than ideal solution set because it is almost always the Pareto set, thus not effectively reducing the number of predicted coalitions.

  7. 7.

    \(\rho _{i}(x,y)=(0.75-0.25+r)\wedge 1\,\mathrm {because}\,\sigma _{i}(x)\ge \sigma _{i}(y).\rho _{i}(y,x)=1-[(0.75-0.25+1-r)\wedge 1]=1-[(0.5+1-r)\wedge 1\,\mathrm {because}\,\sigma _{i}(y)\ge \sigma _{i}(x)\).

  8. 8.

    See Appendix B for the formal argument.

  9. 9.

    See Appendix B for the formal argument.

  10. 10.

    See Appendix B for the formal argument.

  11. 11.

    See Appendix B for the formal argument.

  12. 12.

    See Appendix B for the formal argument.

  13. 13.

    For a more thorough discussion on t-norms see Triangular Norms by Klement and Pap (2000).

  14. 14.

    A party’s economic policy is constructed by the following formula: per414  \(+\)  per401 \(-\) per412 \(-\) per404 \(-\) per403. A party’s foreign affairs’ policy is constructed by the following formula: per104 \(-\) per107 \(-\) per106 \(-\) per105 \(-\) per103.

  15. 15.

    Because the bootstrapped CMP comprises discrete policy dimensions for each party, this book uses a specific design for such purposes. For further information on two-dimensional kernel density estimation see Wand and Jones (1995). In addition, for more explanation on the interaction Kernel estimation and bootstrapping, see Schucany and Polansky (1997).

  16. 16.

    Percentages rounded to nearest tenth.

  17. 17.

    Since neither variables are normally distributed, it may be more appropriate to use Spearman’s rho. In this case, \(r=-0.31\).

References

  • Austen-Smith, D., Banks, J.: Positive Political Theory I. The University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor (1999)

    Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D.P.: A spatial bargaining theory of government formation in paliamentary systems. Am. Polit. Sci. Rev. 85(1), 137–164 (1991)

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Benoit, K., Laver, M., Mikhalov, S.: Treating words as data with error: estimating uncertainty in the comparative manifesto measures. Am. J. Polit. Sci. 53(2), 49–513 (2009)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, E., Feste, K.: Qualitative dimensions of coalition payoffs: evidence for european party governments. Am. Behav. Sci. 18(4), 530–556 (1975)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budge, I., Robertson, D., Hearl, D.: Ideology, Strategy, and Party Change: Spatial Analyses of Post-War Election Programmes in 19 Democracies. Cambrige University Press, New York (1987)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Casey, P., Wierman, M.J., Gibilisco, M.B., Mordeson, J.N., Clark, T.D.: Assessing policy stability in iraq: a fuzzy approach to modeling preferences. Public Choice 151(3–4), 402–423 (2012)

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, T.D., Larson, J., Mordeson, J.N., Potter, J., Wierman, M.J.: Applying Fuzzy Mathematics to Formal Model in Comparative Politics. Springe, Berlin (2008)

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, M., Deb, R.: Fuzzy choice functions. Soc. Choice Welfare 8, 171–182 (1991)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Diermeier, D., Merlo, A.: Government turnover in parliamentary democracies. J. Econ. Theor. 94, 46–79 (2000)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Elff, M.: A spatial model of electoral platforms. Presented at the annual meeting of the midwest political science association 67th annual national conference, The Palmer House Hilton, Chicago, IL (2009)

    Google Scholar 

  • Georgescu, I.: The similarity of fuzzy choice functions. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 158, 1314–1326 (2007)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Golder, M.: Democratic electoral systems around the world, 1946–2000. Elect. Stud. 24(1), 102–121 (2005)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grofman, B.: A dynamic model of protocoalition formation in ideological n-space. Behav. Sci. 27(1), 77–90 (1982)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Klement, E.P., Mesiar, R., Pap, E.: Triangular Norms. Kluwer Academic Publishers, Norwell (2000)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M.: How should we estimate the policy positions of political actors. In: Laver, M. (ed.) Estimating the Policy Position of Political Actors. Routledge, London (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Schofield, N.: Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Oxford University Press, New York (1990)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Budge, I. (eds.): Party Policy and Government Coalitions. MacMillan Press, London (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Hunt, B.: Policy and Party Competition. Routledge, London (1992)

    Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Budge, I.: The policy basis of government coalitions: a comparative investigation. Br. J. Polit. Sci. 23(4), 499–519 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laver, M., Shepsle, K.: Making and Breaking Government: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. Cambrige University Press, New York (1996)

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McKelvey, R.D.: Intransitives in multidimensional voting models and some implications for agenda control. J. Econ. Theor. 12(3), 472–482 (1976)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Mordeson, J.N., Clark, T.D., Miller, N.R., Casey, P.C., Gibilisco, M.B.: The uncovered set and indifference in spatial models: a fuzzy set approach. Fuzzy Sets Syst. 168, 89–101 (2011)

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.: The Theory of Political Coalitions. Yale University Press, New Haven (1962)

    Google Scholar 

  • Schofield, N.: Political competition and multiparty coalition governments. Eur. J. Polit. Res. 23(1), 1–33 (1993)

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schucany, W.R., Polansky, A.M.: Kernal smoothing to improve bootstrap confidence intervals. Roy. Stat. Soc. 59(4), 831–838 (1997)

    MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Van der Brug, W.: Analyzing party dynamics by taking partially overlapping snapshots. In: Laver, M. (ed.) Estimating the Policy Positions of Political Actors. Routledge, London (2001)

    Google Scholar 

  • Wand, M.P., Jones, M.C.: Kernal Smoothing. Chapman and Hall, London (1995)

    Book  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding authors

Correspondence to John N. Mordeson or Terry D. Clark .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Casey, P.C. et al. (2014). Predicting the Outcome of the Government Formation Process: A Fuzzy Two-Dimensional Public Choice Model. In: Fuzzy Social Choice Models. Studies in Fuzziness and Soft Computing, vol 318. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-08248-6_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-08248-6_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-08247-9

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-08248-6

  • eBook Packages: EngineeringEngineering (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics