Skip to main content

A Macroscopic Order of Consumer Demand Due to Heterogenous Consumer Behaviors on Japanese Household Demand Tested by the Random Matrix Theory

  • Conference paper
Econophysics of Agent-Based Models

Part of the book series: New Economic Windows ((NEW))

Abstract

So far the consumer theory was microscopically too restrictive to overlook many important scenes of the whole consumption activities. This view is deliberately dropping the inter-correlated factors between different income classes and household demands. The household demands must have a certain bias toward either common or different directions among different income classes. In some sense, the traditionally narrow interest may be dangerous because other decisive factors contributing to the consumption activities may be missed. This article argued to choose a particular scene where some natural or social correlative relations i.e., some dominant forces, may work in the consumption activities over the different income classes. By introducing the different income classes, we can just analyze a new facet of interactive correlations among the heterogeneous consumers. Here we can find any correlative relation, irrespective of price variations. Such a way of thinking may lead us observing another hidden force of the consumption activities.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Appendix 1.

  2. 2.

    In this example, middle class property is a state property, if the income range of the middle class is pertinently defined. The ingredients of various types in the middle class of income are then ignored. Such a simplification is called a metonymy from types to state properties, according to [3]. Exchangeable agents are virtually used, instead of types in a precise sense. Types are replaced with state variables. A state variable then becomes a surrogate variable for type ([2], p. 133).

  3. 3.

    See Appendix 2.

  4. 4.

    We have employed the database in terms of year-over year basis.

  5. 5.

    http://www.census.gov/srd/www/x12a/.

References

  1. Aruka Y (2001) Family expenditure data in Japan and the law of demand: macroscopic microeconomic view. In: Takayasu H (ed) Empirical science of financial fluctuations. Springer, Tokyo, pp 294–303. Reprinted in Aruka Y (2011) Complexities of production and interacting human behaviour. Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg, pp 129–139

    Google Scholar 

  2. Aruka Y, Akiyama E (2009) Non-self-averaging of a two-person game with only positive spillover: a new formulation of Avatamsaka’s dilemma. J Econ Interact Coord 4(2):131–165

    Article  Google Scholar 

  3. Hildenbrand W (1994) Market demand. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  4. Iyetomi H et al. (2011) What causes business cycles? Analysis of the Japanese industrial production data. J Jpn Int Econ 25:246272

    Article  Google Scholar 

  5. Iyetomi H et al. (2011) Fluctuation-dissipation theory of input-output interindustrial correlations. Phys Rev E 83:016103

    Article  ADS  Google Scholar 

  6. Kitagawa G, Gersch W (1984) A smoothness priors-state space approach to the modeling of time series with trend and seasonality. J Am Stat Assoc 79(386):378–389. http://ssnt.ism.ac.jp/inets2/title.html

    Google Scholar 

  7. Slutsky EE (1937) The summation of random causes as the source of cyclical processes. Econometrica 5:105–146

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Hiroshi Iyetomi .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1

We denote a demand at price p by f(p). We then have a next formula between two distinct price vector p 1 and p 2: ?

$$ \bigl(p^1 - p^2\bigr) \bigl(f\bigl(p^1 \bigr)-f\bigl(p^2\bigr)\bigr) \leq0 $$
(10.11)

i.e.,

$$ \mathrm{d}p\mathrm{d}f \leq0. $$
(10.12)

This is the demand law. The law does not state any analytical confirmation with respect of price when an income variation x derived by price changes is taken account into. The tentative formulation is called the Pareto-Slutsky equation:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial f_j}{\partial p_k}=\frac{\partial h_j}{\partial p_k}-\frac{\partial f_j}{\partial x} f_k. \end{aligned}$$
(10.13)

In other words,

  • demand change = substitution effects + income effects

Here j and k are indices of good. f j is a demand of good k. h j is a compensated demand of good j. x is an income level. Demand for good depend on prices of goods p k including itself (p j ) and also depend on income. Income x is to be measured in terms of goods. So income may be changeable depending on price variations Δp. A change of income naturally induces a change of demand. But the sign of a change of income is not decisive in general. This is a complicated factor for establishing the demand law. Consequently, economists never were successful to confirm the sign of income effect until a new assumption was invented by Hildenbrand [3]). It took about 90 years to solve this problem.

Compensated demand is a sophisticated idea. This demand h always has a negative sign respect with a price rise. Actually, h is supposed to be a special form only reactive to price variation but inactive to income level to guarantee the same level of satisfaction by supplementing a new injection of income if short, or reducing if long.

We introduce into the Pareto-Slutsky equation a very small footnote-sized perturbation of Δp and h:Δp and Δh. A variation of dpdf caused by Δp and Δh i.e., ΔpΔf may be approximately estimated as \(\Delta p \frac{\partial f_{j}}{\partial p_{k}} \Delta p\) In other words, it holds:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta p \frac{\partial f_j}{\partial p_k \partial p_k} = \Delta p \frac{\partial h_j}{\partial p_k \partial p_k} - \Delta p \frac {\partial f_j}{\partial x_k} \Delta p f. \end{aligned}$$
(10.14)

We cannot find any reason that the first item is always equal to the second item. If the second item should be negative, the total variation caused by Δp k could be positive, leading the contrary to the demand law. Thus, the Pareto-Slutsky equation, as it is, is not successful to guarantee a definite analytical relation in general. A so-called Giffen effect could not be removed.

Appendix 2

Most of the items of expenditure have strong seasonal dependence as easily expected. The excepted items are Housing, Medical and Transport. Removal of seasonal components out of the original data is thus a critical procedure to elucidate possible correlations embedded in expenditure of Japanese consumers.

Here we adopt two seasonal adjustment methods. One of them is the X-12-ARIMA,Footnote 5 developed and used by the U.S. Census Bureau. It is also a standard seasonal adjustment method for the Statistic Bureau in Japan. The X-12-ARIMA program, having a long history in the development, is full of experimental knowledge with a number of degrees of freedom left for users to optimize the procedure. However, we allowed the program to determine a best regARIMA model by itself.

To assess the reliability of such an automatic seasonal adjustment, we applied another program called DECOMP [6] to the same data. The DECOMP based on state-space-modeling is free from the moving average procedure that plays an important role in X-12-ARIMA. As indicated in its name, the DECOMP decomposes a given time series data into trend, seasonal and irregular components in a transparent way. In return, there is no much room for us to play with the program for optimization of the procedure. The parameter set for the program that we used is

  • Log Transformed: Yes

  • Seasonal frequency: 12

  • Trend order: 1

  • AR order: 0

  • Trading Day Effects: Yes

As will be shown later, the X-12-ARIMA and DECOMP bring about no fundamentally different results for the principal component analysis. The RMT (random matrix theory) tells us that there are two statistically meaningful principal components for both of the seasonally adjusted data. And the characteristic features of the principal components so obtained are essentially the same between the two alternative data.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2014 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this paper

Cite this paper

Aruka, Y., Kichikawa, Y., Iyetomi, H. (2014). A Macroscopic Order of Consumer Demand Due to Heterogenous Consumer Behaviors on Japanese Household Demand Tested by the Random Matrix Theory. In: Abergel, F., Aoyama, H., Chakrabarti, B., Chakraborti, A., Ghosh, A. (eds) Econophysics of Agent-Based Models. New Economic Windows. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-00023-7_10

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics