Skip to main content

Sovereign Risk, Monetary Policy and Fiscal Multipliers: A Structural Model-Based Assessment

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:

Abstract

This paper briefly reviews the literature on fiscal multipliers and then presents results for the Italian economy obtained by simulating a dynamic general equilibrium model that allows for the possibility (a) that the zero lower bound may be binding and (b) that the initial public debt-to-GDP ratio may affect the financing conditions of the public and private sectors (sovereign risk channel). The results are the following. First, the public consumption multiplier is in general less than 1. Second, it goes above 1 only under extremely strong assumptions, namely the constancy of the monetary policy rate for an exceptionally long period (at least 5 years) and full time-coincidence between the fiscal and the monetary stimuli. Third, when the sovereign risk channel is active the government consumption multiplier is much lower. Fourth, in all cases tax multipliers are lower than government consumption multipliers. Finally, we make a tentative assessment of the fiscal consolidation measures enacted in Italy in 2011–2012: the evidence is that the impact on GDP was much weaker than the IMF had expected.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Government spending is treated as pure waste in the analysis, in order to focus on the pure macroeconomic effects of fiscal policy as a determinant of aggregate demand in the short run. So it does not directly affect households’ welfare or firm’s productivity.

  2. 2.

    The most-cited reference on this regard is Baxter and King (1993). The numbers for the fiscal multipliers quoted in this section refer to their paper. Under fairly general conditions, there is no difference between a debt-financed and a tax-financed fiscal stimulus, provided the latter is based on lump-sum taxes. Baxter and King (1993) consider a fiscal expansion financed by lump-sum taxes.

  3. 3.

    As for the change in government spending, variations in consumption and investment are measured in terms of units of output.

  4. 4.

    Once again it is assumed that the increase in government spending is unexpected but that it is immediately known to last for T years.

  5. 5.

    A short-run multiplier greater than 1 is also possible if the labour supply is highly elastic.

  6. 6.

    The finding that temporary stimulus is less effective than permanent is not trivial. Barro (1981) and Hall (1980) reach opposite conclusions.

  7. 7.

    See Haavelmo (1945).

  8. 8.

    Rule-of-thumb consumers are non-Ricardian. They consume just what they earn, regardless of the impact of government spending on the inter-temporal budget constraint. The larger the share of these non-optimizing agents, the smaller the (negative) impact of wealth effects on consumption and the higher the multiplier.

  9. 9.

    (u l ) must be equal to the (real) wage rate (w) times the marginal utility of consumption (u c ), i.e. u l  = wu c . Households’ labour-supply decision is driven by the intra-temporal equilibrium condition, which states that the marginal utility of leisure (u) must be equal to the (real) wage rate (w) times the marginal utility of consumption (u), i.e. u wu. Because of the negative wealth effect of additional government spending, consumption falls and its marginal utility increases; to restore the equilibrium, either leisure has to diminish (i.e. hours worked have to increase) and/or the real wage has to fall. In the standard Neo-classical (i.e. real business cycle model) both things happen. By preventing the real wage to change, all the adjustment is born by the labour supply, that accordingly has to increase more, boosting the output response to a fiscal stimulus.

  10. 10.

    Woodford (2011) adds an additional condition, namely that the tax increase required to finance the budget deficit also lasts only as long as the constraint binds.

  11. 11.

    DeLong and Summers (2012) provide an example: an incremental $1.00 of government spending raises future output permanently by $0.015 if (1) the fiscal multiplier is 1.5; (2) the average income tax rate is 33 %; (3) the real interest rate on long-term government debt is fixed at 1 %.

  12. 12.

    Leigh et al. (2010) present estimates for 15 developed countries, including the US. However, they consider not the standard government-purchases multiplier but average multipliers, referring to fiscal packages consisting of a mixture of transfers, taxes and purchases. They find that on average a fiscal consolidation equal to 1 percentage point of GDP reduces output after 2 years by half a point and increases the unemployment rate by 0.3 points.

  13. 13.

    The critical issue is to distinguish variations in government spending that represent real changes in the fiscal policy stance from those due to economic events. One solution is to focus on military buildups, on the assumption that this type of spending is the least likely to respond to economic events. Nevertheless, as Ramey (2011b) points out, there is always the possibility that the events that lead to these buildups—e.g. the onset of World War II or the Cold War—could have other effects on the economy, apart from those on government spending, that could bias the estimates of the multiplier. For example, during World War II a surge of patriotism could have expanded the labour supply by more than would have been predicted by economic incentives alone, increasing the multiplier. By contrast, rationing and capacity constraints could have held it down.

    An additional factor complicating identification is that government spending shocks are most often anticipated, implying that the econometrician does not have all the information that economic agents may have. That is, individual agents’ expectations may not be based just on past information from the variables in the empirical model. So errors of expectation or forecasting cannot be the residuals of the econometrician’s model and the shocks to be studied may not be forecast errors and may be non-fundamental. See Ramey (2011b) and Perotti (2011).

  14. 14.

    Ramey (2011b) lists a number of studies dealing with this issue.

  15. 15.

    See e.g. the evidence in Cogan et al. (2010) and Coenen et al. (2012).

  16. 16.

    For example, for a 12-quarter increase in government spending the impact multiplier is roughly 1.6, with a peak value of about 2.3.

  17. 17.

    Note that none of the recessions in their sample (except possibly the last) qualifies as a depression, in which the policy interest rate is at (or close to) the zero lower-bound.

  18. 18.

    In this case the fiscal multiplier does not refer to government purchases but measures the output response to all the fiscal consolidation measures on both the revenue and the expenditure sides adopted in the sample countries.

  19. 19.

    On these two points, see Financial Times (2012).

  20. 20.

    On the third and fourth point, see European Commission (2012a).

  21. 21.

    See European Central Bank (2012).

  22. 22.

    The parameter s is the size of the Italian population, which is also equal to the number of firms in each Italian sector (final non-tradable, intermediate tradable and intermediate non-tradable). Similar assumptions hold for the REA and the RW.

  23. 23.

    See Rotemberg (1982).

  24. 24.

    The rest of the model is set out in the appendix.

  25. 25.

    See Corsetti and Mueller (20062008).

  26. 26.

    The definition of nominal GDP is:

    $$\displaystyle{ \mathit{GDP}_{t} = P_{t}C_{t} + P_{t}^{I}I_{t} + P_{ N,t}C_{t}^{g} + P_{t}^{\mathit{EXP}}\mathit{EXP}_{t} - P_{t}^{\mathit{IMP}}\mathit{IMP}_{t} }$$
    (3)

    where P t , \(P_{t}^{I},\) \(P_{t}^{\mathit{EXP}},\) \(P_{t}^{\mathit{IMP}}\) are prices of consumption, investment, exports and imports, respectively.

  27. 27.

    This assumption is deliberately conservative, because it allows us to rule out large and counterfactual macroeconomic responses associated with perfect anticipation of permanent changes in the cost of borrowing. In this respect, the estimated contribution of the sovereign risk channel to our results should be taken as a lower bound.

  28. 28.

    See for instance Leeper (2013).

  29. 29.

    A financial friction μ t  is introduced to guarantee that net asset positions follow a stationary process and the economy converge to a steady state. Revenues from financial intermediation are rebated in a lump-sum way to households in the REA. See Benigno (2009).

  30. 30.

    For details see the appendix.

  31. 31.

    Among others, see Forni et al. (20092010a,b).

  32. 32.

    Spikes came immediately after the downgrade of Portugal in July, the release of the bail-in plan for Private Sector Involvement at the EU summit of 21–22 July, and the announcement of the Greek referendum on 1st November. Domestic events, i.e. the tensions generated by the uncertainty over the fiscal consolidation m also played some role. For a detailed account of the impact of news on the BTP-Bund spread between June 2011 and March 2012, see Pericoli (2012).

  33. 33.

    The decrease in the spread in the initial months of 2012 and since August is not considered in the computation, as it most likely depends on monetary policy.

  34. 34.

    For temporary shocks the long-run multiplier is 0.

  35. 35.

    The implications of distortionary taxation for the spending multiplier are considered below.

  36. 36.

    This is true for bilateral exports and imports to and from REA and RW (not reported for space reasons). Exports decrease more towards the RW, as their prices increase by more than those of the exports towards the REA (the former are more flexible than the latter).

  37. 37.

    REA and RW consumption and investment (not reported) fall slightly to finance the increase in Italian borrowing associated with the fiscal stimulus and the consumption smoothing of Italian households.

  38. 38.

    In what follows, we assume that the central bank does not or cannot steer the short-term nominal interest rate of the monetary union for a certain amount of time. Unlike much of the literature (see for example Corsetti et al. 2012a), we do not posit an exogenous recessionary shock that takes the monetary policy rate down to the ZLB. The reason is that the ZLB holds at EA level and so can be taken as exogenous with respect to changes in Italian economic conditions.

  39. 39.

    In the case of a permanent stimulus, we assume this takes 5 years.

  40. 40.

    See Ministero dell’Economia e delle Finanze (2012).

  41. 41.

    Note that public spending decreases, helping to crowd in household consumption and investment spending.

  42. 42.

    We have also experimented by calibrating the spread on the basis of Corsetti et al. (2012a). According to our elaborations, the spread would increase by 20 basis points in response to a 1-percentage-point expected increase in the public debt-GDP ratio. The results, available upon request, are intermediate between zero-spread case and the case considered in the sensitivity analysis.

  43. 43.

    For a detailed description of the main features of the model see also Bayoumi (2004) and Pesenti (2008).

References

  • Albertazzi U, Ropele T, Sene G, Signoretti FM (2012) The impact of the sovereign debt crisis on the activity of Italian banks. Questioni di Economia e Finanza (occasional papers), no. 133, Bank of Italy

    Google Scholar 

  • Attinasi MG, Checherita-Westphal C, Nickel C (2010) What explains the surge in euro area sovereign spreads during the financial crisis of 2007–09? Public Finance Manag 10:595-645

    Google Scholar 

  • Auerbach A, Gorodnichenko Y (2012) Measuring the output responses to fiscal policy. Am Econ J Econ Policy 4(2):1–27

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro R (1981) Output effects of government purchases. J Polit Econ 83(6):1113–1144

    Google Scholar 

  • Baxter M, King R (1993) Fiscal policy in general equilibrium. Am Econ Rev 83(3):315–334

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T (2004) GEM: a new international macroeconomic model. IMF occasional paper no. 239

    Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi T, Laxton D, Pesenti P (2004) Benefits and spillovers of greater competition in europe: a macroeconomic assessment. NBER working paper no. 10416

    Google Scholar 

  • Belhocine N, Dell’Erba S (2013) The impact of debt sustainability and the level of debt on emerging markets spreads. IMF working paper no.13/93, May

    Google Scholar 

  • Benigno P (2009) Price stability with imperfect financial integration. J Money Credit Bank 41(1):121–149

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ (1990) Comment on Giavazzi-Pagano. In: NBER macroeconomics annual. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Leigh D (2013) Growth forecast errors and fiscal multipliers. IMF working paper no. 13/1, January

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard OJ, Summers LH (1986) Hysteresis and the European unemployment problem. In: NBER macroeconomic annual. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Borgy V, Laubach T, Mésonnier JS, Renne JP (2011) Fiscal sustainability, default risk and the euro area sovereign bond spreads. Banque de France Document de Travail no. 350

    Google Scholar 

  • Braun AR, Körber LM, Waki Y (2012) Some unpleasant properties of log-linearized solutions when the nominal rate is zero. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta working paper no. 2012–5a

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell JY, Mankiw NG (1989) International evidence on the persistence of economic fluctuations. J Monet Econ 23(2):319–333

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christiano L, Eichenbaum M, Rebelo S (2011) When is the government spending multiplier large? J Polit Econ 119(1):78–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christoffel K, Coenen G, Warne A (2008) The new area-wide model of the euro area: a micro-founded open-economy model for forecasting and policy analysis. ECB working paper series no. 944

    Google Scholar 

  • Coenen G, Erceg C, Freedman C, Furceri D, Kumhof M, Lalonde R, Laxton D, Lind J, Mourougane A, Muir D, Mursula S, de Resende C, Roberts J, Roeger W, Snudden S, Trabandt M, in’t Veld J (2012) Effects of fiscal stimulus in structural models. Am Econ J Macroecon 4(1):22–68

    Google Scholar 

  • Cogan JF, Cwik T, Taylor JB, Wieland V (2010) New Keynesian and old Keynesian government spending multipliers. J Econ Dyn Control 34(3):281–295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Mueller GJ (2006) Twin deficits: squaring theory, evidence and common sense. Econ Policy 21(48):597–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Mueller GJ (2008) Twin deficits, openness and the business cycle. J Eur Econ Assoc 6(2–3):404–413

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Kuester K, Meier A, Mueller GJ (2012a) Sovereign risk, fiscal policy, and macroeconomic stability. IMF working papern no. 12/33

    Google Scholar 

  • Corsetti G, Meier A, Müller GJ (2012b) What determines government spending multipliers? Econ Policy 27(72):521–565

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeLong JB, Summers LH (2012) Fiscal policy in a depressed economy. Presented to BPEA, March 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson G (2001) Real government spending in a liquidity trap. Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • European Central Bank (2012) Monthly Bullettin, December, Box 6

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2012a) European Economic Forecast, Box 1.5, Autumn

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission (2012b) AMECO Database

    Google Scholar 

  • Eurostat (2012) Taxation Trends in the European Union

    Google Scholar 

  • Financial Times (2012) Robustness of IMF Data Scrutinised, October

    Google Scholar 

  • Forni L, Monteforte L, Sessa L (2009) The general equilibrium effects of fiscal policy: estimates for the euro area. J Public Econ 93(3–4):559–585

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forni L, Gerali A, Pisani M (2010a) The macroeconomics of fiscal consolidations in euro area countries. J Econ Dyn Control 34(9):1791–1812

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forni L, Gerali A, Pisani M (2010b) Macroeconomic effects of greater competition in the service sector: the case of Italy. Macroecon Dyn 14(5):677–708

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, López-Salído JD, Vallés J (2004) Rule-of-thumb consumers and the design of interest rate rules. J Money Credit Bank 36(4):739–764

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Galí J, López-Salído JD, Vallés J (2007) Understanding the effects of government spending on consumption. J Eur Econ Assoc 5(1):227–270

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gomes S, Jacquinot P, Pisani M (2012) The EAGLE: a model for policy analysis of macroeconomic interdependence in the euro area. Econ Model 29(5):1686–1714

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gruber JW, Kamin SB (2012) Fiscal positions and government bond yields in OECD countries. J Money Credit Bank 44(8):1563–1587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haavelmo T (1945) Multiplier effects of a balanced budget. Econometrica 13(4):311–318

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hall R (1980) Labor supply and aggregate fluctuations. In: Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, vol 12

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall R (2009) By how much does GDP rise if the government buys more output? Brookings Papers Econ Act 40(2):183–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laubach T (2009) New evidence on the interest rate effects of budget deficits and debt. J Eur Econ Assoc 7(4):858–885

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laubach T (2012) Fiscal policy and interest rates: the role of sovereign default risk. Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Leeper EM (2013) Fiscal limits and monetary policy. Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Leigh D, Devries P, Freedman C, Guajardo J, Laxton D, Pescatori A (2010) Will it hurt? Macroeconomic effects of fiscal consolidation. World Economic Outlook, October, International Monetary Fund

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministero dell’Economia e delle Finanze (2012) Documento di economia e finanza 2012

    Google Scholar 

  • Neri S (2013) The impact of the sovereign debt crisis on bank lending rates in the euro area. Questioni di Economia e Finanza (occasional papers), no. 170, Bank of Italy

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickel C, Tudyka A (2013) Fiscal stimulus in times of high debt: reconsidering multipliers and twin deficits. ECB working paper, no. 1513, February

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2012) Structural Analysis Database. Available at http://www.oecd.org/industry/ind/stanstructuralanalysisdatabase.htm

  • Owyang MT, Ramey VA, Zubairy S (2013) Are government spending multipliers greater during periods of slack? In: Evidence from 20th Century Historical Data, AEA Papers and Proceedings, (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Pericoli M (2012) News, political uncertainty and the Italian sovereign risk premium from June 2011 to March 2012. Mimeo

    Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (1999) Fiscal policy in good times and bad. Q J Econ 114(4):1399–1436

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perotti R (2011) Expectations and fiscal policy: an empirical investigation. GRASP working paper no. 19

    Google Scholar 

  • Pesenti P (2008) The global economy model (GEM): theoretical framework. IMF Staff Papers 55(2):243–284

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey VA (2011a) Identifying government spending shocks: it’s all in the timing. Q J Econ 22:1–50

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey VA (2011b) Can government purchases stimulate the economy? J Econ Literature 49(3):673–685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ramey VA (2012) Discussant Comments on Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy, by J.B. DeLong and L.H. Summers

    Google Scholar 

  • Rotemberg JJ (1982) Monopolistic price adjustment and aggregate output. Rev Econ Stud 49(4):517–531

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sutherland A (1997) Fiscal crises and aggregate demand: can high public debt reverse the effects of fiscal policy? J Public Econ 65(2):147–162

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Woodford M (2011) Simple analytics of the government expenditure multiplier. Am Econ J Macroecon 3(1):1–35

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zoli E (2013) Italian sovereign spreads: their determinants and pass-through to bank funding costs and lending conditions. IMF working paper no. 13/84, April

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank Fabio Canova, Francesco Nucci and participants at Villa Mondragone International Economic Seminar 2013 for useful comments. The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the Bank of Italy.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Massimiliano Pisani .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix

Appendix

In this appendix we report a detailed description of the model, excluding the fiscal and monetary policy part and the description of the households optimization problem that are reported in the main text.Footnote 43

There are three countries, Italy, the rest of the euro area (REA) and the rest of the world (RW). They have different sizes. Italy and the REA share the currency and the monetary authority. In each region there are households and firms. Each household consumes a final composite good made of non-tradable, domestic tradable and imported intermediate goods. Households have access to financial markets and smooth consumption by trading a risk-free one-period nominal bond, denominated in euro. They also own domestic firms and capital stock, which is rent to domestic firms in a perfectly competitive market. Households supply differentiated labor services to domestic firms and act as wage setters in monopolistically competitive markets by charging a markup over their marginal rate of substitution.

On the production side, there are perfectly competitive firms that produce the final goods and monopolistic firms that produce the intermediate goods. Two final goods (private consumption and private investment) are produced combining all available intermediate goods according to constant-elasticity-of-substitution bundle. The public consumption good is a bundle of intermediate non-tradable goods.

Tradable and non-tradable intermediate goods are produced combining capital and labor in the same way. Tradable intermediate goods can be sold domestically or abroad. Because intermediate goods are differentiated, firms have market power and restrict output to create excess profits. We assume that goods markets are internationally segmented and the law of one price for tradables does not hold. Hence, each firm producing a tradable good sets three prices, one for the domestic market and the other two for the export market (one for each region). Since the firm faces the same marginal costs regardless of the scale of production in each market, the different price-setting problems are independent of each other.

To capture the empirical persistence of the aggregate data and generate realistic dynamics, we include adjustment costs on real and nominal variables, ensuring that, in response to a shock, consumption and production react in a gradual way. On the real side, quadratic costs and habit prolong the adjustment of the investment and consumption. On the nominal side, quadratic costs make wage and prices sticky.

In what follows we illustrate the Italian economy. The structure of each of the other two regions (REA and the RW) is similar and to save on space we do not report it.

1.1 Final Consumption and Investment Goods

There is a continuum of symmetric Italian firms producing final non-tradable consumption under perfect competition. Each firm producing the consumption good is indexed by \(x \in \left (0,s\right ]\), where the parameter 0 < s < 1 measures the size of Italy. Firms in the REA and in the RW are indexed by \(x^{{\ast}}\in \left (s,S\right ]\) and \(x^{{\ast}{\ast}}\in \left (S,1\right ]\), respectively (the size of the world economy is normalized to 1). The CES production technology used by the generic firm x is:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & A_{t}\left (x\right ) {}\\ & & \quad \equiv \left (\begin{array}{c} a_{T}^{ \frac{1} {\phi _{A}} }\left (a_{H}^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{A}} }Q_{\mathit{HA},t}\left (x\right )^{\frac{\rho _{A}-1} {\rho _{A}} } + a_{G}^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{A}} }Q_{\mathit{GA},t}\left (x\right )^{\frac{\rho _{A}-1} {\rho _{A}} }\left (1 - a_{H} - a_{G}\right )^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{A}} }Q_{\mathit{FA},t}\left (x\right )^{\frac{\rho _{A}-1} {\rho _{A}} }\right )^{ \frac{\rho _{A}} {\rho _{A}-1} \frac{\phi _{A}-1} {\phi _{A}} } \\ + \left (1 - a_{T}\right )^{ \frac{1} {\phi _{A}} }Q_{\mathit{NA},t}\left (x\right )^{\frac{\phi _{A}-1} {\phi _{A}} } \end{array} \right )^{ \frac{\phi _{A}} {\phi _{A}-1} }{}\\ \end{array}$$

where Q HA , Q GA , Q FA and Q NA are bundles of respectively intermediate tradables produced in Italy, intermediate tradables produced in the REA, intermediate tradables produced in the RW and intermediate non-tradables produced in Italy. The parameter ρ A  > 0 is the elasticity of substitution between tradables and ϕ A  > 0 is the elasticity of substitution between tradable and non-tradable goods. The parameter a H (0 < a H  < 1) is the weight of the Italian tradable, the parameter a G (0 < a G  < 1) the weight of tradables imported from the REA, a T (0 < a T  < 1) the weight of tradable goods.

The production of investment good is similar. There are symmetric Italian firms under perfect competition indexed by \(y \in \left (0,s\right ]\). Firms in the REA and in the RW are indexed by \(y^{{\ast}}\in \left (s,S\right ]\) and \(y^{{\ast}{\ast}}\in \left (S,1\right ]\). Output of the generic Italian firm y is:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & E_{t}\left (y\right ) {}\\ & & \quad \equiv \left (\begin{array}{@{}c@{}} v_{T}^{ \frac{1} {\phi _{E}} }\left (v_{H}^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{E}} }Q_{\mathit{HE},t}\left (y\right )^{\frac{\rho _{E}-1} {\rho _{E}} }\,+\,v_{G}^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{E}} }Q_{\mathit{GE},t}\left (y\right )^{\frac{\rho _{E}-1} {\rho _{E}} }\,+\,\left (1-v_{H}-v_{G}\right )^{ \frac{1} {\rho _{E}} }Q_{\mathit{FE},t}\left (y\right )^{\frac{\rho _{E}-1} {\rho _{E}} }\right )^{ \frac{\rho _{E}} {\rho _{E}-1} \frac{\phi _{E}-1} {\phi _{E}} } \\ + \left (1 - v_{T}\right )^{ \frac{1} {\phi _{E}} }Q_{\mathit{NE},t}\left (y\right )^{\frac{\phi _{E}-1} {\phi _{E}} } \end{array} \right )^{ \frac{\phi _{E}} {\phi _{E}-1} }{}\\ \end{array}$$

Finally, we assume that public consumption C g is composed by intermediate non-tradable goods only.

1.2 Intermediate Goods

1.2.1 Demand

Bundles used to produce the final consumption goods are CES indexes of differentiated intermediate goods, each produced by a single firm under conditions of monopolistic competition:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} Q_{\mathit{HA}}\left (x\right ) \equiv \left [\left (\frac{1} {s}\right )^{\theta _{T}}\int _{0}^{s}Q\left (h,x\right )^{\frac{\theta _{T}-1} {\theta _{T}} }\mathit{dh}\right ]^{ \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T}-1} }& &{}\end{array}$$
(16)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} Q_{\mathit{GA}}\left (x\right ) \equiv \left [\left ( \frac{1} {S - s}\right )^{\theta _{T}}\int _{s}^{S}Q\left (g,x\right )^{\frac{\theta _{T}-1} {\theta _{T}} }\mathit{dg}\right ]^{ \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T}-1} }& &{}\end{array}$$
(17)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} Q_{\mathit{FA}}\left (x\right ) \equiv \left [\left ( \frac{1} {1 - S}\right )^{\theta _{T}}\int _{S}^{1}Q\left (f,x\right )^{\frac{\theta _{T}-1} {\theta _{T}} }\mathit{df }\right ]^{ \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T}-1} }& &{}\end{array}$$
(18)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} Q_{\mathit{NA}}\left (x\right ) \equiv \left [\left (\frac{1} {s}\right )^{\theta _{N}}\int _{0}^{s}Q\left (n,x\right )^{\frac{\theta _{N}-1} {\theta _{N}} }\mathit{dn}\right ]^{ \frac{\theta _{N}} {\theta _{T}-1} }& &{}\end{array}$$
(19)

where firms in the Italian intermediate tradable and non-tradable sectors are respectively indexed by h ∈ (0, s) and n ∈ (0, s), firms in the REA by g ∈ (s, S] and firms in the RW by f ∈ (S, 1]. Parameters θ T , θ N  > 1 are respectively the elasticity of substitution across brands in the tradable and non-tradable sector. The prices of the intermediate non-tradable goods are denoted p(n). Each firm x takes these prices as given when minimizing production costs of the final good. The resulting demand for intermediate non-tradable input n is:

$$\displaystyle{ Q_{A,t}\left (n,x\right ) = \left (\frac{1} {s}\right )\left (\frac{P_{t}\left (n\right )} {P_{N,t}} \right )^{-\theta _{N} }Q_{\mathit{NA},t}\left (x\right ) }$$
(20)

where P N, t is the cost-minimizing price of one basket of local intermediates:

$$\displaystyle{ P_{N,t} = \left [\int _{0}^{s}P_{ t}\left (n\right )^{1-\theta _{N} }\mathit{dn}\right ]^{ \frac{1} {1-\theta _{N}} } }$$
(21)

We can derive \(Q_{A}\left (h,x\right )\), \(Q_{A}\left (f,x\right )\), \(C_{A}^{g}\left (h,x\right )\), \(C_{A}^{g}\left (f,x\right )\), P H and P F in a similar way. Firms y producing the final investment goods have similar demand curves. Aggregating over x and y, it can be shown that total demand for intermediate non-tradable good n is:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & \int _{0}^{s}Q_{ A,t}\left (n,x\right )\mathit{dx} +\int _{ 0}^{s}Q_{ E,t}\left (n,y\right )\mathit{dy} +\int _{ 0}^{s}C_{ t}^{g}\left (n,x\right )\mathit{dx} {}\\ & =& \left (\frac{P_{t}\left (n\right )} {P_{N,t}} \right )^{-\theta _{N} }\left (Q_{\mathit{NA},t} + Q_{\mathit{NE},t} + C_{N,t}^{g}\right ) {}\\ \end{array}$$

where \(C_{N}^{g}\) is public sector consumption. Italy demands for (intermediate) domestic and imported tradable goods can be derived in a similar way.

1.2.2 Supply

The supply of each Italian intermediate non-tradable good n is denoted by N S(n):

$$\displaystyle{ N_{t}^{S}\left (n\right ) = \left (\left (1 -\alpha _{ N}\right )^{ \frac{1} {\xi _{N}} }L_{N,t}\left (n\right )^{\frac{\xi _{N}-1} {\xi _{N}} } +\alpha ^{ \frac{1} {\xi _{N}} }K_{N,t}\left (n\right )^{\frac{\xi _{N}-1} {\xi _{N}} }\right )^{ \frac{\xi _{N}} {\xi _{N}-1} } }$$
(22)

Firm n uses labor \(L_{N,t}^{p}\left (n\right )\) and capital \(K_{N,t}\left (n\right )\) with constant elasticity of input substitution ξ N  > 0 and capital weight 0 < α N  < 1. Firms producing intermediate goods take the prices of labor inputs and capital as given. Denoting W t the nominal wage index and R t K the nominal rental price of capital, cost minimization implies:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} & & L_{N,t}\left (n\right ) = \left (1 -\alpha _{N}\right )\left ( \frac{W_{t}} {\mathit{MC}_{N,t}\left (n\right )}\right )^{-\xi _{N} }N_{t}^{S}\left (n\right ) \\ & & \qquad K_{N,t}\left (n\right ) =\alpha \left ( \frac{R_{t}^{K}} {\mathit{MC}_{N,t}\left (n\right )}\right )^{-\xi _{N} }N_{t}^{S}\left (n\right ) {}\end{array}$$
(23)

where \(\mathit{MC}_{N,t}\left (n\right )\) is the nominal marginal cost:

$$\displaystyle{ \mathit{MC}_{N,t}\left (n\right ) = \left (\left (1-\alpha \right )W_{t}^{1-\xi _{N} } +\alpha \left (R_{t}^{K}\right )^{1-\xi _{N} }\right )^{ \frac{1} {1-\xi _{N}} } }$$
(24)

The productions of each Italian tradable good, \(T^{S}\left (h\right )\), is similarly characterized.

1.2.3 Price Setting in the Intermediate Sector

Consider now profit maximization in the Italian intermediate non-tradable sector. Each firm n sets the price p t (n) by maximizing the present discounted value of profits subject to the demand constraint and the quadratic adjustment costs:

$$\displaystyle{ \mathit{AC}_{N,t}^{p}\left (n\right ) \equiv \frac{\kappa _{N}^{p}} {2} \left ( \frac{P_{t}\left (n\right )} {P_{t-1}\left (n\right )} - 1\right )^{2}Q_{ N,t}\text{ }\kappa _{N}^{p} \geq 0 }$$

paid in unit of sectorial product Q N, t and where \(\kappa _{N}^{p}\) measures the degree of price stickiness. The resulting first-order condition, expressed in terms of domestic consumption, is:

$$\displaystyle{ p_{t}\left (n\right ) = \frac{\theta _{N}} {\theta _{N} - 1}\mathit{mc}_{t}\left (n\right ) -\frac{A_{t}\left (n\right )} {\theta _{N} - 1} }$$
(25)

where \(\mathit{mc}_{t}\left (n\right )\) is the real marginal cost and \(A\left (n\right )\) contains terms related to the presence of price adjustment costs:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} A_{t}\left (n\right )& \approx & \kappa _{N}^{p} \frac{P_{t}\left (n\right )} {P_{t-1}\left (n\right )}\left ( \frac{P_{t}\left (n\right )} {P_{t-1}\left (n\right )} - 1\right ) {}\\ & & -\beta \kappa _{N}^{p}\frac{P_{t+1}\left (n\right )} {P_{t}\left (n\right )} \left (\frac{P_{t+1}\left (n\right )} {P_{t}\left (n\right )} - 1\right )\frac{Q_{N,t+1}} {Q_{N,t}} {}\\ \end{array}$$

The above equations clarify the link between imperfect competition and nominal rigidities. As emphasized by Bayoumi et al. (2004), when the elasticity of substitution θ N is very large and hence the competition in the sector is high, prices closely follow marginal costs, even though adjustment costs are large. To the contrary, it may be optimal to maintain stable prices and accommodate changes in demand through supply adjustments when the average markup over marginal costs is relatively high. If prices were flexible, optimal pricing would collapse to the standard pricing rule of constant markup over marginal costs (expressed in units of domestic consumption):

$$\displaystyle{ p_{t}\left (n\right ) = \frac{\theta _{N}} {\theta _{N} - 1}\mathit{mc}_{N,t}\left (n\right ) }$$
(26)

Firms operating in the intermediate tradable sector solve a similar problem. We assume that there is market segmentation. Hence the firm producing the brand h chooses \(p_{t}\left (h\right )\) in the Italian market,a price \(\ p_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )\) in the REA and a price \(p_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )\) in the RW to maximize the expected flow of profits (in terms of domestic consumption units):

$$\displaystyle{ E_{t}\sum _{\tau =t}^{\infty }\Lambda _{ t,\tau }\left [\begin{array}{c} p_{\tau }\left (h\right )y_{\tau }\left (h\right ) + p_{\tau }^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )y_{\tau }^{{\ast}}\left (h\right ) + p_{\tau }^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )y_{\tau }^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right ) \\ -\mathit{mc}_{H,\tau }\left (h\right )\left (y_{\tau }\left (h\right ) + y_{\tau }^{{\ast}}\left (h\right ) + y_{\tau }^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )\right ) \end{array} \right ] }$$

subject to quadratic price adjustment costs similar to those considered for non-tradables and standard demand constraints. The term E t denotes the expectation operator conditional on the information set at time \(t\), \(\Lambda _{t,\tau }\) is the appropriate discount rate and \(\mathit{mc}_{H,t}\left (h\right )\) is the real marginal cost. The first order conditions with respect to \(p_{t}\left (h\right )\), \(p_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )\) and \(p_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )\) are:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} p_{t}\left (h\right ) = \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T} - 1}\mathit{mc}_{t}\left (h\right ) -\frac{A_{t}\left (h\right )} {\theta _{T} - 1} & &{}\end{array}$$
(27)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} p_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right ) = \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T} - 1}\mathit{mc}_{t}\left (h\right ) -\frac{A_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {\theta _{T} - 1} & &{}\end{array}$$
(28)
$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} p_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right ) = \frac{\theta _{T}} {\theta _{T} - 1}\mathit{mc}_{t}\left (h\right ) -\frac{A_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {\theta _{T} - 1} & &{}\end{array}$$
(29)

where θ T is the elasticity of substitution of intermediate tradable goods, while \(A\left (h\right )\) and \(A^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )\) involve terms related to the presence of price adjustment costs:

$$\displaystyle\begin{array}{rcl} A_{t}\left (h\right )& \approx & \kappa _{H}^{p} \frac{P_{t}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}\left (h\right )}\left ( \frac{P_{t}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}\left (h\right )} - 1\right ) {}\\ & & -\beta \kappa _{H}^{p}\frac{P_{t+1}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}\left (h\right )} \left (\frac{P_{t+1}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}\left (h\right )} - 1\right )\frac{Q_{H,t+1}} {Q_{H,t}} {}\\ A_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )& \approx & \theta _{ T} - 1 + \kappa _{H}^{p} \frac{P_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )}\left ( \frac{P_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} - 1\right ) {}\\ & & -\beta \kappa _{H}^{p}\frac{P_{t+1}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} \left (\frac{P_{t+1}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}^{{\ast}}\left (h\right )} - 1\right )\frac{Q_{H,t+1}^{{\ast}}} {Q_{H,t}^{{\ast}}} {}\\ A_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )& \approx & \theta _{ T} - 1 + \kappa _{H}^{p} \frac{P_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )}\left ( \frac{P_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t-1}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} - 1\right ) {}\\ & & -\beta \kappa _{H}^{p}\frac{P_{t+1}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} \left (\frac{P_{t+1}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} {P_{t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}\left (h\right )} - 1\right )\frac{Q_{H,t+1}^{{\ast}{\ast}}} {Q_{H,t}^{{\ast}{\ast}}} {}\\ \end{array}$$

where \(\kappa _{H}^{p}\),\(\kappa _{H}^{{p}^{{\ast}}}\),\(\kappa _{H}^{{p}^{{\ast}{\ast}}}\) > 0 respectively measure the degree of nominal rigidity in Italy, in the REA and in the RW. If nominal rigidities in the (domestic) export market are highly relevant (that is, if is relatively large), the degree of inertia of Italian goods prices in the foreign markets will be high. If prices were flexible (\(\kappa _{H}^{p} = \kappa _{H}^{p{\ast}} =\kappa _{ H}^{p{\ast}{\ast}} = 0\)) then optimal price setting would be consistent with the cross-border law of one price (prices of the same tradable goods would be equal when denominated in the same currency).

1.3 Labor Market

In the case of firms in the intermediate non-tradable sector, the labor input \(L_{N}\left (n\right )\) is a CES combination of differentiated labor inputs supplied by domestic agents and defined over a continuum of mass equal to the country size (j \(\in\) \(\left [0,s\right ]\)):

$$\displaystyle{ L_{N,t}\left (n\right ) \equiv \left (\frac{1} {s}\right )^{\frac{1} {\psi } }\left [\int _{0}^{s}L_{t}\left (n,j\right )^{\frac{\psi -1} {\psi } }\mathit{dj}\right ]^{ \frac{\psi }{\psi -1} } }$$
(30)

where \(L\left (n,j\right )\) is the demand of the labor input of type j by the producer of good n and ψ > 1 is the elasticity of substitution among labor inputs. Cost minimization implies:

$$\displaystyle{ L_{t}\left (n,j\right ) = \left (\frac{1} {s}\right )\left (\frac{W_{t}\left (j\right )} {W_{t}} \right )^{-\psi }L_{ N,t}\left (j\right ) }$$
(31)

where \(W\left (j\right )\) is the nominal wage of labor input j and the wage index W is:

$$\displaystyle{ W_{t} = \left [\left (\frac{1} {s}\right )\int _{0}^{s}W_{ t}\left (h\right )^{1-\psi }\mathit{dj}\right ]^{ \frac{1} {1-\psi }} }$$
(32)

Similar equations hold for firms producing intermediate tradable goods. Each household is the monopolistic supplier of a labor input j and sets the nominal wage facing a downward-sloping demand, obtained by aggregating demand across Italian firms. The wage adjustment is sluggish because of quadratic costs paid in terms of the total wage bill:

$$\displaystyle{ \mathit{AC}_{t}^{W} = \frac{\kappa _{W}} {2} \left ( \frac{W_{t}} {W_{t-1}} - 1\right )^{2}W_{ t}L_{t} }$$
(33)

where the parameter κ W  > 0 measures the degree of nominal wage rigidity and L is the total amount of labor in the Italian economy.

1.4 The Equilibrium

We find a symmetric equilibrium of the model. In each country there is a representative agent and four representative sectorial firms (in the intermediate tradable sector, intermediate non-tradable sector, consumption production sector and investment production sector). The equilibrium is a sequence of allocations and prices such that, given initial conditions and the sequence of exogenous shocks, each private agent and firm satisfy the correspondent first order conditions, the private and public sector budget constraints and market clearing conditions for goods, labor, capital and bond holdings.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this paper

Cite this paper

Locarno, A., Notarpietro, A., Pisani, M. (2014). Sovereign Risk, Monetary Policy and Fiscal Multipliers: A Structural Model-Based Assessment. In: Paganetto, L. (eds) Wealth, Income Inequalities, and Demography. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-05909-9_7

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics