Advertisement

Competition and the Economy: Historical Perspectives

Chapter
  • 60 Downloads

Abstract

This chapter deals with economic competition from a historical anthropological perspective. In A. Smith’s economic classicism there is an interesting anthropological tension between his two main works as well as an important theory of the invisible hand in its relation to man’s self-interest. J.S. Mill developed an idea of “economic man” as an analytical category. This classic period was followed by a neoclassical period characterized by individualism, marginal analysis, utility, need, supply and demand, rationality, mathematics, and a belief that mathematical models could give probable calculations of rational human behavior. Institutional economic theory criticized these theories from an anthropological perspective—a human being is determined by instincts and cultural habits, rationality is less decisive than supposed in neoclassicism and it is unnatural to maximize utility and happiness on the basis of self-interest. Thus, fellowship and cooperation challenged competition. Game theory (mutual dependence between human beings) and utilitarian welfare theory (the individual in society) modified classical and neoclassical economics. Facing the Depression in the 1930s, J.M. Keynes regarded state intervention instead of competitive market-based self-correction as necessary to secure employment and economic growth. This position was heavily criticized by monetarism: minimum state intervention to avoid a dangerous inflation spiral, efficient allocation of resources, economic growth, and competitive power to reduce unemployment. The last part of the chapter presents the idea of competition in some alternative economic theories: Public Choice school, the Neo-Austrian school of economics, behavioral economics, endogenous growth theory, feminist economics, and ecological economics. Despite all these critics, neoclassical economics survived.

References

  1. Amdam, Rolv Petter, and Ove Bjarnar. 2015. Globalization and the Development of Industrial Clusters: Comparing Two Norwegian Clusters, 1900–2010. Business History Review 89 (4): 693–716.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  2. Aristotle and William Ellis. 2009. The Politics of Aristotle: A Treatise on Government. Waiheke Island: The Floating Press. http://web.b.ebscohost.com/ehost/ebookviewer/ebook/bmxlYmtfXzMxMzgwN19fQU41?sid=0bb420b9-72b4-4fb8-a4db-91c71a7989e5@sessionmgr101&vid=0&format=EB&rid=1 (2.5.2017).
  3. Aspromourgos, Tony. 1986. On the Origin of the Term ‘Neoclassical’. Cambridge Journal of Economics 10: 265–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Blaug, Mark. 1992. The Methodology of Economics, or How Economists Explain, 2nd ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  5. Britton, Andrew, and Peter Sedgwick. 2003. Economic Theory and Christian Belief. Bern: Peter Lang.Google Scholar
  6. Brockway, George P. 2001. The End of Economic Man: An Introduction to Humanistic Economics. New York; London: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
  7. Calcagno, Peter T. 2010. Public Choice. In 21st Century Economics: A Reference Handbook, ed. Rhona C. Free, 237–246. Los Angeles, CA: Sage.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  8. Camerer, Colin, and George Loewenstein. 2004. Behavioral Economics: Past, Present, Future. In Advances in Behavioral Economics, ed. Colin Camerer, George Loewenstein, and Matthew Rabin, 3–51. Princeton; Oxford: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  9. Cohen, Norman J. 1983. Two That Are One—Sibling Rivalry in Genesis. Judaism 32: 331–342.Google Scholar
  10. Collins, Denis. 1997. Ethics of Competition. In The Blackwell Encyclopedic Dictionary of Business Ethics, ed. Patricia H. Werhane and R. Edward Freeman. The Blackwell Encyclopedia of Management, 257–259. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  11. Daly, Herman E., and Joshua Farley. 2011. Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications, 2nd ed. Washington: Island Press.Google Scholar
  12. Debreu, Gerard. 1959. Theory of Value: An Axiomatic Analysis of Economic Equilibrium, vol. 17. Monograph/Cowles Foundation for Research in Economics at Yale University. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Dixon, William, and David Wilson. 2012. A History of Homo Economicus: The Nature of the Moral in Economic Theory, vol. 141. Routledge Studies in the History of Economics. London; New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  14. Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 2004. A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation. In Advances in Behavioral Economics, ed. Colin Camerer, George Loewenstein, and Matthew Rabin, 271–296. New York: Russel Sage Foundation.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  15. Feldman, Allan, and Alan Kirman. 1974. Fairness and Envy. The American Economic Review 64: 995–1005.Google Scholar
  16. Ferber, Marianne A., and Julie A. Nelson (eds.). 1993. Beyond Economic Man: Feminist Theory and Economics. Chicago, IL: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  17. Friedman, Milton. 1953. Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  18. Friedman, Milton. 1956. The Quantity Theory of Money—A Restatement. In Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, ed. Milton Friedman, 3–21. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  19. Friedman, Milton, and Rose D. Friedman. 1962. Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  20. Georgesçu-Roegen, Nicholas. 1971. The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Hewitson, Gillian J. 1999. Feminist Economics: Interrogating the Masculinity of Rational Economic Man. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  22. Hewitson, Gillian J. 2010. Feminist Economics. In Twenty-First Century Economics: A Reference Handbook, ed. Rhona C. Free, 901–911. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.Google Scholar
  23. Holmes, Stephen. 1997. Passions and Constraint: On the Theory of Liberal Democracy. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  24. Humphries, Jane (ed.). 1995. Gender and Economics, vol. 45. The International Library of Critical Writings in Economics. Aldershot: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
  25. Kaplan, Kalman J., and Matthew B. Schwartz. 1998. Jacob’s Blessing and the Curse of Oedipus: Sibling Rivalry and Its Resolution. Journal of Psychology and Judaism 22 (1): 71–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
  27. Kirzner, Israel M. 1991. The Driving Force of the Market: The Idea of ‘Competition’ in Contemporary Economic Theory and in the Austrian Theory of the Market Process. In Austrian Economics: Perspectives on the Past and Prospects for the Future, vol. 17, ed. Richard M. Ebeling, 139–160. Champions of Freedom. Hillsdale, MI: Hillsdale College Press.Google Scholar
  28. Kirzner, Israel M. 1994. The Ethics of Competition. In The Ethical Foundations of the Market Economy: International Workshop, ed. Horst Siebert, 101–114. Tübingen: J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck).Google Scholar
  29. Landreth, Harry, and David C. Colander. 2002. History of Economic Thought, 4th ed. Boston, MA: Houghton Mifflin.Google Scholar
  30. McCloskey, Donald N. 1983. The Rhetoric of Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 21: 481–517.Google Scholar
  31. McCloskey, Donald N. 1985. The Rhetoric of Economics. Rhetoric of the Human Sciences. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
  32. Mestmäcker, Ernst Joachim. 1998. The Role of Competition in a Liberal Society. In The Social Market Economy: Theory and Ethics of the Economic Order, ed. Peter Koslowski. Studies in Economic Ethics and Philosophy, 329–350. Berlin: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Mill, John Stuart, et al. 1965. Collected Works of John Stuart Mill: 2-3 2: Principles of Political Economy with Some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy Books III-V and Appendices. Collected Works of John Stuart Mill. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
  34. Morris, Peter. 1994. Introduction to Game Theory. New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Nelson, Julie A. 1996. Feminism, Objectivity and Economics. Economics as Social Theory. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  36. Nelson, Richard R., and Sidney G. Winter. 1982. An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
  37. Persky, Joseph. 1995. Retrospectives: The Ethology of Homo Economicus. Journal of Economic Perspectives 9 (2): 221–231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Piore, Michael J., and Charles F. Sabel. 1984. The Second Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  39. Read, Daniel, et al. 2003. Introduction. In Time and Decision: Economic and Psychological Perspectives on Intertemporal Choice, ed. Daniel Read, Roy F. Baumeister, and George Loewenstein, 1–11. New York: Russell Sage.Google Scholar
  40. Ridley, Matt. 1996. The Origins of Virtue. London; New York: Viking.Google Scholar
  41. Romer, David H. 2012. Advanced Macroeconomics, 4th ed. New York: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.Google Scholar
  42. Romer, Paul M. 1994. The Origins of Endogenous Growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 3–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  43. Rutherford, Malcolm. 1994. Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. Historical Perspectives on Modern Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  44. Sen, Amartya. 1970. Collective Choice and Social Welfare. Mathematical Economics Texts. San Francisco, CA: Holden-Day.Google Scholar
  45. Sen, Amartya. 1987. On Ethics and Economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
  46. Smith, Adam. 1998 [1776]. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Oxford World’s Classics. Oxford; New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  47. Smith, Adam. 2000 [1759]. The Theory of Moral Sentiments. Great Books in Philosophy. New York: Prometheus Books.Google Scholar
  48. Sraffa, Piero. 1926. The Laws on Returns Under Competitive Conditions. Economic Journal 36: 485–504.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Taylor, Charles. 1989. Sources of the Self: The Making of Modern Identity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  50. Vega-Redondo, Fernando. 2003. Economics and the Theory of Games. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  51. von Neumann, John, and Oskar Morgenstern. 1947. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, 2nd ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  52. Wells, Thomas, and Johan Graafland. 2012. Adam Smith’s Bourgeois Virtues in Competition. Business Ethics Quarterly 22: 319–350.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Werhane, Patricia H. 1999. Business Ethics and the Origins of Contemporary Capitalism: Economics and Ethics in the Work of Adam Smith and Herbert Spencer. In A Companion to Business Ethics, vol. 2, ed. Robert E. Frederick, 325–341. Blackwell Companions to Philosophy. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.MF Norwegian School of Theology, Religion and SocietyOsloNorway

Personalised recommendations