Skip to main content

The Agricultural Sector

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Creation of the East Timorese Economy

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in Economic History ((PEHS))

  • 154 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter contrasts Timor’s record with the agricultural dynamism evident in much of Southeast Asia. The agricultural sector is low in production, and it is not competitive internationally. Imports have to be resorted to in order to ensure food security. Production rests on shifting cultivation, bush fallow rotation, and simple hand tools. The main crops—rice and maize—both display considerable fluctuations, and their absolute yields are among the lowest in the region. The production of coffee, the most important export crop, is decreasing. The quality of the land is low and possibly declining, capital inputs are sparsely used, and credit is difficult to obtain. Most of the time, unimproved seed is used, but introduction of high-yielding varieties has proved successful for several crops. The low educational level and the lack of an effective extension service make the introduction of innovations difficult.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Johnston and Mellor (1961).

  2. 2.

    See for example Williamson (2014), Booth (2014).

  3. 3.

    Timmer (2014), p. 91.

  4. 4.

    Bezemer and Headey (2008).

  5. 5.

    Woo (1991), Hill (1992).

  6. 6.

    Hill (1996), p. 123.

  7. 7.

    Timmer (2014), p. 92.

  8. 8.

    Ibid.

  9. 9.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 15.

  10. 10.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014), p. 63.

  11. 11.

    Ibid.

  12. 12.

    World Bank (2018d), p. 45.

  13. 13.

    Viegas (2007).

  14. 14.

    Molyneux et al. (2012), p. 823.

  15. 15.

    Ministry of Finance, General Directorate of Statistics (2015), pp. 2, 19, 21, (2016), pp. 6, 18, 21.

  16. 16.

    World Bank (2016d), p. 12.

  17. 17.

    FAO and World Food Programme (2007), p. 22.

  18. 18.

    World Bank (2005e), p. 5.

  19. 19.

    Booth (2004).

  20. 20.

    World Bank (2005e), p. 5.

  21. 21.

    Molyneux et al. (2012), p. 825.

  22. 22.

    Viegas (2007).

  23. 23.

    However, the distribution of hand tractors to rice farmers undertaken by the government between 2007 and 2011 appears not to have had much influence on rice production. The farmers did not know how to use them, they were used for other purposes than rice production, conflicts arose between farmers with respect to the order of their use, the criteria used for their distribution were deficient, supporting irrigation schemes were lacking, and so on (Soares de Jesus and Mendonça 2015).

  24. 24.

    Viegas (2007), p. 70.

  25. 25.

    Ibid, p. 23.

  26. 26.

    UNDP (2006), p. 27; UNDP (2011), p. 79; Inder et al. (2014), p. 22.

  27. 27.

    Barlow (2001), p. 110.

  28. 28.

    Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (2004), p. 2.

  29. 29.

    It should also be noted that the figures reported by the FAO may be exaggerated. Other sources claim lower figures for rice and maize production (cf. Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries 2009).

  30. 30.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), pp. 43–44.

  31. 31.

    World Bank (2018d), p. 46.

  32. 32.

    Ibid.

  33. 33.

    Inder et al. (2013), p. 4.

  34. 34.

    Fox (2001), p. 164.

  35. 35.

    World Bank (2011a), p. 41.

  36. 36.

    World Bank (2001), p. 6, Oxfam (2003), p. 19.

  37. 37.

    Old and Caetano dos Santos (2003), p. 139.

  38. 38.

    Oxfam (2003), p. 3.

  39. 39.

    It has been estimated that replanting and pruning alone could triple coffee production (World Bank 2011a, p. 46).

  40. 40.

    Inder et al. (2013), pp. 4–5.

  41. 41.

    Amaral (2003), pp. 24–25.

  42. 42.

    Moreno (2000), p. 3.

  43. 43.

    Inder et al. (2013), pp. 16–17.

  44. 44.

    World Bank (2011a), p. 41.

  45. 45.

    Moreno (2000), p. 3.

  46. 46.

    Inder et al. (2013), p. 18.

  47. 47.

    Timmer (2014), p. 110.

  48. 48.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 15.

  49. 49.

    Ibid., p. 26.

  50. 50.

    Ibid., p. 13.

  51. 51.

    Ibid., p. 19.

  52. 52.

    TOMAK (2016b), p. 9.

  53. 53.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 6.

  54. 54.

    TOMAK (2016a), p. 39.

  55. 55.

    A crop-by-crop discussion of possible ways of improving productivity is found in TOMAK (2016b).

  56. 56.

    See for example Griffin (1974), for a discussion.

  57. 57.

    Fox (2001), p.155.

  58. 58.

    UNDP (2006), p. 19.

  59. 59.

    Ibid., p. 21, FAO and World Food Programme (2007), p. 5.

  60. 60.

    Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (2004), p. 1.

  61. 61.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014), p. 64.

  62. 62.

    Fox (2001), p. 157.

  63. 63.

    UNDP (2006), Table 2.1.

  64. 64.

    Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank (2003), p. 30.

  65. 65.

    UNDP (2006), p. 26.

  66. 66.

    Viegas (2001).

  67. 67.

    Viegas (2007), p. 258.

  68. 68.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 120. Cf., however, note 22 above.

  69. 69.

    Dethier and Effenberger (2012). See Viegas (2003) for a discussion of the relevance of the experience of other countries for mechanization in East Timor.

  70. 70.

    FAO (2012), p. 466.

  71. 71.

    World Bank (2015), pp. 97–100.

  72. 72.

    World Bank (2015), p. 68.

  73. 73.

    República Demcrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), pp. 121, 125.

  74. 74.

    World Bank (2015), pp. 68, 70–71.

  75. 75.

    Ibid., pp. 100–101.

  76. 76.

    Ibid., p. 101.

  77. 77.

    Ibid., pp. 100–102.

  78. 78.

    Ibid., pp. 97–100.

  79. 79.

    Ibid., pp. 73–77, 79, 102, 83.

  80. 80.

    Ibid., pp. 78–89.

  81. 81.

    Ibid., p. 84.

  82. 82.

    Ibid., p. 102.

  83. 83.

    Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (2007).

  84. 84.

    World Bank (2015), p. 88.

  85. 85.

    Ibid., p. 89.

  86. 86.

    Ibid., p. 77.

  87. 87.

    Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank (2003), p. ix; Care International Timor Leste (2004), p. 19.

  88. 88.

    Da Costa et al. (2013), p. 90.

  89. 89.

    Lopes and Nesbitt (2012), Table 3.

  90. 90.

    Banco Central de Timor-Leste (2014), p. 50.

  91. 91.

    Ibid., p. 31.

  92. 92.

    Ibid, p. 15.

  93. 93.

    FAO and World Food Programme (2007), p. 12.

  94. 94.

    World Bank (2011a), pp. 97–98.

  95. 95.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 20.

  96. 96.

    Tambun et al. (2016), p. 123. For a study of the rotating credit associations in East Timor, of which there are few, 329 with 6645 members in 2014, see ibid., pp. 123–124.

  97. 97.

    Johnston and Mellor (1961), p. 569.

  98. 98.

    UNDP (2006), p. 28.

  99. 99.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), p. 38. Detailed information is also available in Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Seeds of Life (2013).

  100. 100.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), p. 39. See Gonzalez Ceniceros et al. (2003), Javier et al. (2003), Jayasinghe et al. (2003), Nigam et al. (2003), and Howeler et al. (2003) for details.

  101. 101.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), p. 39.

  102. 102.

    Ibid.

  103. 103.

    Ibid., p. 40.

  104. 104.

    Kunwar et al. (2016), pp. 68–69, 71.

  105. 105.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), pp. 40–41. The acceptance among rice farmers was lower. Only 45 percent of the adopters grew only improved varieties and the average crop area devoted to them was lower yet: 43 percent.

  106. 106.

    The introduction of the program is dealt with in Piggin and Palmer (2003).

  107. 107.

    Spyckerelle et al. (2016), p. 42.

  108. 108.

    Kunwar et al. (2016), p. 72

  109. 109.

    World Bank (2011a).

  110. 110.

    Ibid., p. 30.

  111. 111.

    Barlow (2001), p. 120.

  112. 112.

    Da Cruz (2003), p. 13.

  113. 113.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 43.

  114. 114.

    Da Cruz (2003), p. 13.

  115. 115.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 22.

  116. 116.

    Da Cruz (2003), p. 15.

  117. 117.

    Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries (2012), p. 6.

  118. 118.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014), p. 75.

  119. 119.

    Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries (2012), p. 13, Joseph and Hamagushi (2014), pp. 75–76.

  120. 120.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 76.

  121. 121.

    In many developing countries insufficient competition in the transport sector has resulted in high transport prices (Raballand et al. 2010).

  122. 122.

    UNDP (2006), p. 29.

  123. 123.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 73.

  124. 124.

    World Bank (2015), p. 127.

  125. 125.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 73.

  126. 126.

    World Bank (2011b), Annex 10.1.

  127. 127.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 73.

  128. 128.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014), p. 71.

  129. 129.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 17.

  130. 130.

    Dethier and Effenberger (2012), p. 187.

  131. 131.

    Jouanjean (2013), p.18.

  132. 132.

    World Bank (2015), p. 107.

  133. 133.

    Ibid.

  134. 134.

    Ibid.

  135. 135.

    Ibid., p. 125.

  136. 136.

    Ibid., p. 121.

  137. 137.

    Ibid., p. 132.

  138. 138.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 74.

  139. 139.

    World Bank (2015), pp. 109–110.

  140. 140.

    Ibid., p. 111.

  141. 141.

    Jouanjean (2013), p. 9.

  142. 142.

    For example, Nkonya et al. (2011).

  143. 143.

    Hettige (2006).

  144. 144.

    Mu and van de Walle (2011).

  145. 145.

    Kwon (2006).

  146. 146.

    Jalan and Ravallion (2002).

  147. 147.

    Jouanjean (2013), p.15.

  148. 148.

    UNDP (2006), p. 30.

  149. 149.

    República Democrática de Timor-Leste (2011a), p. 122.

  150. 150.

    Lopes and Nesbitt (2012), p. 9.

  151. 151.

    Ibid.

  152. 152.

    Fitzpatrick (2001b), p.1.

  153. 153.

    Fitzpatrick (2002), p. 7.

  154. 154.

    Ibid.

  155. 155.

    World Bank (2018a), p. 199. The ranking is found on the web-page http://www.doingbusiness.org/rankings.

  156. 156.

    Fitzpatrick (2002), p. 1.

  157. 157.

    Fitzpatrick (2001a), (2002), p. 15, Harrington (2007), International Crisis Group (2010). For a discussion of traditional views of land rights in East Timor, see Cryan (2015).

  158. 158.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014), p. 65.

  159. 159.

    Fitzpatrick (2002), p. 21.

  160. 160.

    UNDP (2006), p. 29.

  161. 161.

    Justice for the Poor (2010), p. 3.

  162. 162.

    Government of Timor-Leste (2017e).

  163. 163.

    World Bank (2018d), p. 14.

  164. 164.

    See for example Bezemer and Headey (2008).

  165. 165.

    Joseph and Hamaguchi (2014, p. 72), World Bank (2011a), p. 77.

  166. 166.

    Timmer (2001), p. 105, UNDP (2006), p. 41.

  167. 167.

    TOMAK (2016c), pp. 14, 18.

  168. 168.

    Lopes and Nesbitt (2012), p. 8

  169. 169.

    Anderson and Feder (2007).

  170. 170.

    Dorward et al. (2004).

  171. 171.

    Inder et al. (2014), p. 23.

  172. 172.

    The data used in the study are a decade old. However, as the authors point out: ‘While much has changed in Timor-Leste since 2007, it is generally accepted that rural, agricultural life has not changed significantly for the majority of the population’ (ibid., p. 20).

  173. 173.

    TOMAK (2016c), p. 6.

  174. 174.

    Islam et al. (2016), p. 116.

  175. 175.

    As it seems, the pricing system sometimes also serves to discourage farmers from producing higher-quality commodities, for instance, in the case of coffee, where flat price is paid both for cherry (untreated beans) and for parchment (semi-processed coffee). No premium is obtained for processing or quality (República Democrática de Timor-Leste 2011a, p. 129, Joseph and Hamaguchi 2014, p. 69).

  176. 176.

    Conroy (2006).

  177. 177.

    Ibid., p. 21.

  178. 178.

    Ibid., p. 20.

  179. 179.

    Cf. also Inder et al. (2013), pp. 41–42, where it is suggested that the price paid to coffee growers is too low to serve as an incentive for increased production.

  180. 180.

    Conroy (2006), p. 21.

  181. 181.

    Myint (1958).

  182. 182.

    Findlay and Lundahl (1994).

  183. 183.

    TOMAK (2016a), p. 13.

  184. 184.

    Lundahl and Sjöholm (2013).

  185. 185.

    Da Costa (2003), p. 47.

  186. 186.

    Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries (2007), p. 8.

  187. 187.

    Ibid., p. 19.

  188. 188.

    Democratic Republic of Timor-Leste (2011b), p. 9.

  189. 189.

    Gusmão (2017), p. 6.

  190. 190.

    Timor-Leste National Action Programme (2008), p. 8.

  191. 191.

    Ibid.

  192. 192.

    Hunnam (2009), p. 7.

  193. 193.

    Rybczynski (1955).

  194. 194.

    See Lundahl (1979), Chapter 5, for a parallel case: that of Haiti.

  195. 195.

    Molyneux et al. (2012), p. 824.

  196. 196.

    Hunnam (2009), p. 9.

  197. 197.

    Ibid.

  198. 198.

    Molyneux et al. (2012), p. 828.

  199. 199.

    Ibid.

  200. 200.

    Ibid., p. 834.

  201. 201.

    Ibid., p. 831.

  202. 202.

    Ibid., p. 829.

  203. 203.

    Ibid., pp. 828–829.

  204. 204.

    Ibid., p. 833.

  205. 205.

    Ibid., p. 835.

  206. 206.

    Ibid., p. 833.

  207. 207.

    Ibid., p. 834.

  208. 208.

    Ibid.

  209. 209.

    Ibid.

  210. 210.

    Ibid., p. 835.

  211. 211.

    Boserup (1965).

  212. 212.

    Lundahl and Ndulu (1990).

  213. 213.

    An alternative formulation would be to assume that the household maximizes expected utility subject to a survival constraint. The present formulation does not take uncertainty into account.

  214. 214.

    Possibly, the household is not interested in leisure. This reduces the utility maximization to a choice between the consumption of food and manufactured goods.

  215. 215.

    Conroy (2006), p. 20.

  216. 216.

    See Lundahl and Sjöholm (2005), p. 14.

  217. 217.

    Inder et al. (2013), pp. 22, 20. The effects of outside jobs on household income appear to be more uncertain when obtaining an outside job is connected with migration. Thus, Housen et al. (2012, pp. 6, 13) found that in a sample of 654 randomly selected households (4272 individuals) in Baucau, Ermera and Viqueque, 45 percent (294 households) had at least one migrant, but only 19 percent received a cash or in-kind remittance from the latter.

References

  • Amaral, Fernando Egidio. 2003. Prospects for Coffee Development in East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson Jock R., and Gershon Feder. 2007. Agricultural Extension. In Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Vol. 3, ed. Robert Evenson and Prabhu Pingali. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banco Central de Timor-Leste. 2014. Spurring Growth: Master Plan for Financial Sector Development in Timor-Leste 2014–2025. Dili: Banco Central de Timor-Leste. https://www.bancocentral.tl/uploads/documentos/documento_1459352559_2094.pdf. Downloaded 15 June 2017.

  • Barlow, Colin. 2001. The Rural Economy and Institutions in East Timor. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, ed. Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha. Singapore and Canberra: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies and Asia Pacific Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bezemer, Dirk, and Derek Headey. 2008. Agriculture, Development, and Urban Bias. World Development 36: 1342–1364.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, Anne. 2004. Africa in Asia? The Development Challenges Facing Eastern Indonesia and East Timor. Oxford Development Studies 32: 19–35.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, Anne. 2014. A Century of Growth, Crisis, War and Recovery, 1870–1970. In Routledge Handbook of Southeast Asian Economics, ed. Ian Coxhead. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boserup, Ester. 1965. The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure. London: George Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Care International Timor Leste. 2004. Rice Marketing Survey Report Undertaken in Manatutu, Maliana, Suai, Viqueque and Oecusse. http://www.jica.go.jp/easttimor/english/activities/pdf/report.pdf. Downloaded 20 August 2012.

  • Conroy, John. 2006. Timor-Leste Access to Finance for Investment and Working Capital. Report No. 37736. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cryan, Meabh. 2015. ‘Empty Land?’ The Politics of Land in Timor-Leste. In A New Era? Timor-Leste after the UN, ed. Sue Ingram, Lia Kent, and Andrew McWilliam. Canberra: Australian National University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Costa, Helder. 2003. The Evolution of Agricultural Policies in East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste), ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Da Costa, Marcelino dJ, Modesto Lopes, Anita Ximenes, Adelfredo do Rosario Ferreira, Luc Spyckerelle, Rob Williams, Harry Nesbitt, and Williams Erskine. 2013. Household Food Insecurity in Timor-Leste. Food Security 5: 83–94. https://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1007%2Fs12571-012-0228-6.pdf. Downloaded 14 September 2017.

  • Da Cruz, Cesar J. 2003. Livestock Development in East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Democratic Republic of Timor-Leste. 2011a .Strategic Development Plan 2011–2030. Dili: Direcção Geral de Estatística. http://timor-leste.gov.tl/wp-content/uploads/2012/02/Strategic-Development-Plan_EN.pdf.

  • Dethier, Jean-Jacques and Alexandra Effenberger. 2012. Agriculture and Development: A Brief Review of the Literature. Economic Systems 36: 175–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dorward, Andrew, Jonathan Kydd, Jamie Morrison, and Ian Urey. 2004. A Policy Agenda for Pro-Poor Agricultural Growth. World Development 32: 73–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • FAO (Food and Agricultural Organization), and World Food Programme. 2007. Special Report: FAO/WFP Crop and Food Supply Assessment Mission to Timor-Leste. 21 June. Rome: Food and Agricultural Organization and World Food Programme. ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/010/ah866e/ah866e00.pdf. Downloaded 28 September 2017.

  • FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization). (2012). Irrigation in Southern and Eastern Asia in figures – AQUASTAT Survey – 2011, Water Report 37. Rome: Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations. Retrieved June 27, 2018, from http://www.fao.org/docrep/016/i2809e/i2809e.pdf.

  • Findlay, Ronald, and Mats Lundahl. 1994. Natural Resources, ‘Vent-for-Surplus’ and the Staples Theory. In From Classical Economics to Development Economics, ed. Gerald M. Meier. Houndmills, Basingstoke and London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzpatrick, Daniel. 2001a. Property Rights in East Timor’s Reconstruction and Development. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, ed. Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fitzpatrick, Daniel. 2001b. Land Issues in a Newly Independent East Timor. Research Paper No. 21, 2000–01. Canberra: Parliament of Australia, Information and Research Services. http://www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_Departments/Parliamentary_Library/pubs/rp/rp0001/01RP21. Downloaded 11 September 2017.

  • Fitzpatrick, Daniel. 2002. Land Claims in East Timor. Canberra: Asia Pacific Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fox, James J. 2001. Diversity and Differential Development in East Timor: Potential Problems and Future Possibilities. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, ed. Hal Hill, and João M. Saldanha. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gonzalez Ceniceros, F., B. Palmer, C. Piggin, G. San Valentin, F. Tilman de sa Benevides, and A de Oliverira. 2003. Challenges and Opportunities for Maize Research in East Timor – Results of Variety Identification during the 2000 and 2001 Cropping Seasons. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Government of Timor-Leste. 2017e. Enactment of Land Law Major Step for Development. 14 June. http://timor-leste.gov.tl/?p=18216&lang=en. Downloaded 19 June 2017.

  • Griffin, Keith. 1974. The Political Economy of Agrarian Change: An Essay on the Green Revolution. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gusmão, Marcal. 2017. SEPLS in Timor-Leste and Government Initiatives to Promote Their Sustainable Management. Dili: ABS Focal Point of the UNCBD, Ministry of Commerce, Industry and Environment and National University of Timor Lorosa’e. https://www.iges.or.jp/isap/2017/files/TT8/pdf/OK_26_TT8_5_Gusmao.pdf. Downloaded 2 December 2017.

  • Harrington, Andrew. 2007. Ethnicity, Violence, & Land Property Disputes in Timor-Leste. East Timor Law Journal 4, No. 2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hettige, Hemamala. 2006. When Do Rural Roads Benefit the Poor and How? An In-Depth Analysis Based on Case Studies. Manila: Operations Evaluation Department, Asian Development Bank. https://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/publication/29406/when-rural-roads-benefit-poor.pdf. Downloaded 11 September 2017.

  • Hill, Hal. 1992. Regional Development in a Boom and Bust Petroleum Economy: Indonesia Since 1970. Economic Development and Cultural Change 40: 351–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, Hal. 1996. The Indonesian Economy Since 1966. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Housen, T., Hopkins, S., & Earnest, J. (2012). Migration Patterns and the Impact of Internal Remittances on Poverty and Human Capital in Timor-Leste. Reviewed Report Prepared for the Centre for International Health. Perth: Curtin University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Howeler, H. Reihardt, Brian Palmer, Kees Hartojo, and Colin Piggin. 2003. Evaluation of Cassava and Bean Germplasm in East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunnam, Peter. 2009. Sustainable Land Management in Timor-Leste: Capacity Building and Mainstreaming Project. Mid-Term Evaluation. August. Dili: National Directorate of Forestry, Ministry of Agriculture and Forestry, Government of Timor-Leste, and United Nations Development Programme, Global Environment Facility.

    Google Scholar 

  • Inder, Brett, David Lloyd, Katy Cornwell, and Zefereino Tilman. 2013. Coffee, Poverty and Economic Development in Timor-Leste. Clayton: Monash University: Centre for Development Economics. https://www.laohamutuk.org/econ/Monash/MonashCoffeeReport2013en.pdf. Downloaded 16 September 2017.

  • Inder, Brett, Anna Brown, and Gaurav Datt. 2014. Poverty and the Agricultural Household in Timor-Leste: Some Patterns and Puzzles. Mimeo. Clayton: Monash University: Centre for Development Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • International Crisis Group. 2010. Managing Land Conflict in Timor-Leste. Asia Briefing No. 110. 9 September. https://www.crisisgroup.org/asia/south-east-asia/timor-leste/managing-land-conflict-timor-leste. Downloaded 11 September 2017.

  • Islam, Shariful, Syeda Samira Saif, James Maiden, and Robert Raab. 2016. Strengthening Agricultural Markets to Enhance Food Security in Timor-Leste. In Food Security in Timor-Leste through Crop Production. Proceedings of TimorAg2016, an International Conference Held in Dili, Timor-Leste, 13–15 April 2016, ed. Harry Nesbitt, William Erskine, Cesar Jose da Cruz and Anne Moorhead. ACIAR Proceedings No. 146. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. http://aciar.gov.au/files/food_security_in_timor-leste_through_crop_production.pdf. Downloaded 21 September 2017.

  • Jalan, Jyotsna, and Martin Ravallion. 2002. Geographic Poverty Traps? A Micro Model of Consumption Growth in Rural China. Journal of Applied Econometrics 17: 329–346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Javier, E.L., G. San Valentin, P. Kapuhka, B. Monaghan, B. Palmer, C. Piggin, F. Tilman de sa Benavides, D. Da Silva, and A. de Oliveira. 2003. Selection of Better Rice for East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jayasinghe, Upali, Asep Setiawan, Patrick Kapuka, Colin Piggin, and Brian Palmer. 2003. Performance of Some CIP Sweet Potato Clones under East Timorese Conditions. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, Bruce F., and John W. Mellor. 1961. The Role of Agriculture in Economic Development. American Economic Review 51: 566–593.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joseph, Abraham, and Hamaguchi, Takao. 2014. The History and Development of Asia’s Newest Nation. Plymouth: Lexington Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jouanjean, Marie-Agnès. 2013. Targeting Infrastructure Development to Foster Agricultural Trade and Market Integration in Developing Countries: An Analytical Review. Report. June. London: Overseas Development Institute. https://www.odi.org/sites/odi.org.uk/files/odi-assets/publications-opinion-files/8557.pdf. Downloaded 11 September 2017.

  • Justice for the Poor. 2010. The Lay of the Land: Land Access and Dispute Resolution in Timor-Leste. Vol. 5, Issue 3. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/175811468032401006/pdf/560060BRI0J4P1149468B01PUBLIC1print.pdf. Downloaded 20 November 2017.

  • Kunwar, Buddhi, John Dalton, Leoneto Hornai, and Harry Nesbitt. 2016. Seed Multiplication and Distribution: Selecting the Best Option for Timor-Leste. In Food Security in Timor-Leste through Crop Production. Proceedings of TimorAg2016, an International Conference Held in Dili, Timor-Leste, 13–15 April 2016, ed. Harry Nesbitt, William Erskine, Cesar Jose da Cruz, and Anne Moorhead. ACIAR Proceedings No. 146. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. http://aciar.gov.au/files/food_security_in_timor-leste_through_crop_production.pdf. Downloaded 21 September 2017.

  • Kwon, E. (2006). Infrastructure, Growth, and Poverty Reduction in Indonesia: A Cross-Sectional Analysis. Tokyo: Asian Development Bank Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lopes, Modesto and Harry Nesbitt. 2012. Improving Food Security in Timor-Leste with Higher Yield Crop Varieties. Paper presented at the 56th AAERS annual conference, Fremantle, Western Australia, February 7–10, 2012. http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/125077/2/2012AC%20Lopes%20CP.pdf. Downloaded 8 April 2015.

  • Lundahl, Mats. 1979. Peasants and Poverty: A Study of Haiti. London: Croom Helm.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl, Mats, and Benno Ndulu. 1990. Incentives and Food Production in Tanzania. In Mats Lundahl, Incentives and Agriculture in East Africa. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2005. Poverty and Development in Timor-Leste. Sida Country Economic Report 2005:3. Stockholm: Sida.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lundahl, Mats, and Fredrik Sjöholm. 2013. Improving the Lot of the Farmer: Development Challenges in Timor-Leste during the Second Decade of Independence. Asian Economic Papers 12: 71–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Secretariat of State for Fisheries. 2012. Timor-Leste National Aquaculture Development Strategy 2012–2030. Dili: National Directorate of Fisheries and Aquaculture. http://pubs.iclarm.net/resource_centre/WF_3602.pdf. .

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2004. National Food Security Policy for Timor-Leste. Dili: Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2007. First National Report. Land Degradation in Timor-Leste. February. Dili: República Democrática de Timor-Leste. http://www.sprep.org/att/IRC/eCOPIES/Countries/Timor_Leste/3.pdf. Downloaded 31 August 2017.

  • Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries. 2009. Directorate of Agribusiness: Profiles for Maize and Rice. Dili: Ministry of Agriculture, Forestry and Fisheries.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ministry of Finance of Timor-Leste, General Directorate of Statistics. 2015. Timor-Leste National Accounts 2000–2014. December. Dili: Direcção Geral de Estatística. http://www.statistics.gov.tl/wp-content/uploads/2016/06/TL-NA-2000-2014.pdf. Downloaded 29 August 2017.

  • Ministry of Finance of Timor-Leste, General Directorate of Statistics. 2016. Timor-Leste National Accounts 2010–2015. December. Dili. Direcção Geral de Estatística. http://www.statistics.gov.tl/wp-content/uploads/2017/04/TLNA-2010-2015_PUBLISH_FINAL.pdf. Downloaded 29 August 2017.

  • Ministry of Planning and Finance and World Bank. 2003. Poverty in a New Nation: Analysis for Action. Dili and Washington, DC: Ministry of Planning and Finance and the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Molyneux, Nicholas, Gil Rangel da Cruz, Robert L. Williams, Rebecca Andersen, and Neil C. Turner. 2012. Climate Change and Population Growth in Timor Leste: Implications for Food Security. Ambio 41: 823–840. https://link.springer.com/content/pdf/10.1007%2Fs13280-012-0287-0.pdf. Downloaded 19 September 2018.

  • Moreno, Marcos. 2000. East Timor Coffee: An Industry Overview. Dili: Division of Agriculture, United Nations Transitional Administration in East Timor. http://gov.east-timor.org/MAFF/ta200/TA205.pdf. Downloaded 31 August 2017.

  • Mu, Ren, and Dominique van de Walle. 2011. Rural Roads and Local Market Development in Vietnam. Journal of Development Studies 47: 709–734.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myint, Hla. 1958. The Classical Theory of International Trade and the Underdeveloped Countries. Economic Journal 68: 317–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nigam, S.N., B. Palmer, G. San Valentin, P. Kapukha, C. Piggin, and B. Monaghan. 2003. Groundnut: ICRISAT and East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nkonya, Ephraim, Nicolas Gerber, Joachim von Braun, and Alex de Pinto. 2011. Economics of Land Degradation: The Costs of Action versus Inaction. IFPRI Issue Brief 68. September. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute. http://www20.iadb.org/intal/catalogo/PE/2011/07741.pdf. Downloaded 11 September 2017.

  • Old, Kenneth M., and Caetano Dos Santos Cristovao. 2003. A Rust Epidemic of the Coffee Shade Tree. Paraserianthes Falcataria) in East Timor. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Oxfam. 2003. Overview of the Coffee Sector in Timor Leste. January. Oxford: Oxfam.

    Google Scholar 

  • Piggin, Colin, and Brian Palmer. 2003. An Introduction to the ACIAR Project ‘Seeds of Life-East Timor’. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raballand, Gaël, Patricia Macchi, and Carly Petracco. 2010. Rural Road Investment Efficiency: Lessons from Burkina Faso, Cameroon, and Uganda. Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rybczynski, T.M. 1955. Factor Endowment and Relative Commodity Prices. Economica, N.S. 22: 336–341.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seeds of Life/Fini ba Moris. 2013. Seeds of Life 3. Mid-Term Survey. November. Dili: Ministry of Agriculture and Fisheries, Seeds of Life/Fini ba Moris.

    Google Scholar 

  • Soares de Jesus, Leonito, and Abraão Ribeiro Mendonça. 2015. Government Support for a Sustainable Development of Rice Production in Timor-Leste. Master thesis, FE306E Sustainable Management, Bodø: University of Nordland, Bodø Graduate School of Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Spyckerelle, Luc, Octavia Ferreira Agostinho, Sabilio dos Santos, Lucia Viana Branco, and Julie Imron. 2016. Advances in Food Availability in Timor-Leste. In Food Security in Timor-Leste through Crop Production. Proceedings of TimorAg2016, and International Conference Held in Dili, Timor-Leste, 13–15 April 2016, ed. Harry Nesbitt, William Erskine, Cesar Jose da Cruz, and Anne Moorhead. ACIAR Proceedings No. 146. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. http://aciar.gov.au/files/food_security_in_timor-leste_through_crop_production.pdf. Downloaded 21 September 2017.

  • Tambun, Wayan, Jacinto Mala, and Augustinho A. Ximenes. 2016. Savings and Loan Schemes: A Way Forward for Agricultural Development in Rural Timor-Leste? In Food Security in Timor-Leste through Crop Production. Proceedings of TimorAg2016, and International Conference Held in Dili, Timor-Leste, 13–15 April 2016, ed. Harry Nesbitt, William Erskine, Cesar Jose da Cruz, and Anne Moorhead. ACIAR Proceedings No. 146. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research. http://aciar.gov.au/files/food_security_in_timor-leste_through_crop_production.pdf. Downloaded 21 September 2017.

  • Timmer, Peter C. 2001. Food Policy in East Timor: Linking Agriculture, Economic Growth and Poverty Alleviation to Achieve Food Security. In East Timor: Development Challenges for the World’s Newest Nation, ed. Hal Hill and João M. Saldanha. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, Peter C. 2014. The Dynamics of Agricultural Development and Food Security in Southeast Asia: Historical Continuity and Rapid Change. In Routledge Handbook of Southeast Asian Economics, ed. Ian Coxhead. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timor-Leste National Action Programme to Combat Land Degradation. 2008. Revised Draft. November. Dili. http://www.fao.org/fileadmin/templates/cplpunccd/Biblioteca/bib_TL_/Timor-Leste_NAP_Revised_Draft.pdf. Downloaded 1 December 2017.

  • TOMAK (To’os ba Moris Di’ak – Farming for Prosperity). 2016a. Market Analysis of Selected Agricultural Products. Technical Report 1. December. http://tomak.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/Market-analysis-for-selected-agriculture-products.pdf. Downloaded 13 November 2017.

  • TOMAK (To’os ba Moris Di’ak – Farming for Prosperity). 2016b. Potential for Improving On-farm Productivity of Selected Agricultural and Livestock Enterprises. Technical Report 2. December. http://tomak.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/Farm-level-productivity-improvement.pdf. Downloaded 13 November 2017.

  • TOMAK (To’os ba Moris Di’ak – Farming for Prosperity). 2016c. Market Systems & Value Chains Assessment. Technical Report 3. December. http://tomak.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/Market-system-and-value-chain-assessment.pdf. Downloaded 1 November 2017.

  • UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2006. Timor-Leste Human Development Report 2006: The Path out of Poverty. Integrated Rural Development. Dili: UNDP.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNDP (United Nations Development Programme). 2011. Timor-Leste Human Development Report 2011: Managing Natural Resources for Human Development. Dili: UNDP. https://www.laohamutuk.org/econ/HDI10/TLHDR2011En.pdf. Downloaded 30 October 2018.

  • Viegas, Edmundo Da Silva Soares. 2001. Agricultural Mechanization for a Sustainable Development of East Timor, Working Paper. Dili: East Timor Agriculture Network and Virtual Library. http://gov.east-timor.org/MAFF/ta000/TA042.PDF. Downloaded 31 August 2017.

  • Viegas, Edmundo. 2003. Agricultural Mechanisation: Managing Technology Change. In Agriculture: New Directions for a New Nation – East Timor (Timor-Leste). Proceedings of a Workshop 1–3 October 2002, Dili, East Timor, ed. Helder da Costa, Colin Piggin, Cesar J. da Cruz, and James J. Fox. Canberra: Australian Centre for International Agricultural Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viegas, Edmundo Da Silva Soares. 2007. Prospects for Sustainable Crop Production Technologies in East Timor. Palmerston North, New Zealand: PhD Thesis, Institute of Natural Resources, Massey University. https://mro.massey.ac.nz/bitstream/handle/10179/1516/02_whole.pdf?sequence=1&isAllowed=y. Downloaded 31 August 2017.

  • Williamson, Jeffrey G. 2014. Trade, Growth, and Distribution in Southeast Asia, 1500–1940. In Routledge Handbook of Southeast Asian Economics, ed. Ian Coxhead. London and New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woo, Wing T. 1991. Using Economic Methodology to Assess Competing Models of Economic Policy Making in Indonesia. ASEAN Economic Bulletin 7: 307–321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2001. East Timor. A Survey of the Coffee Sector. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2005e. Agricultural Growth for the Poor: An Agenda for Development. Washington DC: The World Bank.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2011a. Timor-Leste: Expanding Near-Term Agricultural Exports. Diagnostic Trade Integration Study (DTIS). Prepared for the Integrated Framework. (In Two Volumes) Volume I: Main Report. Report No. 61814-TP. June. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2011b. Timor-Leste: Expanding Near-Term Agricultural Exports. Diagnostic Trade Integration Study. DTIS) Prepared for the Integrated Framework. (In Two Volumes) Volume II: Report Annexes. Report No. 61814-TP. June. Washington, DC: The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. 2015e. Democratic Republic of Timor-Leste Public Expenditure Review: Infrastructure. A Joint Ministry of Finance and World Bank Review of the Quality of Infrastructure Spending in Timor-Leste, Focusing on Roads, Irrigation and Electricity. Report No. AUS6142. March. Washington, DC: The World Bank. https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/22367/PERI0FINAL00WB0site0.pdf;sequence=1. Downloaded 1 June 2018.

  • World Bank. 2016d. Democratic Republic of Timor-Leste Oecusse Economic and Trade Potential. Volume I: Overview of Oecusse Today & Long Term Potential. Report No ACS 18457 v1. May. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/189241468186840509/pdf/ACS18457-v1-WP-P150407-PUBLIC.pdf. Downloaded 1 June 2017.

  • World Bank. 2016l. Poverty in Timor-Leste 2014. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/577521475573958572/Poverty-in-Timor-Leste-2014. Downloaded 26 April 2017.

  • World Bank. 2018a. Timor-Leste Economic Report. March. Washington, DC: World Bank http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/889001521523777495/Timor-Leste-economic-report-March-2018. Downloaded June 8, 2018.

  • World Bank. 2018d. Timor-Leste Systematic Country Diagnostic: Pathways for a New Economy and Sustainable Livelihoods. Washington, DC: The World Bank Group. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/524131528837983427/Timor-Leste-Systematic-Country-Diagnostic-Pathways-for-a-New-Economy-and-Sustainable-Livelihoods.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mats Lundahl .

Appendix: A Model of the Agricultural Household in East Timor

Appendix: A Model of the Agricultural Household in East Timor

The simple model of farm household behavior below intends to shed some light on the question of whether agricultural ‘entrepreneurs’ will seize the opportunities offered by the market.Footnote 212 In this model, households produce food and a cash crop (which they do not consume themselves) on a given land area. The consumption and production decisions are hence interdependent. The households maximize their utility given the relative prices of cash crops, food crops and purchased goods.Footnote 213 (The price of purchased goods is used as the numéraire, that is, the prices of other goods can be measured in terms of the number of units of purchased goods they can buy.) Utility maximization yields an equilibrium in which the households distribute the available time between production and leisure, the time devoted to production between cash crops and food production, and the resulting income between the consumption of food and purchased goods, all according to their preferences and the prevailing relative prices. It also determines how much food is sold on the market.

The utility function of the agricultural household is

$$ \mathrm{U}=\mathrm{U}\left(\mathrm{F},\mathrm{M},{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{e}}\right) $$
(5.1)

where \( \mathrm{F} \) denotes food, \( \mathrm{M} \) purchased goods and \( {\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{e}} \) leisure.Footnote 214 Utility is positive and diminishing for all arguments of the function.

Food and cash crops are produced using labor (and a fixed quantity of land):

$$ {\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}={\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}\left({\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{f}}\right) $$
(5.2)
$$ {\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}={\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}\left({\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{c}}\right) $$
(5.3)

These production functions display diminishing returns to labor. The total quantity of labor (time) is divided between leisure, food, and cash crop production:

$$ \mathrm{L}={\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{e}}+{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{c}} $$
(5.4)

Households maximize their utility subject to (5.4) and to

$$ {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\mathrm{M}={\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}\left[{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}\left({\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{f}}\right)\hbox{--} \mathrm{F}\right]+{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}}{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}\left({\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{c}}\right) $$
(5.5)

where the p denotes prices. What is available for spending on purchased goods is the sum of the value of food production, minus what is consumed by the household itself, and the value of cash crop production.

Utility maximization yields the following first-order conditions:

$$ {\mathrm{U}}^{\mathrm{M}}\left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right)={\mathrm{U}}^{\mathrm{F}} $$
(5.6)
$$ {\mathrm{U}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{e}}={\mathrm{U}}^{\mathrm{M}}\left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}={\mathrm{U}}^{\mathrm{M}}\left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}} $$
(5.7)

where the superscripts denote first derivatives. In equilibrium, the valuation of a unit of food must be the same at the margin regardless of whether the household chooses to sell it to buy purchased goods or to consume it in the household. Also, at the margin the household must obtain the same satisfaction of a unit of time regardless of whether it is dedicated to leisure, food production, or cash crop production.

The situation is illustrated in Figure 5.6. Beginning with the \( \mathrm{OA} \) curve, this shows the income-leisure tradeoff for the household. The number of hours available is \( \mathrm{OB}. \) Work (as opposed to leisure) is measured leftward in the diagram and income downward. The more hours the household works, the higher is its income, which increases at a decreasing rate. Given the preferences of the household for income and leisure, respectively, it chooses point \( \mathrm{C} \) on the tradeoff, working \( \mathrm{OD} \) hours and taking out \( \mathrm{DB} \) hours of free time. This yields a total income of \( \mathrm{OK}, \) measured in terms of purchased goods.

Fig. 5.6
figure 6

The equilibrium of the farm household

The \( \mathrm{OD} \) hours worked must be distributed between food and cash crop production. If only the latter is chosen, the maximum output will be \( \mathrm{OE}, \) one of the two endpoints on the household’s production possibility curve. If the household specializes in food production instead, the maximum output is given by the other endpoint of the curve, \( \mathrm{OF}. \) The production possibility curve is drawn on the assumption of a given factor endowment and shows the different possible combinations of food and cash crops that can be obtained with the aid of this endowment. The actual choice of production is determined by the relative price of the two crops, as given by the price line \( \mathrm{IJ}. \) This line is tangent to the production possibility curve at \( \mathrm{G}, \) which is where the value of output is maximized at the given prices.

The output combination given by \( \mathrm{G} \) gives a farm household income of \( \mathrm{OI}, \) measured in terms of cash crops, or \( \mathrm{OJ}, \) if we choose to measure in terms of food instead. Given the relative price prevailing between food and purchased goods, this translates into an income of \( \mathrm{OK}, \) in terms of the latter, our numéraire. The only thing that remains to be determined is the consumption of the household, given this income, represented by the budget line \( \mathrm{JK}. \) Given the preferences of the household for the two goods, the consumption point is \( \mathrm{L}, \) where \( \mathrm{ML} \) units of the purchased goods are consumed and \( \mathrm{OM} \) is units of food. This, in turn, leaves a food surplus of \( \mathrm{MH}, \) which is sold in the market.

Farm Household Response to Market Incentives

Next, we use our model to examine the proposition offered by John Conroy: that Timorese farmers may be expected to increase production for any of the following three reasonsFootnote 215:

  1. 1

    increased prices of cash crops,

  2. 2

    increased prices of food crops, and

  3. 3

    reduced prices (increased availability) of goods not manufactured by the farmers but purchased from outside.

In the present chapter, we do not make any assumptions as to where the price changes come from, but they are likely to be intimately connected with, for example, infrastructural development. For example, better roads are likely to increase the net price fetched by farmers both for cash and for food crops while at the same time they should have to pay less for what they buy from the outside.

We next examine the probable effects of each one of these price changes with the aid of our model.

Increased Prices of Cash and Food Crops

Let us begin with what happens when the price of cash crops increases \( \left({\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}}>0\right) \) while the other two prices are kept constant. The price increase serves to rotate the income-leisure tradeoff in Figure 5.6 anti-clockwise, since the value of the marginal product of labor in the production of cash crops increases. For any given labor effort in agriculture, household income will increase. At the same time, leisure will become more expensive in terms of income forgone. We have an income effect and a substitution effect, and it will not be possible to reach a general conclusion of whether more hours will be devoted to agriculture than before or the number of leisure hours will increase. However, if leisure is an inferior good, as hinted by Conroy, the number of hours worked will increase. This is a quite realistic case in a poor economy. Households have plenty of idle time. Should income possibilities improve, it is quite likely that the farm household prefers to work more and not less. Leisure does not even have to be inferior. It is enough that the substitution effect is strong enough to swamp the increased demand for leisure at given prices.

What will happen to the production of the two goods? The first-order condition (5.7) may be rewritten as:

$$ \left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}=\left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}} $$
(5.8)

Differentiating (5.4) yields:

$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}=-\left({\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}+{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{e}}\right) $$
(5.9)

and, from (5.8), allowing \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}} \) to change and keeping \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}} \) and \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}} \) constant (normalizing all three prices = 1, at the outset), we obtain

$$ {{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}+{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}} $$
(5.10)

Combining (5.9) and (5.10) gives us

$$ -\left({{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}+{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}\right){\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}}+{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{e}}>0 $$
(5.11)

provided that \( {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{e}}<0, \) since \( {\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}}>0, \) and the second derivatives of the production functions are negative. By the same token \( {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}} \) must be positive. If the rise in the price of cash crops leads to less leisure, the production of these crops must increase. Even if \( {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{e}} \) is positive, the production of cash crops may increase, if the price rise is large. The production of food crops may increase as well, in the case where the reduction of the hours devoted to leisure exceeds the increase in the number of hours devoted to cash crop production. Finally, what happens to the marketed surplus of food crops is uncertain. The on-farm demand for food will increase if the production of cash crops, and hence income, increases, since the relative price of food and purchased goods remains constant, but food production may also increase.

In the same way as above, it may be demonstrated that an increase in the price of food will lead to increased food production, provided that leisure is reduced or provided that the increase in the price of food is large. What will happen to on-farm consumption and the marketed surplus of food is, however, not clear. When incomes rise in terms of the purchased goods, the farm households will demand more of both these goods and food at given relative prices. However, there is also a substitution effect due to the increase of the relative price of food. This serves to reduce the consumption of food and increase that of purchased goods. The net outcome of this is unclear and will depend on the income elasticity of demand for food products among the farm households themselves.

Normally, we should expect Engel’s Law to operate, that is, when incomes rise, less and less of the income increase will be devoted to food consumption, so that the share of the household budget spent on food will decrease as income increases. In Timor-Leste, however, this is not necessarily the case. Various empirical investigations have shown that households experience a shortage of food between November and April, that is, for some four months every year (cf. Chapter 3). Hence, given the low-income level and the large share of the population living in poverty, it is far from certain that Engel’s Law is operative. It is not possible to rule out the possibility that an increase in the price of food will lead to a reduction of the marketed surplus.

Cheaper Purchased Goods

Finally, we investigate whether a cheapening of the goods that the farm households purchase from the outside will serve as a stimulus to increased production and sales (in the case of food). Again, we differentiate (5.8) but this time holding \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}} \) and \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}} \) constant, while allowing \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}} \) to fall. This yields

$$ {{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}-{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}-{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}} $$
(5.12)

In equilibrium, the value of the marginal product of labor in food production must equal that in cash crop production (remembering that we have normalized all prices = 1 at the outset). Hence the second terms on both sides of the equality sign in (5.12) are equal. What remains is

$$ {{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{LL}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{LL}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}} $$
(5.13)

Either the production of food and cash crops will both increase or both decrease. Rewriting (5.9) as

$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{e}}=-\left({\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}\right) $$
(5.14)

shows that the crucial determinant here is what happens to leisure as purchased goods become cheaper. Since we have chosen the price of purchased goods as our numéraire, making these goods cheaper amounts to increasing farm household income. The income-leisure tradeoff in Figure 5.6 will rotate anti-clockwise, exactly when the price of cash crops or food increases. Once more, we have an income effect and a substitution effect, and if the net outcome of these is to reduce leisure, the production possibility curve will shift outward and the production of both cash and food crops will increase. In the opposite case, it will fall. Again, what will happen to the marketed surplus of food crops is not certain. The same considerations as before apply.

The Importance of Outside Alternatives

So far, we have considered farm households with no options to work outside of agriculture. The household survey carried out in 2001, however, reported two significant findings: (1) among the individuals who were in the labor force, those belonging to households whose heads were limited to farm employment were considerably poorer than when the heads worked in wage employment, household business, or other outside ventures and (2) almost 70 percent of all Timorese belonged to families with no or only small possibilities of obtaining income from outside agriculture.Footnote 216

This clearly points to the desirability of creating employment outside the agricultural sector. The conclusion is supported by later empirical evidence as well. The 2011 survey of coffee growers in Ermera stressed that ‘In the current rural economy, almost the only viable path out of extreme poverty is to find non-agricultural labour income’ and that ‘It appears as if the less poor households are able to achieve their higher incomes largely from labour income—roles such as teachers, drivers, security guards etc.’Footnote 217

In the short run, outside employment could for example take the form of public works during the off-peak season in agriculture. In the longer run, a private sector will develop. Smallholders in the Third World often derive their income from a variety of sources, and this serves to increase their standard of living. This finding can easily be incorporated into our model. In Figure 5.7, the possibility of earning a given outside wage equal to \( \mathrm{w}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}, \) when measured in terms of purchased goods, has been incorporated. The household keeps working in agriculture until the value of the marginal product of labor there falls to the level given by the constant outside wage. At this point \( \left(\mathrm{B}\right), \) the income-leisure curve becomes a straight line. Thereafter, the remaining hours worked are spent in wage employment, up to point \( \mathrm{C}. \) The income from this must be added to that from farm work. Hence, the total income line will lie outside \( \mathrm{IJ} \) and outside the budget line \( \mathrm{JK}. \) The incorporation of outside employment changes our conclusions.

Fig. 5.7
figure 7

An increase in the relative price of cash crops

Let us begin with the case of increased prices of cash crops. When \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}} \) increases, as before, the income-leisure tradeoff rotates anti-clockwise, from \( \mathrm{OA} \) to \( {\mathrm{OA}}_1. \) The value of the marginal product increases in agriculture, and more hours will be worked there. Outside work will no longer begin at \( \mathrm{B} \) (or \( \mathrm{D} \)) but at \( {\mathrm{B}}_1 \) (or \( {\mathrm{D}}_1 \)). The total number of hours worked will, however, decrease. Provided that leisure is not an inferior good, points \( {\mathrm{C}}_1 \) and \( {\mathrm{E}}_1 \) lie to the right of \( \mathrm{C} \) and \( \mathrm{E}, \) respectively, as long as some outside work takes place both before and after the price increase. The reason is that the substitution effect disappears. Leisure is no more expensive at the margin after the price increase than before, since the marginal valuation is given by the wage rate and not by the price of cash crops, and the wage rate does not change. All that remains is the income effect, and this makes for increased leisure. Income increases as well but as a result of the reallocation of work hours between wage labor and farm work. Should leisure on the other hand be inferior, \( {\mathrm{C}}_1 \) will be to the left of \( \mathrm{C} \) and \( {\mathrm{E}}_1 \) to the left of \( \mathrm{E}. \) Work will increase both inside and outside agriculture, at the expense of leisure.

Turning to the allocation of work hours between cash and food crop production, (5.8) may now be rewritten as

$$ \left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}=\left({\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right){{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}=\mathrm{w}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}} $$
(5.15)

where the wage rate is given in terms of purchased goods. Also, the available labor time has to be distributed among leisure, crop production, and outside work. This changes (5.4) to

$$ \mathrm{L}={\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{e}}+{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{f}}+{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{c}}+{\mathrm{L}}_{\mathrm{w}} $$
(5.16)

Differentiating (5.15) when \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}} \) changes and the other two prices and the wage rate in terms of purchased goods \( \left(\mathrm{w}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}\right) \) is held as constant (with \( {\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{f}}={\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{c}}={\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}}=1 \) at the outset) yields

$$ {{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}+{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}}=0 $$
(5.17)

or

$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}=-\left({{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}/{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}\right){\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{c}}>0 $$
(5.18)

and

$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}=0 $$
(5.19)

The output of cash crops increases while that of food remains constant. Here, price incentives work unequivocally, and since all cash crops are sold in the market, outside sales will increase as well. The marketed surplus of foodstuffs, on the other hand, will be reduced. Farm household income has increased, and both food prices and the price of purchased goods remain constant. Hence, only the income effect remains. The demand for both food and purchased goods among farm households will increase, but food output remains constant. The marketed surplus of food must therefore shrink.

The analysis is analogous for the case of increased food prices. There will be more leisure and larger food production, while cash crop production will remain constant. In this case, however, we don’t know with certainty what will happen to the marketed surplus of food. The price of the latter good increases and the substitution effect will be reintroduced. Possibly, on-farm consumption will be reduced, and more food will be sold outside.

The conclusions will change also when the price of purchased goods is reduced (but \( \mathrm{w}/{\mathrm{p}}_{\mathrm{m}} \) remains constant). The income-leisure tradeoff again rotates anti-clockwise, more leisure is enjoyed, and less work takes place outside the farm and more inside. (5.12), in turn, becomes

$$ {{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}-{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}={{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}-{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}{\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}=0 $$
(5.20)

and

$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{c}}=\left({{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}}/{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{c}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}\right){\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}>0 $$
(5.21)
$$ {\mathrm{dL}}_{\mathrm{f}}=\left({{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}}/{{\mathrm{q}}_{\mathrm{f}}}^{\mathrm{L}\mathrm{L}}\right){\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}>0 $$
(5.22)

\( {\mathrm{dp}}_{\mathrm{m}}<0, \) so the production of both cash crops and food will increase. The farm households will increase their consumption of purchased goods and possibly, but not with certainty, that of food as well, since food becomes more expensive in terms of purchased goods. However, since the production of foodstuffs increases as well, the net result of the cheapening of purchased goods may be increased leisure, at the expense of outside work (provided that leisure is a superior good), increased on-farm consumption of food, and increased sales not only of cash crops but also of food.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Lundahl, M., Sjöholm, F. (2019). The Agricultural Sector. In: The Creation of the East Timorese Economy. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-22052-5_5

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-22052-5_5

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-22051-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-22052-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics