Skip to main content

Consequences of Preferential Voting

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Preferential Voting Systems
  • 439 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter underlines the main trends in the number of preferences cast and the intraparty dynamics. The share of preference votes can be determined as the ratio between the total number of preferences expressed and the total number of preferences possible. An important question related to preferential voting systems is linked to their effect on the internal party electoral competition and how to measure it. In addition, we can measure two dimensions of competition: the influence and the weight of the head of the list or the most-voted-for candidate. In this chapter, the author reports data for 19 countries in terms of preference cast at the general elections, and in some cases also for European elections. The focus is on the effects of the preferential voting on the incumbents’ MPs electoral fate. The different sources of turnover are analysed and described for all the PLPR sub-types.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    In countries where it is not possible to cast other than a personal vote that is pooled to the party too, following other examples, I calculate the share of preferences indicated by counting all those given to other candidates than the head of the list.

  2. 2.

    This test is particularly interesting given newly available data that make possible an analysis that also considers the district magnitude (as an intervening variable) (Carey and Shugart 1995), as I present in Chapters 5 and 6.

  3. 3.

    Electronic voting machines were introduced in Brazilian federal elections in 2002. This has somehow affected the trend changes in preference voting as suggested by Hidalgo (2012). That is, invalid voting rates went down when the voting moved from paper to machine, and less knowledgeable voters, who were likelier to give only a party vote, were less likely to spoil their ballots on the machine.

  4. 4.

    It must be noticed—as indicated in the methodological part of the book—that the share of preferences is calculated as the ratio between the total preferences over the total votes and the maximum preferences allowed.

  5. 5.

    Regarding incumbents, it must be clarified that the turnover is important even soon after the elections. Therefore, as for other countries and to ensure methodological consistency, I calculate the data after the results have been made official. For example, during the 2003–2007 parliamentary term, there were several dozen MPs who either left office or were ministers, and so on. That means that just as many “alternatives” were appointed from the parties’ original candidate lists, and many of them also ran for “re-election” in 2007. Therefore, if one looks simply at who was listed as an MP in the 2007 election lists, the total number of “incumbents” (thanks to these alternatives) was 118, thereby surpassing even the number of MPs in the Parliament itself (which is 101).

  6. 6.

    In 2012, Greece held two early elections in a row, the first in May and the second in June. However, for the latter case, data are not available.

  7. 7.

    In districts with a magnitude up to 15, 3 preferences can be indicated, and 4 preferences when 16 or more deputies are selected in the district.

  8. 8.

    For local elections, voters can also cast a preference vote. In 2012, the male/female vote of preference alternation was also introduced in cities with more than 15,000 inhabitants.

  9. 9.

    Although data from the 2007 elections are not available, it would have been interesting to see any difference in the share of preference votes cast. In fact, any significant variation could have been related to changes in the electoral law rather than in voters’ behaviour per se. In fact, these data could have been misleading. As the proportion of preference votes cast is calculated as the ratio between the preferences expressed and the valid votes multiplied by the number of preference votes allowed, then it is crucial to refer to the change in the latter. As seen, in 2017, 10 preference votes were allowed, while, in 2010 and 2014, this number decreased to exactly half. Therefore, although the values are perfectly comparable and meaningful, it is important to determine whether there have been important changes over time in terms of the total amount of preferences expressed. These data would in fact tell us more about the effective and real weights of the personal votes over time. The raw number of preferences expressed could help us in detecting whether their electoral influence and importance have grown between two elections or, vice versa, whether the percentage increase is only due to the change in the number of votes allowed. In the first case, Kosovo would have been facing an electoral event with potential relevant political consequences (no relevant change in valid vote terms and a big increase in terms of preferences), while, in the second, the importance of preferences would be only marginal (no changes in both variables).

References

  • Ames, B. 1995. Electoral Rules, Constituency Pressures, and Pork Barrel: Bases of Voting in the Brazilian Congress. The Journal of Politics 57 (2): 324–343.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andeweg, R.B., and J. van Holsteyn. 2011. Second Order Personalization: Preference Voting in the Netherlands. Paper Presented at the ECPR General Conference, August 25–27, University of Iceland, Reykjavík.

    Google Scholar 

  • André, A., S. Depauw, M.S. Shugart, and R. Chytilek. 2017. Party Nomination Strategies in Flexible-List Systems: Do Preference Votes Matter? Party Politics 23 (5): 589–600.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carey, J., and M. Shugart. 1995. Incentives to Cultivate a Personal Vote: A Rank Ordering of Electoral Formulas. Electoral Studies 14 (4): 417–439.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • De Winter, L. 1988. Belgium: Democracy or Oligarchy? In Candidate Selection in Comparative Perspective, ed. M. Gallagher and M. Marsh, 20–46. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Winter, L. 2005. Belgium: Empowering Voters and Party Elites? In The Politics of Electoral Systems, ed. M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell, 417–432. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elklit, J. 2005. Denmark: Simplicity Embedded in Complexity (or Is it the Other Way Round?). In The Politics of Electoral Systems, ed. M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell, 433–452. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Farrell, D.M. 2001. Electoral Systems. A Comparative Introduction. New York: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo, F.D. 2012. Renovating Democracy: The Political Consequences of Electoral Reforms in Post-War Brazil. UC Berkley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Karvonen, L. 2004. Preferential Voting: Incidence and Effects. International Political Science Review 25 (2): 203–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Karvonen, L. 2010. The Personalization of Politics: A Study of Parliamentary Democracies. Colchester: ECPR press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, R.S. 1986. Intraparty Preference Voting. In Electoral Laws and Their Political Consequences, ed. B. Grofman and A. Lijphart, 85–103. New York: Agathon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Katz, R.S., and L. Bardi. 1980. Preference Voting and Turnover in Italian Parliamentary Elections. American Journal of Political Science 24 (1): 97–114.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lijphart, A. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performances in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, S. 1990. Politicians, Parties and Electoral Systems: Brazil in Comparative Perspective. Working Paper #141, Kellogg Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mainwaring, S. 1999. Rethinking Party Systems in the Third Wave of Democratization: The Case of Brazil. Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marsh, M. 1985. The Voters Decide? Preferential Voting in European List Systems. European Journal of Political Research 13 (4): 365–378.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Müller, W.C. 1999. Austria. In Semi-Presidentialism in Europe, ed. R. Elgie, 22–47. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunes, F. 2015. Political Parties: The Case of Brazil. In The Presidentialization of Political Parties, ed. G. Passarelli, 67–87. London: Palgrave.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ortega Villodres, C. 2004. Los sistemas de voto preferencial. Un estudio de 16 democracias: reflexiones sobre el sistema electoral español. Madrid: CIS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Passarelli, G. 2017. Determinants of Preferential Voting in Italy: General Lessons from a Crucial Case. Representation 5 (2): 167–183.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Passarelli, G. 2018. Electoral Systems in Context: Italy. In The Oxford Handbook of Electoral Systems, ed. E. Herron, R. Pekkanen, and M.S. Shugart, 851–870. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raunio, T. 2005. Finland: One Hundred Years of Quietude. In The Politics of Electoral Systems, ed. M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell, 473–490. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Renwick, A., and J.-L. Pilet. 2016. Faces on the Ballot: The Personalization of Electoral Systems in Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Samuels, D. 2003. Ambition, Federalism, and Legislative Politics in Brazil. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sartori, G. 1997. Ingegneria costituzionale comparata. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schepis, G. 1963. Analisi statistica dei risultati. In Elezioni e comportamento politico in Italia, ed. A. Spreafico and J. LaPalombara. Milano: Edizioni di Comunità.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shugart, M. 2005. Comparative Electoral Systems Research: The Maturation of a Field and New Challenges Ahead. In The Politics of Electoral Systems, ed. M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell, 25–56. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Spáč, P. 2016. The Role of Ballot Ranking: Preferential Voting in a Nationwide Constituency in Slovakia. East European Politics & Societies 30 (3): 644–663.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Siavelis, P.M. 2005. Chile: The Unexpected (and Expected) Consequences of Electoral Engineering. In The Politics of Electoral Systems, ed. M. Gallagher and P. Mitchell, 433–452. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Wertman, D. 1977. ‘The Italian Electoral Process: The Elections of June 1976’, in Italy at the Polls. In The Parliamentary Elections of 1976, ed. H. R. Penniman, 41–79. Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Gianluca Passarelli .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Passarelli, G. (2020). Consequences of Preferential Voting. In: Preferential Voting Systems. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-25286-1_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics