Skip to main content

Towards a Transdisciplinary Ecological Economics: A Cognitive Approach

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Ecological Economic and Socio Ecological Strategies for Forest Conservation

Abstract

Postmodern cognitive sciences have identified many historical examples of social downfalls, or even the collapse of entire civilizations, and there has been one common cause: a crisis of perception. A crisis of perception has its origin in a cognitive disconnection of one specific culture with the socio-environmental context from which it arose. Partially this disconnection is possible due to the characteristics of the nervous system, as a system with organizational closure, and consequently the nature of language, as an autonomous cognitive process, developed and performed by human beings. It is the language that gives “sense” to our process of living, but it confuses us too, as ideas are never concrete realities. The cultural context defines “meanings”, bringing this way forth to worldviews that define social coexistence, specific understandings that define disciplines and specific values that define what is valuable. However, language as a behavioral process taking place in human beings, is not about a “universal truth” but a “human truth” that emerges in the process of human living, and consequently it is determined by the human experience. In short, under this prospect, we humans cannot refer to a non-human reality, as we are only capable to perceive and think the reality that our cognitive system is structurally able to perform. Therefore, a so-called “objective” knowing is simply not possible, which in turn leaves a set of strong implications regarding any discipline, including economics. Disciplines are networks of conversations that coordinate themselves setting linguistic (and symbolic) boundaries to the “outside” in the course of internal interactions among the members of each discipline. In this manner, every discipline develops a way to understand (a “disciplinary story”) that sets the framework of rationality within, together with an internal “specialized” technical language. Both the disciplinary understanding and language are not objective realities, but ever-changing cultural phenomena determined by the nature of social phenomena as linguistic processes, even in the so-called “hard” or “natural” sciences. As any disciplinary knowledge, economic thinking has been developed under a certain set of foundational concepts that are implicitly believed. Beliefs arise in the interplay of the different human domains of existence, such as experiences (evidences), cultural background, preferences and the internal drift that the collectivity of a discipline have performed. Disciplinary (scientific) knowledge is never only about facts or truths but involves all the aspects of human living. Neoclassical economics have received critics from the scientific world since decades. Therefore, it is extremely interesting to study the existing incoherencies between neoclassical economics and other scientific disciplines, like natural sciences, in order to discover what set of beliefs are guiding current mainstream economics, and why such incoherencies have been kept for so long.

an extractive economy is a terminal economy.

Thomas Berry

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Malthus stated one of the first scientific critics to growth as a way of progress, with a simple mathematical demonstration of the demographic limits. After 220 years of its publication, his critic remains valid.

  2. 2.

    Although there are many previous scientific works giving the same framework, “The Limits to Growth” (Meadows et al. 1972) of the Club of Rome addressed many problems that we are facing today.

  3. 3.

    Etymology (https://www.etymonline.com/): from Medieval Latin objectum “thing put before” (literally “thrown against”). Late 14c., “tangible thing, something perceived or presented to the senses”.

  4. 4.

    With parenthesis is meant: Objectivity under question.

  5. 5.

    Reality is a word, and therefore it is a linguistic construct and not an objective reality.

  6. 6.

    In the logic and validity codes created by the language “mathematics” 1 + 1 = 2 may be defined as a “reality”.

  7. 7.

    https://www.etymonline.com/.

  8. 8.

    It is therefore very difficult to find a universal definition of science, and there is no universal consensus about a definition of science among the scientific world.

  9. 9.

    In this context it is noteworthy that the former German health minister Ulla Schmidt in an official statement wrote that it was an “international consensus” that HIV caused AIDS (Schmidt 2004).

  10. 10.

    It has not been proven yet that the Universe behaves always in the same manner, an assumption that is implicit in the concept of natural law.

  11. 11.

    A model of an economy in which neighbourly love instead of competition is the driving force of the economy has been described (Fuders 2017; Fuders and Nowak 2019).

  12. 12.

    This assumption is especially relevant, as it implies that economists understand what is at stake with such environmental impacts.

  13. 13.

    In brief, it states that energy (and matter) cannot be created nor destroyed, but only transformed. Related to the production of goods and services this means that they cannot be produced out of nothing. If real GDP increases, so has to increase the use of energy and material input, unless a purely qualitative transformation takes place. Obviously, that is not the case of a quantitatively driven science, like neo-classical economics.

References

  • Aristotle (1995) Aristotle, 1995 Politik, 1. Buch. In: Aristoteles Phillosophische Schriften in sechs Bänden. Felix Meiner Verlag, Hamburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Capra F (1997) The web of life; a new synthesis of mind and matter. Harper Collins Publishers, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fantuzzi G (2014) The sound of health. Front Immunol 5:351

    Google Scholar 

  • Freudenthal G, McLaughlin P (2009) The social and economic roots of the scientific revolution: texts by Boris Hessen and Henryk Grossmann. Springer Netherlands

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuders F (2017) Neues Geld für eine neue Ökonomie – Die Reform des Geldwesens als Voraussetzung für eine Marktwirtschaft, die den Menschen dient. In: Finanzwirtschaft in ethischer Verantwortung – Erfolgskonzepte für Social Banking und Social Finance. Springer-Gabler, Wiesbaden, pp 121–18

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuders F, Nowak V (2019). https://link.springer.com/chapter/10.1007/978-3-030-25513-8_17

  • IPCC (2011) Special report renewable energy sources (SRREN) – summary for policymakers. Abu Dabi

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhn TS (1970) The structure of scientific revolutions, vol II, 2nd edn. The University of Chicago, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Maturana H (1988) Ontology of observing, the biological foundations of self-consciousness and the physical domain of existence. Conference workbook: texts in cybernetics, American Society for cybernetics conference, 18–23 October, Felton

    Google Scholar 

  • Maturana H (1989) Language and reality: the constitution of what is human. Arch Biol Med Exp 22:77–81

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Maturana H (1997) Metadesign. Instituto de Terapia Cognitiva INTECO. http://www.inteco.cl/articulos/006/texto_ing.htm. Maturana, Humberto

  • Maturana H, Mpodozis J (2000) The origin of species by means of natural drift. Rev Chil Hist Nat 73:261–310

    Google Scholar 

  • Maturana HR, Varela FJ (1980) Autopoiesis and cognition. The realization of the living. Reidel, Dordrecht, p 13

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Max-Neef M (2005) Foundations of transdisciplinarity. Ecol Econ 53:5–16

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Max-Neef M (2010) The world on collision course and the need for a new economy. Ambio 39:200–210

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meadows DH, Meadows DL, Randers J et al (1972) The limits to growth; a report for the Club of Rome’s project on the predicament of mankind (PDF). Universe Books, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Novak JD, Cañas AJ (2008) The theory underlying concept maps and how to construct and use them, technical report IHMC Cmap Tools 2006–01 Rev 01–2008, Florida Institute for Human and Machine Cognition, available at: http://cmap.ihmc.us/Publications/ResearchPapers/TheoryUnderlyingConceptMaps.pdf

  • Popper KR (1959) The logic of scientific discovery. Hutchinson & Co. London, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Röling N (2000) Gateway to the global garden: Beta/gamma science for dealing with ecological rationality.. Eight Annual Hopper Lecture. University of Guelph, Guelph

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt U (2004) Official answer from January 5, 2004 to an inquiry of Rudolf Kraus (member of parliament), Bundestag, BMGS Leitungsabteilung Registry No 3538. Bundestag, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumacher EF (2010) Small is beautiful; economics as if people mattered. Harper Perennial, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith P, Max-Neef M (2011) Economics unmasked: from power and greed to compassion and the common good paperback. Green Books, UK

    Google Scholar 

  • Varela F, Thompson E, Rosch E (1991) The embodied mind: cognitive science and human experience. MIT Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • von Bertalanfy L (1955) An essay on the relativity of categories. Philos Sci 22(4):243

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Alfredo Erlwein .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Erlwein, A., Oliva, I., Fuders, F., Donoso, P.J. (2020). Towards a Transdisciplinary Ecological Economics: A Cognitive Approach. In: Fuders, F., Donoso, P. (eds) Ecological Economic and Socio Ecological Strategies for Forest Conservation. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-35379-7_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics