Skip to main content

Goethe’s Price Games, Auctions, and Other Surprises

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Scissors and Rock

Abstract

This chapter is dedicated to Goethe’s price game which can be interpreted as a second-price sealed-bidauction. Nobel Laureate William Vickrey has shown for this type of auction that bidding one’s willingness-to-pay price is an optimal strategy. We do not know whether Goethe had a similar result in mind. In fact, his sealed-bid price functioned like a take-it-or-leave-it option. Given the historical circumstances, it implied price-fixing, thereby avoiding explicit bargaining. A discussion of the Revenue Equivalence Theorem adds some theory to Goethe’s auction setting. The theorem says that, in principle, first-price sealed-bidauctions, Dutchauctions, second-price sealed-bidauctions, and Englishauctions pick the same winners and have identical prices. There are other types of auctions as well, and some have rather peculiar effects. All-payauctions are recommended for exploiting bidders—as in collecting money for a charity. If you want to win, do not participate. English auctions can have peculiar results, too. You might be interested in paying a high auction price for Gauguin’s “Mata Mua” if you already have a number of Gauguin paintings in your collection. On May 9, 1989, the “Mata Mua” was auctioned by Sotheby at 24.2 million dollars, then being the highest price ever bid for a Gauguin painting. You might also be willing and able to pay a high auction price if you represent a consortium of the Federal Republic of Germany, the States of Lower Saxony and Bavaria, the Prussian Cultural Heritage Foundation, and private donators. On December 6, 1983, the gospel book of Henry the Lion (1129–1195) was auctioned and sold for a price of £8,140,000, then equaling 32.5 million German marks. There was a single bidder present in the auction hall, i.e., the representative of the consortium, and a second person calling bids from outside—possibly the seller.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 34.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 44.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In the first act of Faust, The Tragedy´s Second Part, Goethe refers to the monetary ideas of the Scottish banker John Law of Lauriston (1671–1729) and their implementation in France. The enormous speculative demand for shares and bank bills was met by John Law´s finance company “Compagnie des Indes,” leading to hyperinflation that threw France into a serious economic and political crisis by the end of 1720. Goethe’s emperor, issuing bills on his country´s mineral resources, was not much better off with the “paper monster of the guilders.”

  2. 2.

    Also for this book the publisher acted as proposer when it came to signing a contract.

  3. 3.

    There are alternative years of birth.

  4. 4.

    It is said that Henry the Lion founded Munich in 1158 by burning a bridge that belonged to the Prince Bishop of the nearby Freising. Most of the text of the gospel book was written in Munich. Hence, there is a straightforward relationship between this book and Henry the Lion.

  5. 5.

    The theorem has been introduced in Vickrey (1996 [1961]) and further elaboratedin Myerson (1981) and Riley and Samuelson (1981). See also Milgrom (1989) for “a primer” in “auctions and bidding.”

  6. 6.

    The Tullock auction is a variant of the all-payauction: everybody submits a sealed bid and the winner and the losers pay the amount of their bids.

References

  • Berz, G. (2015). Game theory bargaining and auction theory. New York, Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Herchenröder, C. (1990). Die Neuen Kunstmärkte. Analyse, Bilanz, Ausblick. Düsseldorf: Verlag Wirtschaft und Finanzen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce, D. R., & Raiffa, H. (1957). Games and decisions. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Milgrom, P. (1989). Auctions and bidding: A primer. Journal of Economic Perspectives,33, 3–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moldovanu, B., & Tietzel, M. (1998). Goethe’s second-price auction. Journal of Political Economy,106, 854–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1981). Optimal auction design. Mathematics of Operation Research,6(1), 58–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Riley, J. G., & Samuelson, W. F. (1981). Optimal auctions. American Economic Review,71, 381–392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tietzel, M. (1995). Literaturökonomik. Tübingen: Mohr-Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • Vickrey, W. (1996 [1961]). Counterspeculation, auctions and competitive sealed tenders. In R. Arnott, K, Arrow, A, Atkinson, & J. Drèze (Eds.), Public economics. Selected papers by William Vickrey (pp. 55–84), Cambridge: Cambridge University Press (first publication in Journal of Finance 16(1961), 8–37).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Manfred J. Holler .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Holler, M.J., Klose-Ullmann, B. (2020). Goethe’s Price Games, Auctions, and Other Surprises. In: Scissors and Rock. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-44823-3_13

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics