Skip to main content

Economic Orthodoxy and Emerging Pluralism

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economics of a Crowded Planet
  • 186 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter summarizes major steps in the emergence of twentieth-century economic orthodoxy and traces the recent emergence of a new methodological pluralism. To foresee where economics may be going, it is necessary to understand where it came from: particularly the social and technical contexts within which major changes occurred. The economics that emerged during the nineteenth and twentieth centuries was wholly unprepared for a world in which the economy engages in measurable coevolution with nature; yet recent developments indicate the field is adapting to this new world. The chapter concludes with a discussion of economics’ political influence and its implications for the economy of the future.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Galbraith (1973, p. 11).

  2. 2.

    Dowd (2004, pp. 34–35).

  3. 3.

    Dowd (2004, p. 81).

  4. 4.

    McCloskey (1998).

  5. 5.

    Marglin (2008, p. 95).

  6. 6.

    Beinhocker (2006, pp. 27–29).

  7. 7.

    Beinhocker (2006, pp. 30–32).

  8. 8.

    Beinhocker (2006, p. 43).

  9. 9.

    Beinhocker (2006, pp. 34–35).

  10. 10.

    Galbraith (1973) and Dowd (2004).

  11. 11.

    Marshall (1920, p. 84).

  12. 12.

    Primarily a mathematician applying his techniques to economics, Cournot established an analytical basis for the rule of supply and demand. He also was a major influence on Léon Walras.

  13. 13.

    Marshall (1890). Preface to the First Edition of Principles of Economics. See Marshall (1920).

  14. 14.

    Marshall (1920, p. 139).

  15. 15.

    Marshall (1920, p. 163).

  16. 16.

    Marshall (1920, p. 139).

  17. 17.

    See, for instance, in the Preface to the Eighth Edition of Principles of Economics (Marshall 1920) and on p. 238.

  18. 18.

    Marshall (1920, p. 61).

  19. 19.

    Veblen (1919) quoted in Dowd (2004).

  20. 20.

    Veblen (1898, p. 373).

  21. 21.

    Veblen (1898, pp. 383–384).

  22. 22.

    Veblen (1898, p. 386).

  23. 23.

    Veblen (1898, p. 387).

  24. 24.

    Veblen (1898, pp. 389–390).

  25. 25.

    Veblen (1898, pp. 390–391).

  26. 26.

    Veblen (1898, pp. 394–395).

  27. 27.

    Veblen (1898, p. 396).

  28. 28.

    Veblen (1898, p. 397).

  29. 29.

    Dowd (2004, pp. 32, 240).

  30. 30.

    Marx (1867).

  31. 31.

    Galbraith (1973, p. 21).

  32. 32.

    Pigou (1920, 1932, p. 183).

  33. 33.

    Pigou (1920, 1932, pp. 183–185).

  34. 34.

    Pigou (1920, 1932, p. 224).

  35. 35.

    Pigou (1920, 1932, p. 184).

  36. 36.

    Galbraith (1973, p. 183).

  37. 37.

    Galbraith (1973, pp. 21–22).

  38. 38.

    E.g., Baumol (1982).

  39. 39.

    Dowd (2004).

  40. 40.

    Rousseas (1998, p. 15).

  41. 41.

    Marglin (2008, p. 113).

  42. 42.

    Schumpeter (1950, pp. 79, 83).

  43. 43.

    Schumpeter (1950, pp. 82–83).

  44. 44.

    E.g., Samuelson (1981) quoted in the Introduction to the 2008 reprinting of Schumpeter (1950) by Harper Perennial.

  45. 45.

    McCloskey (1998, p. 140).

  46. 46.

    Galbraith (1973, p. 27).

  47. 47.

    Coase (1937, p. 387).

  48. 48.

    They were shown, for example, to drive Time Warner’s decision to spin off its cable division in 2008 (Colander 2010, p. 278).

  49. 49.

    McCloskey (1998, p. 94).

  50. 50.

    Coase (1960, p. 44).

  51. 51.

    Coase (1960, p. 15).

  52. 52.

    Coase (1960, p. 17).

  53. 53.

    Galbraith (1973, p. 211).

  54. 54.

    Eichengreen (2008, p. 229).

  55. 55.

    Dowd (2004, pp. 185–186).

  56. 56.

    Mazower (2012, p. 346).

  57. 57.

    Stiglitz (2003, p. 284).

  58. 58.

    Stiglitz (2003, p. 275).

  59. 59.

    Perhaps markets have a socially optimal range of ‘viscosity’?

  60. 60.

    Stiglitz (2003, pp. 282, 292).

  61. 61.

    Beinhocker (2006, p. 166).

  62. 62.

    von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944).

  63. 63.

    Kahneman (2002) and Colander (2010, p. 511).

  64. 64.

    Hill and Myatt (2010, pp. 146–149).

  65. 65.

    Biologists have come to similar conclusions about animal behavior.

  66. 66.

    E.g., Beinhocker (2006, ch. 3).

  67. 67.

    Hsieh (1991, p. 1839). See also Berry et al. (1987) for a contemporaneous synthesis and James Gleick’s (1988) popular account.

  68. 68.

    See, for example, Falcon Crack and Ledoit (1996) on the ‘robust structure’ of financial time series that are nevertheless unpredictable.

  69. 69.

    Sornette (2003).

  70. 70.

    Akerlof and Shiller (2009) cited in Hill and Myatt (2010, pp. 147–149).

  71. 71.

    Lucas (1976).

  72. 72.

    For a recent example, see Sbordone et al. (2010).

  73. 73.

    Orrell and Chlupatý (2016, p. 153).

  74. 74.

    Woodford (2003) provides a survey.

  75. 75.

    Arthur (1994, p. 411).

  76. 76.

    Holland and Miller (1991)

  77. 77.

    Nelson and Winter (1982, p. 31).

  78. 78.

    Beinhocker (2006, pp. 136–138); see also Arthur (1995) and Arthur et al. (1997).

  79. 79.

    Buchanan (2009).

  80. 80.

    Recent reviews include Sandholm and Lesser (2001), Tesfatsion and Judd (2006), LeBaron and Tesfatsion (2008), Colander et al. (2008) and Westerhoff and Franke (2012).

  81. 81.

    Bowles et al. (2017, p. 218), their emphasis.

  82. 82.

    Bowles et al. (2017, pp. 215–216).

  83. 83.

    Friedman (1953, p. 22).

  84. 84.

    Nelson and Winter (1982, p. 47).

  85. 85.

    Nelson and Winter (1982, pp. 405–406).

  86. 86.

    Beinhocker (2006).

  87. 87.

    Colander (2010, pp. 132–133).

  88. 88.

    Norgaard, pers. comm.

  89. 89.

    Coase (1960, p. 43).

References

  • Akerlof, G.A., and R.J. Shiller. 2009. Animal Spirits: How Human Psychology Drives the Economy and Why It Matters for Global Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W.B. 1994. Inductive Reasoning and Bounded Rationality. The American Economic Review 84 (2): 406–411.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W.B. 1995. Complexity in Economic and Financial Markets. Complexity 1: 20–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arthur, W.B., et al. 1997. Asset Pricing Under Endogenous Expectations in an Artificial Stock Market. In The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II, ed. W.B. Arthur, S.N. Durlauf, and D.A. Lane, 15–44. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W.J. 1982. Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure. The American Economic Review 72 (1): 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beinhocker, E.D. 2006. The Origin of Wealth: Evolution, Complexity, and the Radical Remaking of Economics. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Berry, M.V., et al. (eds.). 1987. Dynamical Chaos. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, S., A. Kirman, and R. Sethi. 2017. Retrospectives: Friedrich Hayek and the Market Algorithm. Journal of Economic Perspectives 31 (3): 215–230.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, M. 2009. Meltdown Modelling: Could Agent-Based Computer Models Prevent Another Financial Crisis? Nature 460: 680–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica 4 (16): 386–405.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R.H. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics 3: 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D.C., et al. 2008. Beyond DSGE Models: Toward an Empirically Based Macroeconomics. American Economic Review 98 (2): 236–240.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Colander, D.C. 2010. Economics, 8th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dowd, D. 2004. Capitalism and Its Economics: A Critical History, 2nd ed. London: Pluto Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eichengreen, B. 2008. Globalizing Capital. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Falcon Crack, T., and O. Ledoit. 1996. Robust Structure Without Predictability: The “Compass Rose” Pattern of the Stock Market. The Journal of Finance 51 (2): 751–762.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. 1953. The Methodology of Positive Economics. In Essays in Positive Economics, ed. M. Friedman, 3–43. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galbraith, J.K. 1973. Economics and the Public Purpose. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gleick, J. 1988. Chaos: Making a New Science. London: William Heinemann.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hill, R., and T. Myatt. 2010. The Economics Anti-Textbook: A Critical Thinker’s Guide to Microeconomics. London: Zed Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holland, J.H., and J.H. Miller. 1991. Artificial Adaptive Agents in Economic Theory. American Economic Review 81 (2): 365–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hsieh, D.A. 1991. Chaos and Nonlinear Dynamics: Application to Financial Markets. The Journal of Finance 46 (5): 1839–1877.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. 2002. Maps of Bounded Rationality: A Perspective on Intuitive Judgement and Choice. Nobel Prize Lecture, December.

    Google Scholar 

  • LeBaron, B., and L. Tesfatsion. 2008. Modeling Macroeconomies as Open-Ended Dynamic Systems of interacting Agents. American Economic Review 98 (2): 246–250.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R.E., Jr. 1976. Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 1: 19–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marglin, S. 2008. The Dismal Science: How Thinking Like an Economist Undermines Community. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. 1920. Principles of Economics, 8th ed. Amherst, NY: Promethius Books (reprint 1997).

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, C. 1867. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, vol. 1. Hamburg: Verlag von Otto Meissner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazower, M. 2012. Governing the World: The History of an Idea. New York: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D.N. 1998. The Rhetoric of Economics, 2nd ed. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R.R., and S.G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Orrell, D., and R. Chlupatý. 2016. The Evolution of Money. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A.C. 1920. The Economics of Welfare, 4th ed. 1932. Palgrave Macmillan: London, UK (reprint 2013).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rousseas, S. 1998. Post Keynesian Monetary Economics, 3rd ed. London: Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. 1981. Schumpeter’s Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. In Schumpeter’s Vision: Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy After 40 Years, ed. Arnold Heertje. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sandholm, T.W., and V.R. Lesser. 2001. Leveled Commitment Contracts and Strategic Breach. Games and Economic Behavior 35 (1–2): 212–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sbordone, A., et al. 2010. Policy Analysis Using DSGE Models: An Introduction. Federal Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 16 (2): 23–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter, J.E. 1950. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 3rd ed. New York: Harper & Row (reprint 2008).

    Google Scholar 

  • Sornette, D. 2003. Why Stock Markets Crash: Critical Events in Complex Financial Systems. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stiglitz, J.E. 2003. The Roaring Nineties. New York and London: W.W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion, L., and K.L. Judd (eds.). 2006. Handbook of Computational Economics, 2: Agent-Based Computational Economics. Handbooks in Economics, No. 13, ed. K.J. Arrow and M.D. Intriligator. North-Holland, Amsterdam, The Netherlands: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. 1898. Why Is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science? Quarterly Journal of Economics 12: 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. 1919. The Vested Interests and the Common Man. New York: B.W. Huebsch.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Neumann, J., and O. Morgenstern. 1944. The Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westerhoff, F., and R. Franke. 2012. Agent-Based Models for Economic Policy Design. BERG Working Paper No. 88, University of Bamberg, Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodford, M. 2003. Interest and Prices: Foundations of a Theory of Monetary Policy. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Murison Smith, F. (2019). Economic Orthodoxy and Emerging Pluralism. In: Economics of a Crowded Planet. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-31798-0_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-31798-0_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-31797-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-31798-0

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics