Skip to main content

One Flew Over the Cuckoo’s Clock

Selling Exclusivity Through Conspicuous Goods on Evolution

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Crime and Art

Part of the book series: Studies in Art, Heritage, Law and the Market ((SAHLM,volume 1))

Abstract

Despite the increase of specialised law enforcement and commercial art crime databases concerning the registration of luxury products, it remains an often-overlooked category in art crime research. This chapter analyses the market for luxury products, focusing specifically on watches, jewellery, and designer clothing, on defunct anonymous marketplace Evolution, which was active between January 2014 and March 2015. We argue that this marketplace works as a way to buy exclusivity through the purchase of both original and counterfeited luxury goods, here called ‘conspicuous goods’. The goods we focus on in our analysis endow cultural value, and their possession allows consumers to display a higher level of distinction. However, rather than looking at consumers who desire to differentiate themselves by purchasing these objects, we were more interested in how the market is structured to best sell these products. Therefore, we have implemented a series of statistical analyses on the market supply, focusing on the type of traded object, their brand, and the average prices in Bitcoin, finding that a brand effect on price is at work both in counterfeited and original conspicuous goods. This signals that the market is aware of the dynamics of conspicuous goods and its sellers behave accordingly.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    At the time of writing, May 2021.

  2. 2.

    Angelini and Castellani (2019) present a critical review on the link between these two values, with a focus on (potential) causal effects.

  3. 3.

    The dates of the data dumps were not equally distanced, in particular in the first two months, when the download dates were very sparse. In our final data, the distance between one dump and the other goes between two and nine days.

  4. 4.

    Between the start of Evolution as a marketplace until roughly the end of April 2014, the reputation system did not consist of a numerical value, but only of levels (Freshman, Junior, Senior, Expert, tentatively ordered by us since there is no way to check for this). From May 2014 onwards, the reputation system changed to a numerical value, starting from 0, as in most online marketplace in the legal market, that was associated with a reputation level based on these numbers (Level 1, Level 2, etc.).

  5. 5.

    Notice that each unique id is associated with a certain object that was up on the marketplace in a certain day.

  6. 6.

    The figures are computed considering the lowest BTC to EUR exchange rate, so they should be taken as the lower boundaries of the ranges of these prices over time, since the exchange rate is highly volatile in the considered period.

  7. 7.

    Notice that the number of dropped observations in this case would have been higher if we did not drop the N/A reputation number in the previous step, since all the dates before May 2014 presented very few observations with respect to the rest of the period. This might be due to the fact that the marketplace did not start ‘at full power’ from the beginning, but we have no means to test this hypothesis.

  8. 8.

    Combining the categories necklace (6.61 percent), bracelet (5.10 percent), and earrings (2.45 percent). Other less represented sub-categories which can be considered as jewels are ring (1.40 percent), cufflinks (0.34 percent), ring and necklace (0.18 percent), keyring (0.07 percent), and money clips (0.01 percent). Some sellers also sold branded boxes of necklaces and bracelets, and these accounted for 0.23 percent of total observations, and branded boxes of watches, accounting for 1.53 percent of all observations.

  9. 9.

    We cannot know how many of these objects were sold, since we only observed the ads of the sellers and information of consumers is not available. What we can observe is the reputation number as a noisy measure of completed transactions. Inferring remains complex because we cannot assert how many points of the reputation number comes from our examined categories, and how many are from other categories. However, this information is not reproducible from the original dataset.

  10. 10.

    The median is computed over a moving window of 10 periods, the signal level is estimated at the end of each time window. The computation was implemented using the R package by Fried et al. (2019).

  11. 11.

    We reported these values in logarithmic form since the high variability of these values (see Table 1) would impede a graphical comparison otherwise.

  12. 12.

    In our analysis, we pool the data at cross-sectional level, meaning that we do not consider time dynamics. This is because our data is irregularly spaced with respect to time and an approach to consider time dynamics with this type of data would be too complex.

References

  • Afilipoaie, S., & Shortis, P. (2015). Operation Onymous: International law enforcement agencies target the dark net in November 2014. Swansea University, UK. Retrieved May 30, 2021, from https://www.swansea.ac.uk/media/Operation-Onymous.pdf

  • Albrecht, M. C. (1968). Art as an institution. American Sociological Review, 33(3), 383–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aldridge, J., & Décary-Hétu, D. (2016). Hidden wholesale: The drug diffusing capacity of online drug cryptomarkets. International Journal of Drug Policy, 35, 7–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelini, F., & Castellani, M. (2019). Cultural and economic value: A critical review. Journal of Cultural Economics, 43(2), 173–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Angelini, F., Castellani, M., & Pattitoni, P. (2019). Artist names as human brands: Brand strategies in the Italian gallery art market. Retrieved May 30, 2021, from https://ssrn.com/abstract=3495474

  • Ataman, E., Aatre, V. K., & Wong, K. M. (1981). Some statistical properties of median filters. IEEE Transactions on Acoustics, Speech and Signal Processing, 29(5), 1073–1075.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell, L. S., & Bernheim, D. (1996). Veblen effects in a theory of conspicuous consumption. The American Economic Review, 86(3), 349–373.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1983). The field of cultural production, or: The economic world reversed. Poetics, 12(4–5), 311–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1984). Distinction: A social critique of the judgment of taste. Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brodie, N. (2003). Stolen history: Looting and illicit trade. Museum International, 55(3–4), 10–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Červený, J., & Van Ours, J. C. (2019). Cannabis prices on the dark web. European Economic Review, 120, 1–11.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Compton, R. (2015). Darknet market basket analysis. Retrieved September 15, 2020, from http://ryancompton.net/2015/03/24/darknet-market-basket-analysis.html

  • Dodds, W. B., Monroe, K. B., & Grewal, D. (1991). Effects of price, brand, and store information on buyers’ product evaluations. Journal of Marketing Research, 28(3), 307–319.

    Google Scholar 

  • Erdem, T., & Swait, J. (2004). Brand credibility, brand consideration, and choice. Journal of Consumer Research, 31(1), 191–198.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Farberman, H. A. (1975). A criminogenic market structure: The automobile industry. Sociological Quarterly, 16(4), 438–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fried, R., Schettlinger, K., & Borowski, M. (2019). robfilter: Robust time series filters. R package version 4.1.2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hufnagel, S., & King, C. (2020). Anti-money laundering regulation and the art market. Legal Studies, 40(1), 131–150.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kerr, J. (2015). The securitization and policing of art theft. The case of London. Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mackenzie, S., Brodie, N., Yates, D., & Tsirogiannis, C. (2019). Trafficking culture: New directions in researching the global market in illicit antiquities. Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterlinck, K., & Radermecker, A. S. (2019). “The Master of …”: Creating names for art history and the art market. Journal of Cultural Economics, 43, 57–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterman, N. (2019). Regional overviews of the policing of art crime in the European Union. In S. Hufnagel & D. Chappell (Eds.), The Palgrave handbook on art crime (pp. 213–235). Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Oosterman, N., & Yates, D. (2020). Policing heritage crime in Latin America. Revista de Direito Internacional, 17(3), 275–290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Passas, N. (1999). Globalization, criminogenic asymmetries and economic crime. EUR JL Reform, 1, 399–424.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roodt, C., & Carey-Miller, D. (2013). Stolen cultural property: Implications of vitium reale in private law and private international law. Transnational Dispute Management, 10(5), 1–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schroeder, J. E. (2005). The artist and the brand. European Journal of Marketing, 39(11–12), 1291–1305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soska, K., & Christin, N. (2015). Measuring the longitudinal evolution of the online anonymous marketplace ecosystem. Carnegie Mellon University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigg, A. B. (2001). Veblen, Bourdieu, and conspicuous consumption. Journal of Economic Issues, 35(1), 99–115.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tukey, J. W. (1971). Exploratory data analysis. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1899). The theory of the leisure class: An economic study of institutions. Unwin Book.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wooldridge, J. (2006). Introductory econometrics: A modern approach. Thomson South-Western.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yates, D. (2015). Illicit cultural property from Latin America: Looting, trafficking, and sale. In F. Desmarais (Ed.), Countering illicit trafficking in cultural goods. The global challenge of protecting the world’s heritage. ICOM.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Michelangelo Puliga for his assistance with the database.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Naomi Oosterman .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2021 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Oosterman, N., Angelini, F. (2021). One Flew Over the Cuckoo’s Clock. In: Oosterman, N., Yates, D. (eds) Crime and Art. Studies in Art, Heritage, Law and the Market, vol 1. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-84856-9_16

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-84856-9_16

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-84855-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-84856-9

  • eBook Packages: Law and CriminologyLaw and Criminology (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics