Skip to main content

Time in Economic Theory

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 1053 Accesses

Abstract

Much of spatial economic theory is based on general economic equilibrium theory, although there are problems in a direct addition of a spatial dimension. The most striking is the lack of an analysis of the role of non-material and material public capital (or infrastructure) in the deduction of a static equilibrium structure or patterns of growth and development of economies. In this paper I demonstrate how different aspects of time can improve our understanding of dynamics of economies.

In this paper I furthermore show that a proper refocusing on the time dimension can also shed light on the structure of economies in space. Four approaches are necessary for such a synthesis.

  1. 1.

    Subdivision of products and systems of production according to their different and always positive durability, implying that everything produced is capital.

  2. 2.

    Subdivision of products according to the time used in their production.

  3. 3.

    Subdivision into private and public goods, allowing for non-linearity.

  4. 4.

    Allowing for differences in time scales of economic processes.

With these distinctions it can be shown that the economic development in time and space is determined by the impact of economies of scale, duration of the production process, durability of products and the—relative to most other kinds of capital—much slower growth of public capital (i.e. material and non-material infrastructure).

This technical paper is closely related to my popular and thus non-technical paper published as Andersson Å.E. (2013) Time, space and capital. In: Andersson DE (ed) Advances in Austrian economics—the spatial market process. Emerald, Bingley

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    If we assume indivisible units of machines and humans and that the productivity of a machine or a human (x(i)) depends on interaction with (x(j)) and if these interaction net benefits can be captured by the quadratic form x’Cx, then there is no simple incentive mechanism or computerized search algorithm that would provide the route to a global maximum for most interaction matrices C (Koopmans and Beckmann 1959).

References

  • Andersson ÅE (2013) Time, space and capital. In: Andersson DE (ed) Advances in Austrian economics—the spatial market process. Emerald, Bingley

    Google Scholar 

  • Andersson ÅE, Kallio M (1982) A mathematical programming approach to land allocation in regional planning. IIASA, Laxenburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ, Hurwicz L (1957) On the stability of the competitive equilibrium. Department of economics technical report 46. Stanford University

    Google Scholar 

  • Böhm-Bawerk E (1959–1921) History and critique of interest theories. Libertarian Press, South Holland, IL (First published as Kapital und Kapitalzins.) Volume 1: History and critique of interest theories, 1884. Volume 2: Positive theory of capital, 1889. Volume 3: Further essays on capital and interest was first published as appendixes to volume 2 of the 1909–1912 edition, and was printed in a separate volume in 1921

    Google Scholar 

  • Bródy A (1970) Proportions, prices and planning. North Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Burmeister E (1974) Synthesizing the Neo-Austrian and alternative approaches to capital theory: a survey. J Econ Lit 12:413–456

    Google Scholar 

  • Cassel G (1918) The theory of social economy, 1932nd edn. Harcourt, Brace and Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase R (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4(16):386–405

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G, Herstein IN (1953) Nonnegative square matrices. Econometrica 21:597

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Debreu G (1959) Theory of value an axiomatic analysis of economic equilibrium. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorfman R (1959) Waiting and the period of production. Q J Econ 73(3):351–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haken H (1977) Synergetics, an introduction. Nonequilibrium phase-transitions and self-organization in physics, chemistry and biology. Springer, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Hayek FA (1941) The pure theory of capital. Routledge and Kegan Paul, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins D (1948) Some conditions of macroeconomic stability. Econometrica 309–322

    Google Scholar 

  • Hawkins D, Simon HA (1949) Note: Some conditions of macroeconomic stability. Econometrica 17:245–224

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks J (1970) A Neo-Austrian growth theory. Econ J 80:257–281

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks J (1973) Capital and time. Clarendon Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Isard W, Liossatos P (1979) Spatial dynamics and optimal space-time development. North-Holland, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons WS (1871/1970) The theory of political economy. Penguin Classics, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman S (1996) At home in the universe. The search for laws of self-organization and complexity. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans TC, Beckmann MJ (1959) Assignment problems and the location of economic activities. Econometrica 15:53–76

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight F (1934) Capital, time, and the interest rate. Economica 257–286

    Google Scholar 

  • Lev B, Theil H (1978) A maximum entropy approach to the choice of asset depreciation. J Accounting Res 16(2):286–293

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lintner J (1965) The valuation of risk assets and the selection of risky investments in stock portfolios and capital budgets. Rev Econ Stat 73:13–37

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz H (1952) Portfolio selection. J Fin 12:71–91

    Google Scholar 

  • Marschak J (1934) A note on the period of production. Econ J, 146–151

    Google Scholar 

  • Modigliani F, Miller M (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance, and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48(3):261–297

    Google Scholar 

  • Mossin J (1966) Equilibrium in a capital asset market. Econometrica 34(4):768–783

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgenstern O (1935) Zur Theorie der Produktionsperiode. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie, (Band VI):196–208

    Google Scholar 

  • Nagurney A (1999) Network economics: a variational inequality approach. Kluwer, Amsterdam

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann J (1937) Über ein ökonomisches Gleichungssystem und eine Verallgemeinerung des Brouwerschen Fixpunktsatzes. In: Menger K (ed) Ergebnisse eines Mathematischen Kolloquiums, 8: 73, 83. Deuticke, Leipzig, Translated as: A Model of General Economic Equilibrium. Review of Economic Studies (1945–1946), 13: 19

    Google Scholar 

  • Puu T (2003) Attractors, bifurcations and chaos. Springer, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: a theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Fin 19(3):425–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugakov VI (1998) Lectures in synergetics, vol 33, Series on Nonlinear Science, Series a. World Scientific, Singapore

    Google Scholar 

  • Thom R (1989) Structural stability and morphogenesis: an outline of a general theory of models. Addison-Wesley, Reading, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • von Thünen JH (1826) Der isolierte Staat in Beziehung auf Landwirthschaft und National-Ökonomie, oder Untersuchungen über den Einfluß, den die Getreidepreise, der Reichthum des Bodens und die Abgaben auf den Ackerbau ausüben. Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • von Thünen JH (1960) The isolated state in relation to agriculture and political economy. Second part. In: Dempsey BW (ed) The frontier wage. The economic organization of free agents. Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Wald A (1936, 1951) On some systems of equations of mathematical economics. Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie (translated in Econometrica 19(4), 368–403

    Google Scholar 

  • Walras L (1874, 1954, Engl. transl.)(Éléments d’économie politique pure, ou théorie de la richesse sociale) Elements of Pure Economics, or the theory of social wealth, transl. W. Jaffé, London: Allen and Unwin

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell K (1966) Föreläsningar i nationalekonomi. Gleerups, Femte upplagan, Lund

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell K (1967) Lectures on political economy. Reprints of economic classics. Augustus M. Kelley Publishers, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell K (1914) Lexis och Böhm-Bawerk. Ekonomisk Tidskrift Årg 16, häfte 11, pp. 322–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson OE (1981) The economics of organization: the transaction cost approach. Am J Sociol 87:548–577

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Åke E. Andersson .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Andersson, Å.E. (2015). Time in Economic Theory. In: Nijkamp, P., Rose, A., Kourtit, K. (eds) Regional Science Matters. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-07305-7_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics