Skip to main content

Behavioural Economics and Individual Ageing

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Economics and Ageing
  • 429 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter acts as a primer on behavioural economics and ageing: it introduces the basic concepts studied in behavioural economics, including the anomalies and departures from the rational choice framework, along with a discussion of the main empirical findings.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Modern behavioural economics is considered to have started with the papers by Tversky and Kahneman (1974) and Kahneman and Tversky (1979). For a historical view of behavioural economics, see Heukelom (2014). Belsky and Gilovich (2000) is a non-technical introduction.

  2. 2.

    Although see Rachlin (1995) for a criticism to this approach.

  3. 3.

    For book-length treatments of behavioural economics, see Altman (2012), Wilkinson and Klaes (2012), and Cartwright (2014).

  4. 4.

    I am not going to delve into the weak and strong axioms of revealed preferences and other theoretical points, which I leave to any interested readers to consult in any intermediate or advanced textbook in microeconomics, such as Mas-Colell et al. (1995), Jehle and Reny (2011), and Varian (2014). For thorough, though advanced, book-length discussions, see Wakker (2010) and Chambers and Echenique (2016).

  5. 5.

    See Plott and Zeiler (2005) for a criticism.

  6. 6.

    Decision quality is ‘the frequency with which the decision-maker chooses the option with the higher expected value …associated with each possible outcome of an option’ (Pachur et al. 2017, p. 504).

  7. 7.

    Or ‘valenced’, which in psychology refers to the ‘intrinsic attractiveness or aversiveness’ of events, objects, and situations (Frijda 1986, p. 207).

  8. 8.

    In the poem ‘Sacred Emily’ (Stein 2012).

  9. 9.

    The experiment applied a computer-based psychological task known as the Iowa gambling task; rewards and punishment were administered in the shape of game money. See Bechara et al. (1994, 2005) and Damasio (1994) to learn more about this task.

  10. 10.

    On lack of willpower and retirement saving, see Ellen et al. (2012), Millar and Devonish (2009), Raaij (2016), Visco (2009), and the sub-section on the Save More Tomorrow programme below.

  11. 11.

    For lack of willpower as a barrier to physical activity in later life, see Dye and Wilcox (2006), Kim (2015), and Schreier et al. (2016).

  12. 12.

    In the words of the Committee who awarded Herbert Alexander Simon the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel in 1978:

    Simon’s scientific output goes far beyond the disciplines in which he has held professorships - political science, administration, psychology and information sciences. He has made contributions in, among other fields, science theory, applied mathematical statistics, operations analysis, economics, and business administration. In all areas in which he has conducted research, Simon has had something of importance to say…

    (The Prize in Economics 1978 2014)

References

  • Abeler, Johannes and Felix Marklein (2008). Fungibility, labels, and consumption. IZA Discussion Paper 3500. Bonn: Germany: Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA).

    Google Scholar 

  • Agarwal, Sumit et al. (2009). “The Age of Reason: Financial Decisions over the Life Cycle and Implications for Regulation”. In: Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, pages 51–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie, George and Varda Haendel (1983). “The motives of the will”. In: Etiologic aspects of alcohol and drug abuse. Edited by Keith A Gottheil Edward and Druley, Thomas Skoloda, and Howard Waxman. Springfield, IL: United States of America: Charles C Thomas, pages 119–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Altman, Morris (2012). Behavioral Economics For Dummies. Mississauga, ON: Canada: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Appleton, Katherine M et al. (2010). “Barriers to increasing fruit and vegetable intakes in the older population of Northern Ireland: low levels of liking and low awareness of current recommendations”. In: Public health nutrition 13.4, pages 514–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, Dan (2009). Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces that Shape Our Decisions. London: United Kingdom: HarperCollins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arkes, Hal R and Catherine Blumer (1985). “The psychology of sunk cost”. In: Organizational behavior and human decision processes 35.1, pages 124–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barberis, Nicholas, Ming Huang, and Tano Santos (2001). “Prospect theory and asset prices”. In: The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116.1, pages 1–53.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bargh, John A, Mark Chen, and Lara Burrows (1996). “Automaticity of social behavior: Direct effects of trait construct and stereotype activation on action”. In: Journal of personality and social psychology 71.2, pages 230–244.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, AS et al. (2013). “Myopia for the future or hypersensitivity to reward? Age-related changes in decision making on the Iowa Gambling Task”. In: Emotion 13.1, pages 19–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechara, Antoine, Sara Dolan, and Andrea Hindes (2002). “Decision-making and addiction (part II): myopia for the future or hypersensitivity to reward?” In: Neuropsychologia 40.10, pages 1690–1705.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechara, Antoine et al. (1994). “Insensitivity to future consequences following damage to human prefrontal cortex”. In: Cognition 50.1-3, pages 7–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bechara, Antoine et al. (2005). “The Iowa Gambling Task and the somatic marker hypothesis: some questions and answers”. In: Trends in cognitive sciences 9.4, pages 159–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Belsky, Gary and Thomas Gilovich (2000). Why Smart People Make Big Money Mistakes-and how to Correct Them: Lessons from the New Science of Behavioral Economics. New York, NY: United States of America: Simon & Schuster.

    Google Scholar 

  • Besede, Tibor et al. (2012). “Age effects and heuristics in decision making”. In: Review of Economics and Statistics 94.2, pages 580–595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Best, Ryan and Neil Charness (2015). “Age differences in the effect of framing on risky choice: A meta-analysis”. In: Psychology and aging 30.3, pages 688–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bockweg, Christian et al. (2017). “Framing and the annuitization decision. Experimental evidence from a Dutch pension fund”. In: Journal of Pension Economics & Finance, pages 1–33. doi: https://doi.org/10.1017/S147474721700018X.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, Jeffrey R (2007). Rational and Behavioral Perspectives on the Role of Annuities in Retirement Planning. NBER Working Paper 13537. Cambridge, MA: United States of America: National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • —— (2009). “Understanding the role of annuities in retirement planning”. In: Overcoming the saving slump: how to increase the effectiveness of financial education and saving programs. Edited by Annamaria Lusardi. Chicago, IL: United States of America: University of Chicago Press, pages 178–208.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brown, Jeffrey R et al. (2017). “Cognitive constraints on valuing annuities”. In: Journal of the European Economic Association 15.2, pages 429–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Browning, Martin and Thomas F. Crossley (2001). “The life-cycle model of consumption and saving”. In: Journal of Economic Perspectives 15.3, pages 3–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruine de Bruin, Wändi, Andrew M Parker, and JoNell Strough (2016). “Choosing to be happy? Age differences in “maximizing” decision strategies and experienced emotional well-being”. In: Psychology and aging 31.3, pages 295–300.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruine de Bruin, Wändi, JoNell Strough, and Andrew M Parker (2014). “Getting older isn’t all that bad: Better decisions and coping when facing “sunk costs” ”. In: Psychology and aging 29.3, pages 642–647.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bryan, Mark and James Lloyd (2014). Who Saves for Retirement? 2: Eligible non-savers. Technical report. London: United Kingdom.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bryan, Mark et al. (2011). Who saves for retirement. Technical report. London: United Kingdom.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cartwright, Edward (2014). Behavioral Economics. Routledge Advanced Texts in Economics and Finance. Abingdon: United Kingdom: Taylor & Francis.

    Google Scholar 

  • Case, Karl E, John M Quigley, and Robert J Shiller (2005). “Comparing wealth effects: the stock market versus the housing market”. In: Advances in macroeconomics 5.1. doi: https://doi.org/10.2202/1534-6013.1235.

  • Chambers, Christopher and Federico Echenique (2016). Revealed Preference Theory. Econometric Society Monographs. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clark, L et al. (2008b). “Differential effects of insular and ventromedial prefrontal cortex lesions on risky decision-making”. In: Brain 131.5, pages 1311–1322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Damasio, Antonio R (1994). Descartes’ Error: Emotion, Reason and the Human Brain. New York, NY: United States of America: G. P. Putnam’s Sons.

    Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, Stefano (2009). “Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field”. In: Journal of Economic Literature 47.2, pages 315–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dye, Cheryl J and Sara Wilcox (2006). “Beliefs of low-income and rural older women regarding physical activity: You have to want to make your life better”. In: Women & Health 43.1, pages 115–134.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellen, Pam Scholder, Joshua L Wiener, and M Paula Fitzgerald (2012). “Encouraging people to save for their future: Augmenting current efforts with positive visions of the future”. In: Journal of Public Policy & Marketing 31.1, pages 58–72.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Elster, Jon (1979). Ulysses and the Sirens: Studies in Rationality and Irrationality. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, Jon (2000). Ulysses Unbound: Studies in Rationality, Precommitment, and Constraints. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ersner-Hershfield, Hal, G Elliott Wimmer, and Brian Knutson (2008). “Saving for the future self: Neural measures of future self-continuity predict temporal discounting”. In: Social cognitive and affective neuroscience 4.1, pages 85–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fein, George, Shannon McGillivray, and Peter Finn (2007). “Older adults make less advantageous decisions than younger adults: Cognitive and psychological correlates”. In: Journal of the International Neuropsychological Society 13.3, pages 480–489.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Finucane, Melissa L (2008). “Emotion, affect, and risk communication with older adults: challenges and opportunities”. In: Journal of Risk Research 11.8, pages 983–997.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foster, Liam (2017). “Young people and attitudes towards pension planning”. In: Social Policy and Society 16.1, pages 65–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frey, Renato, Rui Mata, and Ralph Hertwig (2015). “The role of cognitive abilities in decisions from experience: Age differences emerge as a function of choice set size”. In: Cognition 142, pages 60–80.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frijda, Nico H (1986). The Emotions. Studies in Emotion and Social Interaction. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Furnham, Adrian and Hua Chu Boo (2011). “A literature review of the anchoring effect”. In: The Journal of Socio-Economics 40.1, pages 35–42.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • García, María Teresa M (2006). “Individual responsibility for the Adequacy of Retirement Income”. In: Pensions: An International Journal 11.3, pages 192–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilbert, Daniel T and Timothy D Wilson (2007). “Prospection: Experiencing the future”. In: Science 317.5843, pages 1351–1354.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goldstein, E. Bruce, editor (2001). Blackwell Handbook of Perception. Blackwell Handbooks of Experimental. Psychology Oxford: United Kingdom: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • —— (2013). Sensation and Perception. Belmont, CA: United States of America: Cengage Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grondin, Simon (2016). Psychology of Perception. Cham: Switzerland: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grubb, Michael A et al. (2016). “Neuroanatomy accounts for age-related changes in risk preferences”. In: Nature communications 7. doi: https://doi.org/10.1038/ncomms13822.

  • Haller, Ariane and Lars Schwabe (2014). “Sunk costs in the human brain”. In: Neuroimage 97, pages 127–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Han, S Duke et al. (2016). “Grey matter correlates of susceptibility to scams in community-dwelling older adults”. In: Brain imaging and behavior 10.2, pages 524–532.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hanoch, Yaniv et al. (2011). “Choosing the right medicare prescription drug plan: the effect of age, strategy selection, and choice set size”. In: Health Psychology 30.6, pages 719–727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, Mathew A et al. (2016). “Personality stability from age 14 to age 77 years”. In: Psychology and aging 31.8, pages 862–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hess, Thomas M, Daniel C Rosenberg, and Sandra J Waters (2001). “Motivation and representational processes in adulthood: the effects of social accountability and information relevance”. In: Psychology and Aging 16.4, pages 629–642.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Heukelom, Floris (2014). Behavioral Economics: A History. Historical Perspectives on Modern Economics. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hippo, Augustine of (1998). The Confessions. Oxford World’s Classics. Oxford: United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Homer (1990). The Odyssey [c. 8C B.C.](translation by Richmond Lattimore). Great Books of the Western World. Chicago, IL: United States of America: Encyclopaedia Britannica Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Horowitz, John K and Kenneth E McConnell (2002). “A Review of WTA/WTP Studies”. In: Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 44, pages 426–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu, Wei-Yin and Jason S Scott (2007). “Behavioral obstacles in the annuity market”. In: Financial Analysts Journal 63.6, pages 71–82.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, Sheena S and Emir Kamenica (2010). “Choice proliferation, simplicity seeking, and asset allocation”. In: Journal of Public Economics 94.7, pages 530–539.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Iyengar, Sheena S and Mark R Lepper (2000). “When choice is demotivating: Can one desire too much of a good thing?” In: Journal of personality and social psychology 79.6, pages 995–1006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jehle, Geoffrey Alexander and Philip J. Reny (2011). Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Harlow, Essex: United Kingdom: Pearson Education Limited.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jolls, Christine, Cass R Sunstein, and Richard Thaler (1998). “A Behavioral Approach to Law and Economics”. In: Stanford Law Review 50, pages 1471–1550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Josef, Anika K et al. (2016). “Stability and change in risk-taking propensity across the adult life span”. In: Journal of personality and social psychology 111.3, pages 430–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel (2003). “Maps of Bounded Rationality: Psychology for Behavioral Economics”. In: The American Economic Review 93.5, pages 1449–1475.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —— (2011). Thinking, Fast and Slow. London: United Kingdom: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L Knetsch, and Richard H Thaler (1991). “Anomalies: The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias”. In: The Journal of Economic Perspectives 5.1, pages 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, Ilana Ritov, and David Schkade (1999). “Economic Preferences or Attitude Expressions?: An Analysis of Dollar Responses to Public Issues”. In: Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19.1-3, pages 203–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel and Amos Tversky (1979). “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk”. In: Econometrica 47.2, pages 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kearney, JM and S McElhone (1999). “Perceived barriers in trying to eat healthier. Results of a pan-EU consumer attitudinal survey”. In: British Journal of Nutrition 81.S1, S133–S137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, Sunghan et al. (2005). “Framing effects in younger and older adults”. In: The Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 60.4, P215–P218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, YoungHee (2015). An Analysis of Barrier Factors of Physical Activity among Old Adults.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kovalchik, Stephanie et al. (2005). “Aging and decision making: A comparison between neurologically healthy elderly and young individuals”. In: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 58.1, pages 79–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, David (1998). “Comment on ‘Personal Retirement Saving Programs and Asset Accumulation. Reconciling the Evidence’ by James M Poterba, Steven F Venti, and David A Wise”. In: Frontiers in the Economics of Aging. Edited by David A Wise. Chicago, IL: United States of America: The University of Chicago Press, pages 106–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lara, Jose, Leigh-Ann McCrum, and John C Mathers (2014). “Association of Mediterranean diet and other health behaviours with barriers to healthy eating and perceived health among British adults of retirement age”. In: Maturitas 79.3, pages 292–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lemaire, Patrick (2016). Cognitive Aging: The Role of Strategies. Abingdon: United Kingdom: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, Irwin P, Sandra L Schneider, and Gary J Gaeth (1998). “All frames are not created equal: A typology and critical analysis of framing effects”. In: Organizational behavior and human decision processes 76.2, pages 149–188.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Levin, Laurence (1998). “Are assets fungible?: Testing the behavioral theory of life-cycle savings”. In: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 36.1, pages 59–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malenka, David J et al. (1993). “The framing effect of relative and absolute risk”. In: Journal of general internal medicine 8.10, pages 543–548.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mas-Colell, Andreu, Michael D Whinston, and Jerry R Green (1995). Microeconomic Theory. Oxford: United Kingdom: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mata, Rui et al. (2011). “Age differences in risky choice: A meta-analysis”. In: Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1235.1, pages 18–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mather, Mara and Laura L Carstensen (2005). “Aging and motivated cognition: The positivity effect in attention and memory”. In: Trends in cognitive sciences 9.10, pages 496–502.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mehta, Shivan J et al. (2016). “Participation Rates With Opt-out Enrollment in a Remote Monitoring Intervention for Patients With Myocardial Infarction”. In: JAMA Cardiology 1.7, pages 847–848.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mikels, Joseph A and Andrew E Reed (2009). “Monetary losses do not loom large in later life: Age differences in the framing effect”. In: Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 64.4, pages 457–460.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Millar, Michael and Dwayne Devonish (2009). “Attitudes, savings choices, level of knowledge and investment preferences of employees toward pensions and retirement planning: Survey evidence from Barbados”. In: Pensions: An International Journal 14.4, pages 299–317.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell, Jason P et al. (2011). “Medial prefrontal cortex predicts intertemporal choice”. In: Journal of cognitive neuroscience 23.4, pages 857–866.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morewedge, Carey K and Colleen E Giblin (2015). “Explanations of the endowment effect: an integrative review”. In: Trends in cognitive sciences 19.6, pages 339–348.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Munro, Alistair (2009). Bounded Rationality and Public Policy: A Perspective from Behavioural Economics. The Economics of Non-Market Goods and Resources. Dordrecht: The Netherlands: Springer Netherlands.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pachur, Thorsten, Rui Mata, and Ralph Hertwig (2017). “Who dares, who errs? Disentangling cognitive and motivational roots of age differences in decisions under risk”. In: Psychological science 28.4, pages 504–518.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pettigrew, Nick et al. (2007). Live now, save later? Young people, saving and pensions. Research Report. London: United Kingdom.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierce, Jon L, Tatiana Kostova, and Kurt T Dirks (2001). “Toward a theory of psychological ownership in organizations”. In: Academy of Management Review 26.2, pages 298–310.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Plott, Charles R and Kathryn Zeiler (2005). “The Willingness to Pay-Willingness to Accept Gap, the “Endowment Effect”, Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations”. In: The American Economic Review 95.3, pages 530–545.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pu, Bingyan, Huamao Peng, and Shiyong Xia (2017). “Role of Emotion and Cognition on Age Differences in the Framing Effect”. In: The International Journal of Aging and Human Development. doi: https://doi.org/10.1177/0091415017691284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raaij, W Fred van (2016). “Saving Behavior”. In: Understanding Consumer Financial Behavior. Money Management in an Age of Financial Illiteracy. New York, NY: United States of America: Springer, pages 33–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin, Howard (1995). “Behavioral economics without anomalies”. In: Journal of the experimental analysis of behavior 64.3, pages 397–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reed, Andrew E, Joseph A Mikels, and Kosali I Simon (2008). “Older adults prefer less choice than young adults”. In: Psychology and aging 23.3, pages 671–675.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rolison, Jonathan J et al. (2013). “Risk-taking differences across the adult life span: a question of age and domain”. In: Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 69.6, pages 870–880.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roth, Stefan, Thomas Robbert, and Lennart Straus (2015). “On the sunk-cost effect in economic decision-making: a meta-analytic review”. In: Business research 8.1, pages 99–138.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rutledge, Robb B et al. (2016). “Risk taking for potential reward decreases across the lifespan”. In: Current Biology 26.12, pages 1634–1639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, William and Richard Zeckhauser (1988). “Status quo bias in decision making”. In: Journal of risk and uncertainty 1.1, pages 7–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schooley, Diane K and Debra Drecnik Worden (2008). “A behavioral life-cycle approach to understanding the wealth effect”. In: Business Economics 43.2, pages 7–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schreier, Maria Magdalena et al. (2016). “Fitness training for the old and frail”. In: Zeitschrift für Gerontologie und Geriatrie 49.2, pages 107–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, Barry (2000). “Self-determination: The tyranny of freedom”. In: American psychologist 55.1, pages 79–88.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seaman, Kendra L et al. (2017). “Individual differences in skewed financial risk-taking across the adult life span”. In: Cognitive, Affective, & Behavioral Neuroscience 17.6, pages 1232–1241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sethi-Iyengar, Sheena, Gur Huberman, and Wei Jiang (2004). “How much choice is too much? Contributions to 401 (k) retirement plans”. In: Pension design and structure: New lessons from behavioral finance 83, pages 84–87.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shamaskin, Andrea M, Joseph A Mikels, and Andrew E Reed (2010). “Getting the message across: age differences in the positive and negative framing of health care messages”. In: Psychology and Aging 25.3, pages 746–751.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shefrin, Hersh M and Richard H Thaler (1988). “The behavioral life-cycle hypothesis”. In: Economic inquiry 26.4, pages 609–643.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shu, Suzanne B and Joann Peck (2011). “Psychological ownership and affective reaction: Emotional attachment process variables and the endowment effect”. In: Journal of Consumer Psychology 21.4, pages 439–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Simon, Herbert A (1947). Administrative behavior. A study of decision-making processes in administrative organization. New York, NY: United States of America. Macmillan Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • —— (1955). “A behavioral model of rational choice”. In: The Quarterly Journal of Economics 69.1, pages 99–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —— (1959). “Theories of decision-making in economics and behavioral science”. In: The American Economic Review 49.3, pages 253–283.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simonson, Itamar and Aimee Drolet (2004). “Anchoring effects on consumers’ willingness-to-pay and willingness-to-accept”. In: Journal of consumer research 31.3, pages 681–690.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, Arun Kumar (2015). Social Psychology. Delhi: India: PHI Learning.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spiegelhalter, DJ and M Pearson (2010). 2845 ways to spin the risk. url: http://understandinguncertainty.%20org/node/233.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stein, Gertrude (2012). Geography and Plays. Madison, WI: United States of America: University of Wisconsin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strotz, Robert Henry (1955). “Myopia and inconsistency in dynamic utility maximization”. In: The Review of Economic Studies 23.3, pages 165–180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strough, JoNell, Leo Schlosnagle, and Lisa DiDonato (2011). “Understanding decisions about sunk costs from older and younger adults’ perspectives”. In: Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 66.6, pages 681–686.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Strough, JoNell et al. (2008). “Are older adults less subject to the sunk-cost fallacy than younger adults?” In: Psychological Science 19.7, pages 650–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanius, Betty E et al. (2009). “Aging and choice: applications to Medicare Part D”. In: Judgment and Decision Making 4.1, pages 92–101.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teger, Allan I (1980). Too Much Invested to Quit. Pergamon general psychology series. Elmsford, NY: United States of America: Pergamon Press Inc.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, Richard (1980). “Toward a positive theory of consumer choice”. In: Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 1.1, pages 39–60.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, Richard H (1988). “Anomalies: The winner’s curse”. In: The Journal of Economic Perspectives 2.1, pages 191–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —— (1990). “Anomalies: Saving, fungibility, and mental accounts”. In: The Journal of Economic Perspectives 4.1, pages 193–205.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —— (1999). “Mental accounting matters”. In: Journal of Behavioral decision making 12.3, pages 183–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Prize in Economics 1978 (2014). Press Release. url: http://www.nobelprize.org/nobel_prizes/economic-sciences/laureates/1978/press.html.

  • Thomas, Ayanna K and Peter R Millar (2011). “Reducing the framing effect in older and younger adults by encouraging analytic processing”. In: Journals of Gerontology Series B: Psychological Sciences and Social Sciences 67.2, pages 139–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomer, John F (2007). “What is behavioral economics?” In: The Journal of Socio-Economics 36.3, pages 463–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tversky Amos and Daniel Kahneman (1974). “Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases”. In: Science 185.4157, pages 1124–1131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tymula, Agnieszka et al. (2013). “Like cognitive function, decision making across the life span shows profound age-related changes”. In: Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 110.42, pages 17143–17148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Varian, Hal R (2014). Intermediate Microeconomics: A Modern Approach. New York, NY: United States of America: W. W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Venti, Steven F and David A Wise (1990b). “Have IRAs increased US saving?: Evidence from consumer expenditure surveys”. In: The Quarterly Journal of Economics 105.3, pages 661–698.

    Google Scholar 

  • Visco, Ignazio (2009). “Retirement saving and the payout phase”. In: OECD Journal: Financial Market Trends 2009.1, pages 143–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wakker, Peter P (2010). Prospect Theory: For Risk and Ambiguity. Cambridge: United Kingdom: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wang, Xiao Tian (1996). “Framing effects: Dynamics and task domains”. In: Organizational behavior and human decision processes 68.2, pages 145–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Watanabe, Satoshi and Hirohide Shibutani (2010). “Aging and decision making: Differences in susceptibility to the risky-choice framing effect between older and younger adults in Japan”. In: Japanese Psychological Research 52.3, pages 163–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiesiolek, Carine Carolina, Maria Paula Foss, and Paula Rejane Beserra Diniz (2014). “Normal aging and decision-making: a systematic review of the literature of the last 10 years”. In: Jornal Brasileiro de Psiquiatria 63.3, pages 255–259.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilkinson, Nick and Matthias Klaes (2012). An Introduction to Behavioral Economics. Basingstoke: United Kingdom: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, Timothy D et al. (1996). “A new look at anchoring effects: basic anchoring and its antecedents”. In: Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 125.4, pages 387–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong, Kin Fai Ellick and Jessica Kwong (2005). “Comparing two tiny giants or two huge dwarfs? Preference reversals owing to number size framing”. In: Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 98.1, pages 54–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wood, Meagan, Sheila Black, and Ansley Gilpin (2016). “The effects of age, priming, and working memory on decision-making”. In: International journal of environmental research and public health 13.1. doi: https://doi.org/10.3390/ijerph13010119.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zeng, Jianmin et al. (2013). “An fMRI study on sunk cost effect”. In: Brain research 1519, pages 63–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to José Luis Iparraguirre .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Iparraguirre, J.L. (2019). Behavioural Economics and Individual Ageing. In: Economics and Ageing . Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-29013-9_8

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-29013-9_8

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-29012-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-29013-9

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics