Skip to main content

Integration, Contagion, and Income Distribution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Abstract

The 2008/2009 global financial crisis and the unprecedented policy response in advanced economies have a worldwide impact. The episode also led many to question the standard framework of economic thinking on regional integration, financial liberalization and their repercussions on income disparity. The paper argues that one needs to take a balanced view on integration—not just the benefits but also the risks. If regional integration leads to greater inequality, the expected growth and prospect of improved welfare can be diminished. Utilizing a general equilibrium framework, it is also shown how financial liberalization and the surge of capital inflows can produce not only financial instability but also worsening income disparity. By combining model-based results and theory-based ranking applied to the Asian case, and considering the benefits, opportunities, costs and risks of alternative policies, it is revealed that imposing levy on bank-led flows can be used to reduce instability and inequality. This type of macro-prudential policy reflects a departure from the ‘First Best’ to the ‘Second Best’ approach of liberalization, where the frictionless outcome of the former is seriously questioned.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    When integration is promoted for political reasons and to build trust, the political windfall that follows can also lead to significant economic benefits.

  2. 2.

    Asia’s export share to other emerging markets outside Asia, particularly exports to the Middle East, grew fast, followed by Africa and Latin America. As a result, the export share to these regions increased from 8.4 % in January 2007 to 11.3 % in August 2012.

  3. 3.

    Venables (2009) argued that the gains from integration are unevenly distributed. Some countries will lose from integration. In particular, the effects of preferential liberalization in regional integration will only benefit resource-poor countries, whereas non-preferential liberalization tends to benefit only resource-rich countries.

  4. 4.

    Evidence from Cross-Sectional Analysis of the Regional Growth Process within the European Union is shown in Armstrong (1995); and Ben-David (2001). Some, however, found a pattern of divergence; see Slaughter (2001); Arestis and Paliginis (1995). Part of the explanation rests on the interpretation of σ- and β-convergence (Martin 1996), where σ-convergence is a decrease in GDP dispersion, hence showing how the distribution of income evolves, and β-convergence points to a negative relationship between growth and initial level of GDP.

  5. 5.

    Recent comment by Vice President of the European Commission, Vivane Reding, who is the longest serving Brussels commissioner, is simply a re-confirmation. She called for the EU (European Union) to become a “United States of Europe as the best weapon against the Euro-skeptics.” She further argued that “We need to build a United States of Europe with the Commission as government and two chambers…………,” implying that individual sovereignty would be a thing of the past.

  6. 6.

    Under certain circumstances, however, Stiglitz (2010) shows that risk sharing can be unfavorable. While the more integrated the regional economy the better risks can be dispersed, risk sharing can lower expected utility when the standard assumption of convexity and concave utility function does not hold. In particular, this is true when technologies are not convex. Following this dictum, and given the fact that information, externalities, and learning processes may give rise to a natural set of non-convexities, the intuition that integration should be desirable is not always accurate.

  7. 7.

    A customs union is a form of regional integration likely to cause the largest trade diversion, where effects are distributed unequally.

  8. 8.

    The trade-off between trade creation and trade diversion is often used to back north-south FTAs. South-south FTAs are more prone to trade diversion.

  9. 9.

    The convergence effect of regionalization on between-country income inequality in Europe outweighs the polarizing effect of regionalization on within-country inequality, such that the net total income inequality has declined. In other words, regional integration has a positive net effect on reducing total income inequality (Scharpf 1997).

  10. 10.

    Inequality can also affect poverty by way of determining the growth-poverty elasticity. Added by the well-known effect of growth on poverty, a triangular relation between growth, inequality, and poverty is established [see (Bourguignon 2004)].

  11. 11.

    OECD and International Labour Organization (ILO) 2012. Joint statement by ILO Director-General Juan Somavia and OECD Secretary-General Angel Gurría on the occasion of the G20 Labour and Employment Ministers Meeting. Guadalajara, Mexico, 17 May.

  12. 12.

    A similar principle can also be applied to the concept of globalization; see Rodrik (2011).

  13. 13.

    In the 1990s alone, financial crisis struck Europe (1992/1993), Mexico/Latin America (1994), Asia (1997), Eastern Europe and Russia (1998). The recent global financial crisis began in the US and Europe. Crisis contagion has also become less regional and more global. Technology and information enable financial spillovers by reducing structural distance.

  14. 14.

    Most analysis suggests the easy money policy in advanced economies was less effective than originally thought. The policy not only failed to strengthen recovery in the US and other advanced economies, but also provoked global monetary instability through capital flows, including those led by “carry traders,” who exploit interest rate differentials across countries. See Mckinnon (2012).

  15. 15.

    The amplified effect of cross-border flows on the supply of credit due to the changing risk behavior of banks is shown in Valentina and Shin (2012).

  16. 16.

    For example, in the Republic of Korea, each 1 % decline in external funding due to European bank deleveraging following the global financial crisis led to a 0.01 % decline in domestic credit by domestic banks [see Jain-Chandra et al. (2013)]. This occurred despite the country’s relatively healthy foreign reserves, government efforts to provide foreign currency liquidity through bilateral and multilateral currency swap arrangements, and macroprudential measures that lowered domestic banks’ reliance on short-term wholesale funding.

  17. 17.

    See Forbes and Warnock (2012). However, unlike their analysis, I distinguish “debt” from “bank” because banks are more prone to deleveraging and procyclicality, thus having more direct impact on the real sector.

  18. 18.

    In a standard computable general equilibrium (CGE) model, for example, the allocation between the domestic market (D) and imports (M) follows Armington’s constant elasticity of substitution (CES), while the allocation between domestic market (D) and exports (E) follows a constant elasticity of transformation (CET).

  19. 19.

    The dynamics of the use of imported inputs to produce exported goods, known as vertical specialization (VS), is analyzed in Hummels et al. (2001). Amador and Cabral (2009) show that vertical specialization (VS) in high-tech products has increased dramatically since the 1980s, especially in emerging Asia. Some even label it a new paradigm in the organization of world production, representing an important element of international trade.

  20. 20.

    The effect of income level on macro variables works through the expenditure side. Together with government expenditure (GD) and net exports (E-M), real consumption (CD) reflects the size of agents’ expenditure (EXP) out of their disposable income (YCON). The latter is determined by the income level (INC).

  21. 21.

    Note that lending (BANKLOAN) is not only determined by the size of a bank’s available funds, but also by changes in net worth and external finance premia of both borrowers and lenders; this “credit channel” hypothesis was elaborated in Bernanke et al. (1996), Adrian and Shin (2009), Stiglitz and Greenwald (2003), and Stiglitz (2001).

  22. 22.

    Other financial variables can also affect aggregate economic activity by way of the money market.

  23. 23.

    Changes in the exchange rate also cause some valuation effects: the local currency value of any assets denominated in foreign currencies will increase (decrease) when local currency appreciates (depreciates).

  24. 24.

    Aside from income inequality, poverty and unemployment (UEMPR) are two other social indicators endogenously determined in the model. While unemployment is derived from the difference between labor demand (L) and fixed labor supply, the aggregate variables in the real sector (X, D, E, M, and Q) are all determined along with their respective prices (PX, PD, PE, PM, and PQ). It is PQ that sets the overall price index (PINDEX). The poverty line (PL) can be derived from this. When PL is matched with the endogenously determined household income, the poverty level can be estimated.

  25. 25.

    Indonesia is selected because like most emerging markets, its financial sector has been growing rapidly since financial liberalization began in the 1980s, and income inequality has worsened. Indonesia also became a primary destination for capital flows once advanced economies set ultra-easy monetary policy.

  26. 26.

    The model version used in the analysis here follows Min (2014). Due to space constraint, the detailed explanations of the model and simulation results are not shown here (they are available upon request).

  27. 27.

    On the asset side, other than reducing loan-to-value ratio, efforts to contain excessive credit expansion and other risky investments are also made. On the liability side, mitigating the increase of non-core liabilities through bank-led flows is critical because they can heighten risky bank behavior and increase leverage. See Azis and Shin (2013) and Forbes and Warnock (2012).

  28. 28.

    For the status of Asia’s regional financial safety nets, see Azis (2012).

  29. 29.

    For example, under the BENEFIT scenario in Table 9.1, three eigen-vectors are shown (“Ideals,” “Normals,” and “Raw”). While all three give the same ranking, i.e., encourage outflows being most preferred, followed by assigning levies, and regional financial safety nets (hence the ranking shown in the last column of Table 9.1), the normalized eigen-vector (0.4381; 0.4358; and 0.1261) under “Normal” with the sum equals unity is the most often used. All numbers under the column “Benefit,” “Opportunity,” “Cost,” and “Risk” in Table 9.2 show the normalized eigen-vector.

References

  • Adrian T, Shin HS (2009) Money, liquidity and monetary policy. Am Econ Rev 99(2):600–605

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alderson AS, Nielsen F (2002) Globalization and the great U-Turn: income inequality trends in 16 OECD countries. Am J Sociol 107:1244–1299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amador J, Cabral S (2009) Vertical specialization across the world: a relative measure. North Am J Econ Financ 20:267–280

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arestis P, Paliginis E (1995) Divergence and peripheral fordism in the European Union. Rev Soc Econ 53:261–283

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong HW (1995) An appraisal of the evidence from cross-sectional analysis of the regional growth process within the European Union. In: Armstrong HW, Vickerman RW (eds) Convergence and divergence among European regions. Pion, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Asian Development Bank (2012) Asian development bank outlook 2012: confronting rising inequality in Asia. Manila

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (1997) Impacts of Economic reform on rural-urban welfare: a general equilibrium framework. Rev Urban Reg Develop Stud 9(1):1–19

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2000) The non-linear general equilibrium impact of the financial crisis and manufacturing downfall. Develop Econ 38(4):518–546

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2003) Modeling the repercussions of financial shock on socio-economic indicators. In: Ananta A (ed) The Indonesian crisis: a human development perspective. Institute of Southeast Asian Studies, Singapore

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2004) Modeling the disconnect between financial policy and real sector using the financial social accounting matrix as a data system: the case of Indonesia. In: Charles J (ed) Banking disintermediation and its implication to monetary policy: a theoretical view and country experiences bank. Indonesia, Jakarta

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2007) Articulating the benefits and costs of regional financial arrangement in East Asia. In: Simorangkir I (ed) Global imbalances and their impact on emerging market economies: issues and challenges. Bank Indonesia, Jakarta

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2008) Fiscal policy and workouts from debt crises: the case of Indonesia’s domestic debt. IPD Working Paper, Columbia University, New York, pp 1–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2009) Regional financial arrangement. In: Azis IJ (ed) Crisis, complexity and conflict. Emerald, London

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ (2012) Asian regional financial safety nets? Don’t hold your breath. Pub Policy Rev 8(3):321–340

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ, Shin HS (2013) How do global liquidity phases manifest themselves in Asia? Asian Development Bank, Manila

    Google Scholar 

  • Azis IJ, Yarcia D (2014) How capital flows affect economy-wide vulnerability and inequality: flow-of-funds analysis of selected Asian economies. ADB Working Paper Series on Regional Economic Integration, No 136

    Google Scholar 

  • Backus DK, Kehoe JP, Kydland FE (1992) International real business cycles. J Polit Econ 100(4):745–775

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai Y, Jin Z (2005) Financial integration and international risk sharing. Working Paper, Department of Economics, Arizona State University

    Google Scholar 

  • Baysan T, Arvind P, Nihal P (2006) Preferential trading in South Asia. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, 3813. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Beckfield J (2009) Remapping inequality in Europe: the net effect of regional integration on total income inequality in the European Union. Int J Comp Sociol 50(5–6):486–509

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ben-David D (2001) Trade liberalization and income convergence: a comment. J Int Econ 55:229–234

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke BS, Gertler M, Gilchrist S (1996) The financial accelerator and the flight to quality. Rev Econ Stat 78(1):1–15

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Borensztein E, Loungani P (2011) Asian financial integration: trends and interruptions. IMF Working Paper, No. 11/4, January, 2011

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourguignon F (2004) The poverty-growth-inequality triangle. Paper Presented at the Indian Council for Research on International Economic Relations, New Delhi

    Google Scholar 

  • Brady D (2003) The politics of poverty: left political institutions, the welfare state and poverty. Soc Forces 82(2):557–588

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cameron DR (1978) The expansion of the public economy: a comparative analysis. Am Polit Sci Rev 72:1243–1261

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Canova F, Ravn MO (1996) International consumption risk sharing. Int Econ Rev 37(3)

    Google Scholar 

  • CIEPR-Committee on International Economic Policy and Reform (2012) Banks and cross-border capital flows: policy challenges and regulatory responses. Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Cochrane JH (1991) A simple test of consumption insurance. J Polit Econ 99(5):957–976

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forbes KJ, Warnock F (2012) Capital flow waves: surges, stops, flight and retrenchment. J Int Econ 88(2):235–251

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • French KR, Poterba JM (1991) Investor diversification and international equity markets. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, vol 81, pp 222–226

    Google Scholar 

  • Hummels D, Ishii J, Yi K-M (2001) The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade. J Int Econ 54(1):75–96

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • International Monetary Fund (2012) The liberalization and management of capital flows: an institutional view. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Jain-Chandra S, Kim MJ, Park SH, Shin J (2013) The impact of Foreign Bank deleveraging on Korea. IMF Working Paper, WP/13/101, Washington DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Leonardi R (1995) Convergence, cohesion, and integration in the European Union. St. Martin’s Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Levine R (2001) International financial liberalization and economic growth. Rev Int Econ 9(4):668–702

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Machiko N, Thorbecke E (2010) The poor under globalization in Asia, Latin America, and Africa. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin XS (1996) Regional cohesion: evidence and theories of regional growth and convergence. Eur Econ Rev 40:1325–1352

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mckinnon R (2012) Zero interest rates in the United States provoke World Monetary instability and constrict the US economy. SIEPR Policy Brief, Stanford University

    Google Scholar 

  • Mendoza EG (1995) The terms of trade, the real exchange rate and economic fluctuations. Int Econ Rev 36:101–137

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Min HH (2014) The analysis of the link between capital flows and macroeconomic-financial-spatial income distribution indicators: combining financial CGE and perception models. PhD Dissertation in Regional Science. Cornell University

    Google Scholar 

  • Obstfeld M (1994) Risk-taking, global diversification, and growth. Am Econ Rev 84: 1310–1329

    Google Scholar 

  • Rodrik D (2011) The globalization paradox. Making it. 24 August

    Google Scholar 

  • Saaty TL, Vargas L (2005) Theory and applications of the analytic network process: decision making with benefits, opportunities, costs, and risks. RWS Publication, Pittsburgh, PA

    Google Scholar 

  • Saaty TL, Vargas L (2006) Decision making with the analytic network process. Springer’s International Series

    Google Scholar 

  • Scharpf FW (1997) Economic integration, democracy, and the welfare state. J Eur Pub Policy 4:18–36

    Google Scholar 

  • Slaughter MJ (2001) Trade liberalization and per capita income convergence: a difference-in-differences analysis. J Int Econ 55:203–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2001) Information and the change in the paradigm in economics. Prize Lecture, Nobel Foundation, Stockholm

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE (2010) Risk and global economic architecture: why full financial integration may be undesirable. NBER Working Paper Series. No 15718. NBER, Cambridge, MA)

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz JE, Greenwald BC (2003) Towards a new paradigm in monetary economics. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz J, Amartya Sen E, Fitoussi J-P (2010) Mis-measuring our lives: why GDP doesn’t add up/the report by the commission on the measurement of economic performance and social progress. The New Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolper W, Samuelson PA (1941) Protection and real wages. Rev Econ Stud 9(1):58–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Valentina B, Shin HS (2012) Capital flows and the risk-taking channel of monetary policy. BIS working papers, No 400, December

    Google Scholar 

  • Venables AJ (2009) Economic integration in remote resource-rich regions. OxCarre Working Papers No 022. Oxford Centre for the Analysis of Resource Rich Economies, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Western B (1997) Between class and market: postwar unionization in capitalist democracies. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Iwan J. Azis .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix

The presence of feedback influences in a network model requires a large matrix—known as supermatrix—that contains a set of sub-matrixes. The supermatrix captures the influence of elements in a network on other elements in that network. Denoting a cluster by C h , h = 1, ……m, and assuming that it has nh elements e h1 , e h2 , e h3 ……., e hmh , and laying out all the clusters and all the elements in each cluster both vertically on the left and horizontally at the top, we have the following supermatrix:

Supermatrix of a Network

figure a

The typical entry of this supermatrix is

Entries in Supermatrix of a Network

$$ {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}\mathrm{j}}=\left[\begin{array}{cccc}\hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}1}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_1\right)}\hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}1}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_2\right)}\hfill & \hfill \bullet \bullet \bullet \hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}1}^{\left(\mathrm{j}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{j}}\right)}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}2}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_1\right)}\hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}2}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_2\right)}\hfill & \hfill \bullet \bullet \bullet \hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}1}^{\left(\mathrm{j}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{j}}\right)}\hfill \\ {}\hfill \begin{array}{l}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \end{array}\hfill & \hfill \begin{array}{l}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \end{array}\hfill & \hfill \operatorname{}\operatorname{}\operatorname{}\hfill & \hfill \begin{array}{l}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \\ {}\bullet \end{array}\hfill \\ {}\hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{i}}}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_1\right)}\hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{i}}}^{\left({\mathrm{j}}_2\right)}\hfill & \hfill \bullet \bullet \bullet \hfill & \hfill {\mathrm{W}}_{\mathrm{i}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{i}}}^{\left(\mathrm{j}{\mathrm{n}}_{\mathrm{j}}\right)}\hfill \end{array}\right] $$

The entries of sub-matrixes in W ij are the ratio scales derived from paired comparisons performed on the elements within the clusters themselves according to their influence on each element in another cluster (outer dependence) or elements in their own cluster (inner dependence). Judgments are elicited from which ratio scales are derived. The resulting unweighted supermatrix is then transformed into a matrix where each column sums to unity to generate a stochastic supermatrix. The derived weights are used to weight the elements of the corresponding column blocks (cluster) of the supermatrix, resulting in a weighted supermatrix which is also stochastic. The final ranking is derived from the limiting supermatrix, obtained by raising the stochastic supermatrix to large powers to read off final priorities, in which all matrix columns are identical. Each gives the relative priorities of the elements from which the priorities of the elements in each cluster are normalized to one (the powers of the supermatrix do not converge unless it is stochastic, ensuring that its largest eigenvalue is one). Using the example of the EXPAND component under the BENEFIT cluster in Fig. 9.10, the resulting limiting supermatrix is

Limiting super matrix

  

Alternatives

Goal

EXPAND

     
 

Encourage Outflows

Assign Levy

Reg Safety Nets

EXPAND

CD

FIN INC

FINTM

ID

Alternatives

Encourage Outflows

0.18477

0.18477

0.18477

0.18477

0.18477

0.18477

0.18477

0.1848

 

Assign Levy

0.23605

0.23605

0.23605

0.23605

0.23605

0.23605

0.23605

0.2361

 

Reg Safety Nets

0.07918

0.07918

0.07918

0.07918

0.07918

0.07918

0.07918

0.0792

Goal

EXPAND

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

0

EXPAND

CD

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

0.0745

 

FIN INC

0.15758

0.15758

0.15758

0.15758

0.15758

0.15758

0.15758

0.1576

 

FINTM

0.13292

0.13292

0.13292

0.13292

0.13292

0.13292

0.13292

0.1329

 

ID

0.135

0.135

0.135

0.135

0.135

0.135

0.135

0.135

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Azis, I.J. (2015). Integration, Contagion, and Income Distribution. In: Nijkamp, P., Rose, A., Kourtit, K. (eds) Regional Science Matters. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-07305-7_9

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics