Skip to main content

Real Worlds: Simulating Non-standard Rationality in Microeconomics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 401 Accesses

Part of the book series: Computational Social Sciences ((CSS))

Abstract

In this chapter, the differences between the standard notion of rationality, used in neoclassical economic model, and the notion of “non-standard” rationality are highlighted. The notion of non-standard rationality has been used in an attempt to address the discrepancies found between the ideal cognitive attitudes of the homo economicus and limited rational abilities of real decision-makers. By contrast, this notion is not supported by any adequate nor exhaustive theoretical account of “non-standard” preferences and therefore doesn’t provide useful applications for real-world simulations in microeconomics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   69.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   89.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD   119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

References

  • Akerlof, G. A. (2002). Behavioural macroeconomics an macroeconomics behaviour. The American Economic Review, 92(3), 411–433.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G. A., & Kranton, R. E. (2000). Economics and identity. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(3), 715–753.

    Google Scholar 

  • Akerlof, G., & Shiller, R. (2009). Animal Spirits: How human psychology drives the economy and why it matters for global capitalism. Rinceton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allais, M. (1953). Le Comportement de l'Homme Rationnel devant le Risque: Critique des Postulats et Axiomes de l'Ecole Americaine. Econometrica, 21(4), 503–546.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, D. (2008). Predictably irrational: The hidden forces that shape our decisions. New York, NY: Harper Collins.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ariely, D., Lowenstein, G., & Prelec, D. (2003). Coherent arbitrariness: Stable demand curves without stable preferences. The Quarterly Journl of Economics, 118, 73–105.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baptista, M. L., et al. (2014). An agent-based model of consumer behaviour based on the BDI Architecture and Neoclassical theory. Developments in Business Simulation and Experiential Learning, 41, 170–178.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bargh, J. A., & Morsella, E. (2008). The unconscious mind. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 3, 73–79.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, S. G. (1976). The economic approach to human behaviour. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bicchieri, C. (2006). The grammar of society: The nature and dynamics of social norms. Cambridge: University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K. (2010). Social norms or social preferences? Mind and Society, 9, 139–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bratman, M. (1987). Intentions, plans and practical reason. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, et al. (2003). Regulations for conservatives: Behavioural economics and the case for asymmetric paternalism. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 51, 1211–1254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C. F., Loewenstein, G., & Rabin, M. (2004). Advances in behavioral economics (The Roundtable Series in behavioral Economics). Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cialdini, R. B., et al. (1990). A focus theory of normative conduct: A theoretical refinement and re-evaluation of the role of norms in human behaviour. Advances in Experimental Social Psychology, 24, 201–234.

    Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. (2014). Caring, the emotions and social norm compliance. Journal of Neuroscience, Psychology and Economics, 7(1), 33–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahr, R., & Gorlin, M. (2013). A dual system framework to understand preference construction processes in choice. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 23(4), 528–542.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Neys, W. (2014). Conflict detection, dual processes and logical intuition: Some clarifications. Thinking and Reasoning, 20(2), 169–187.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Neys, W., & Glumicic, T. (2008). Conflict monitoring in dual process theories of thinking. Cognition, 106(3), 1248–1299.

    Google Scholar 

  • DellaVigna, S. (2009). Psychology and economics: Evidence from the field. Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Association, 47(2), 315–372.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diasakos T. M. (2013). Complexity and bounded rationality in individual decision problems. DiscussionPaper series 201314, Department of Economics, University of St. Andrews.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dietrich, F., & List, C. (2013). Where do preferences come from? International Journal of Game Theory, Springer; Game Theory Society, 42(3), 613–637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dijksterhuis, A., Bos, M. W., Nordgren, L. F., & van Baaren, R. B. (2006). On making the right choice: The deliberation-without-attention effect. Science, 311, 1005–1007.

    Google Scholar 

  • Djiksterhuis, A., & Nordgren, L. F. (2006). A theory of unconscious thought. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 1, 95–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Elster, J. (1994). Rationality, emotions and social norms. Synthese, 98(1), 21–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Espinosa, B. A., et al. (2017). Toward formal modelling of affective agents in a BDI architecture. ACM Transactions on Internet Technology, 17(1), 5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J. (2007). Hypothetical thinking: Dual processes in reasoning and judgement. New York: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J. (2008). Dual-processing accounts of reasoning, judgment, and social cognition. Annual Review of Psychology, 59, 255–278.

    Google Scholar 

  • Evans, J., & Stanovich, K. (2013). Dual-process theories of higher cognition: Advancing the debate. Perspectives on Psychological Sciences, 8(3), 223–241.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., & Gaetcher, S. (2000). Fairness and retaliation. The economics of reciprocity. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, 159–181.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisman, R., Shachar, K., & Markovits, D. (2007). Individual preferences for giving. American Economic Review, 97(5), 1858–1876.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, R. H. (2006). Microeconomics and behaviour. McGraw-Hill/Irwin publisher.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012a) Justifying normative objects: An answer to J. Searle’s model. Paper presented at the 20th anniversary conference of the Italian Society for Analytic Philosophy (SIFA) – Sept. 12–15, 2012, Alghero (University of Sassari).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012b) Positionality and normative ought in Max Scheler’s Formalism. American Philosophical Association - Max Scheler Society of North America biannual conference (Chicago USA)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012c). Normative objects and material a-priori. Poster presented at the conference “Objects in Mind” - Interacting Mind Centre, Aarhus University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012d). Normativity and material-a priori. Draft contents sent and discussed via e-mail with Francesco Guala; July the 7th 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012e). On the Justification of normative objects. Draft contents sent via e-mail to the attention of Mattia Gallotti and John Michael; December the 1st 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2012f). Justifying normative objects: An answer to J.Searle’s model Conference long abstract sent and discussed with Enrico Terrone; September the 18th 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2013a). Emergence and persistence of social norms: A material-based account. Paper presented at the Mid-Term Postgraduate conference of the Italian Society of Logic and Philosophy of Science –SILFS - May 29–31, 2013, University of Urbino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2013b). Coordinate action and individual intentions. Poster presented at the conference “Minds in Common” Institut d’Etude de la Cognition, École normale supérieure.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2013c). Justifying normative objects: A material apriori-based account. Phd Project Proposal submitted at the University of Exeter - College of Social Sciences and International Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gerace, G. (2018). A study for the representation of social normativity. Phd Project Proposal submitted at the IMT – Lucca and sent to the attention of Gustavo Cevolani; August the 3rd 2018.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G. (2008). Why heuristic works. Perspectives on Psychological Science, 3, 20–281.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gigerenzer, G., & Goldstein, D. (1996). Reasoning the fast and frugal way: Models of bounded rationality. Cognitive Science, 103(4), 650–666.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, N., et al. (2014). Microeconomics in context. New York: Routledge. Gordon, R.

    Google Scholar 

  • Haidt, J. (2001). The emotional dog and its rational tail: A social intuitionist approach to moral judgment. Psychological Review, 108(4), 814–834.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, O. (1995). Changes in preferences. Theory and Decision, 38(1), 1–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hassin, R., Uleman, J. S., & Bargh, J. A. (Eds.). (2005). The new Unconscious. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, D. (2012). Preference, value, choice and welfare. Cambridge: CUP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hédoin, C. (2015). From utilitarianism to paternalism: When Behavioural economics meets moral philosophy. Revue de Philosophieèconomique, 16, 73–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heidl, S. (2016). Philosophical problems of Behavioural economics. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heukelom, F., & Sent, E.-M. (2017). Behavioral economics: From advising organizations to nudging individuals. Journal of Behavioral Economics for Policy, 1(1), 5–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirshleifer, D., & Shumway, T. (2003). Good day sunshine: Stock returns and the weather. Journal of Finance, 58(3), 1009–1032.

    Google Scholar 

  • Infante, G., Lecouteux, G., & Sugden, R. (2016). Preference purification and the inner rational agent: A critique of the conventional wisdom of behavioural welfare economics. Journal of Economic Methodology, 23(1), 1–25.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. London: Allen Lane.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Frederick, S. (2005). A model of heuristic judgment. In K. Holyoak & R. G. Morrison (Eds.), The Cambridge handbook of thinking and reasoning (pp. 267–294). Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J., & Thaler, R. H. (1990). Experimental tests of the endowment effect and the Coase theorem. Journal of Political Economy, 98(6), 1325–1348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kant, I. (1781). Kritik der reinen Vernunft. De Gruyter Verlag, 2018.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levin, J., & Milgrom, P. (2004). Introduction to choice theory. [online] pp. 1–25. Available at: https://web.stanford.edu/~jdlevin/Econ%20202/Choice%20Theory.pdf.

  • Lieberman, M. D. (2003). Reflective and reflexive judgment processes: A social cognitive neuroscience approach. In Forgas et al. (Eds.), Social judgment: Implicit and explicit processes. New York, NY: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Logan, G. D., & Crump, M. J. (2010). Cognitive illusions of authorship reveal hierarchical error detection in skilled typists. Science, 330, 683–686.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lowenstein, G., & Lerner, J. (2003). The role of affect in decision making. In R. Dawson, K. R. Scherer, & H. H. Goldsmith (Eds.), Handbook of affective science (pp. 619–642). Oxford: OUP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marquès, G., & Weisman, D. (2016). Rethinking Rationality theory’s epistemological status. Normative vs positive approaches. Real World Economic Review, 77, 50–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. W., & Sloman, S. A. (2013). Refining the dual-system theory of choice. Journal of Consumer Psychology, 23(4), 552–555.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mathis, K., & Steffen, A. D. (2015). From rational choice to behavioural economics. In K. Mathis & A. Tor (Eds.), Nudging - possibilities, limitations and applications in European law and economics. Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Melnikoff, D. E., & Bargh, J. A. (2018). The mythical number two. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 22(4), 280–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickerson, R. S. (1998). Confirmation bias: A ubiquitous phenomenon in many guises. Review of General Psychology, 2, 175–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pacherie, E. (2006). Towards a dynamic theory of intentions. In S. Pockett, W. P. Banks, & S. Gallagher (Eds.), Does consciousness cause behavior? An investigation of the nature of volition (pp. 145–167). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Page, S. (2012). Aggregation in agent-based models of economics. The Knowledge Engineering Review, 27(2), 151–162.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paternotte, C., & Grose, J. (2012). Social norms and game theory: Harmony or discord? British Journal for the Philosophy of Science, 64, 551–587.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pennycook, G. (2017). A perspective on the theoretical foundation of dual process models. In W. De Neys (Ed.), Dual process theory 2.0. New York: Psychology Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (1993). Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics. The American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (2000). Risk aversion and expected utility theory: A calibration theorem. Econometrica, 68, 1281–1290.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (2002a). A perspective on psychology and economics. The European Economic Review, 46(4–5), 657–685.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. (2002b). Inference by believers in the law of small numbers. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 775–816.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M., & Thaler, R. (2001). Anomalies: Risk Aversion. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 15, 219–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizzi, J. (2009). Behavioral basis of the financial crisis. Senior Investment Strategist, CapGen financial.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rumbell, T., et al. (2012). Emotions in autonomous agents: Comparative analysis of mechanisms and functions. Autonomous Agents and Multi-Agent System, 25(1), 1–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samson, A. (2016). The behavioral economics guide. London: Behavioral Science Solutions Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1948). Economics, an introductory analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Secchi, D., & Neumann, M. (Eds.). (2016). Agent-based simulation of organizational behavior: New Frontiers of social science research. New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shane, F., Loewenstein, G., & O’Donoghue, T. (2002). Time discounting and time preference: A critical review. Journal of Economic Literature, 40(2), 351–401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpanskykh, A. (2007). Agent-based modeling of human organizations. In F. Amblard (Ed.), Proceedings of the 4th European social simulation association conference (pp. 335–347).

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. A. (1982). Models of bounded rationality: Empirically grounded economic reason. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, A., & Voyer, B. (2014). Emergency purchasing situations: Implications for consumer decision-making. Journal of Economic Psychology, 44, 21–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Slovic, P., et al. (2007). The affect heuristic. European Journal of Operational Research, 177(3), 1333–1352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. (1759). The theory of moral sentiments. (1986). Düsseldorf: Wirtschaft und Finanzen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stanovich, K. E., et al. (2011). The complexity of developmental predictions from dual process models. Developmental Review, 31, 103–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R. (2005). Why rationality is not a consequence of Hume’s theory of choice. European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 12(1), 113–118.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chai Sun-Ki. (2001). Choosing an identity: A general model of preference and belief formation. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sunstein, C. R., & Thaler, R. H. (2003). Libertarian paternalism is not an oxymoron. The University of Chicago Law Review, 70(4), 1159–1202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tesfatsion, L. (2002). Agent-based computational economics. Growing economies from the bottom-up. Artificial Life, 8(1), 55–82.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1985). Mental accounting and consumer choice. Marketing Science, 4(3), 199–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (1999). Mental accounting matters. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making., 12(3), 183–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H. (2016). Behavioural economics: Past, present and future. American Economic Review. American Economic Association, 106(7), 1577–1600.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1974). Judgment under uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185(4157), 1124–1131.

    Google Scholar 

  • Velmans, M. (2000). Understanding consciousness. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Wright, G. H. (1963). The logic of preference. Edimburgh: Edimburgh University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, R., & Dawes, R. (2010). Behavioural economics. In N. J. Smelser & R. Swedberg (Eds.), The handbook of economic sociology. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Windrum, P., et al. (2007). Empirical validation of agent-based models: Alternatives and prospects. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 10(2), 1–8.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gerace, G. (2019). Real Worlds: Simulating Non-standard Rationality in Microeconomics. In: Cecconi, F., Campennì, M. (eds) Information and Communication Technologies (ICT) in Economic Modeling. Computational Social Sciences. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-22605-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics