Skip to main content

Discretion and Blame Avoidance

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Discretion and the Quest for Controlled Freedom

Abstract

This chapter explores discretion from a blame-avoidance perspective, focusing on the idea that there is a trade-off between discretion—defined as the ability or duty to exercise judgement—and blame avoidance. It argues that the idea of such a trade-off is plausible up to a point, but that it is limited in at least two ways. One is that there are some half-way houses between discretion and blame avoidance (including pooling of discretion to share blame, partial or apparent delegation to diffuse or transfer blame and the validation of discretion by others), though half-way houses of that kind are likely to be precarious and unstable. The other is that any trade-off between discretion and blame avoidance is liable to break down, particularly in times of crisis, to the point where officeholders come to incur blame for failing to exercise discretion.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 119.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 159.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Chadwick (1854: 190) saw too many public officeholders as following the fatalistic maxim: ‘Fungi officio taliter qualiter; numquam male loqui de superioribus; sinere insanum mundum vadere quo vult […]’ (‘Perform your duties tolerably, or so-so; never speak ill of superiors; allow the mad world to go where it wants […]’).

  2. 2.

    However, the organization continued to be funded up to the early 1980s by interest on deposits placed with it by private banks and is said to have continued to enjoy a degree of independence from the government in its regulatory capacity (Reid 1988: 205–6).

  3. 3.

    And those monetary decisions may themselves be framed or indeed pre-empted by the fiscal decisions or non-decisions made by elected politicians.

  4. 4.

    Franklin’s utterance of this famous dictum is disputed by historians and the saying is anyway traceable to much earlier sources.

  5. 5.

    Nevertheless the NAO chose to accept this role, and indeed in 2006 also accepted another role that might be interpreted as having ‘blame shield’ characteristics, namely that of ‘sleaze czar’ (as the role was dubbed) or, more precisely, independent adviser on ministerial conflicts of interest (Hencke 2006).

References

  • Arendt, H. (1963). Eichmann in Jerusalem: A report on the banality of evil. New York: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentham, J. (1843). The works of Jeremy Bentham (published under the superintendence of his executor, John Bowring, Vol. 6). Edinburgh: William Tait.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blancheton, B. (2016). Central Bank independence in a historical perspective: Myth, lessons and a new model. Economic Modelling, 52(Part A), 101–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Budd, A. (1999). Learning from the wise people. The Manchester School, supplement 1999 1463–6786, 36–48.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chadwick, E. (1854). Papers relating to the reorganization of the civil service. London: HMSO.

    Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, K. (2016). Kind of blue: A political memoir. London: Pan Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crozier, M. (1964). The bureaucratic phenomenon. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunleavy, P.J. (1991). Democracy, bureaucracy and public choice: Economic explanations in Political Science. New York: Harvester-Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, K.E. (1984). The feminist case against bureaucracy. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1982). Legislative choice of regulatory reform: Legal process or administrative process? Public Choice, 39(1), 33–66.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M. (1986). Legislator uncertainty, legislator control and the delegation of legislative power. Journal of Law, Economics and Organization, 2(1), 133–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gusterson, H. (2016). Drone: Remote control warfare. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, C., Scott, C. & Hood, C. (2000). Telecommunications regulation: Culture, chaos and interdependence inside the regulatory process. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Halliday, J. (2012, 19 December). Pollard Report: George Entwistle ‘did not read emails’ about Jimmy Savile. The Guardian. Retrieved July, 2017, from https://www.theguardian.com/media/2012/dec/19/pollard-report-george-entwistle-jimmy-savile.

  • Hencke, D. (2006, 24 March). Blair names audit chief as anti-sleaze adviser. The Guardian. Retrieved August, 2017, from https://www.theguardian.com/politics/2006/mar/24/uk.labour.

  • Hood, C. (2011). The blame game: Spin, bureaucracy and self-preservation in government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C. & Himaz, R. (2017). A century of fiscal squeeze politics: A hundred years of austerity, politics and bureaucracy in Britain. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C. & Mackenzie, W. (1975). Appendix III: The problem of classifying institutions. In D. Hague, W. Mackenzie & A. Barker (Eds), Public policy and private interests: The institutions of compromise (pp. 409–423). London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C., Scott, C., James, O., Jones, G.W. & Travers, T. (1999). Regulation inside government: Waste-watchers, quality police and sleaze-busters. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C., Rothstein, H. & Baldwin, R. (2001). The government of risk: Understanding risk regulation regimes. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hood, C., Heald, D. & Himaz, R. (Eds) (2014). When the party’s over: The politics of fiscal squeeze in perspective. Oxford: Oxford University Press for the British Academy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hume, L.J. (1981). Bentham and bureaucracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaffash, J. (2010, 17 May). Mixed reaction to Office of Budget responsibility. Public Finance. Retrieved August, 2017, from http://www.publicfinance.co.uk/news/2010/05/mixed-reaction-office-budget-responsibility.

  • Kaufman, H. (1960). The forest ranger: A study of administrative behaviour. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • King, D. & Peters, B.G. (1994). The United States. Ch 9 in C. Hood, C. & B.G. Peters (Eds), Rewards at the top: A comparative study of high public office (pp. 146–165). London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindblom, C. (1965). The intelligence of democracy: Decision-making through mutual adjustment. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lipsky, M. (1980). Street-level bureaucracy. Dilemmas of the individual in public service. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, J. (2005). Outsourcing torture. New Yorker. Magazine, February 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meier, K.J. & Rutherford, A. (2017). The politics of African-American education: Representation, partisanship and educational equity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moynihan, D.P. (1969). Maximum feasible misunderstanding: Community action in the war on poverty. New York: Collier Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • OECD (2010). Making reform happen: Lessons from OECD countries. Paris: OECD.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pierson, P. (1994). Dismantling the welfare state: Reagan, Thatcher and the politics of retrenchment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pifer, A. (1967). The quasi nongovernmental organization (Reprinted from the 1967 Annual report of the Carnegie Corporation). New York: Carnegie Corporation of New York.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, P. (2016). Portfolio budgeting: A new strategy for budgeting. Statement for hearing before the Committee on the Budget, US Senate. Retrieved August, 2017, from https://www.budget.senate.gov/imo/media/doc/senate-budget-test-april%2D%2D%2D%2Dfinal-Posner.pdf.

  • Power, M. (1994). The audit explosion. London: Demos.

    Google Scholar 

  • Power, M. (1997). The audit society: Rituals of verification. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prasser, S. (1985). Public inquiries in Australia: An overview. Australian Journal of Public Administration, XL(1), 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reid, M. (1988). All-change at the City. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Resodihardjo, S. (2009). Crisis and change in British and Dutch prison services: Understanding crisis-Reform processes. Burlington, VT: Ashgate.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rhodes, G. (1975). Committees of inquiry. London: George Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R. (1990). Inheritance before choice in public policy. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 2(3), 263–291.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R. & Davies, P. (1994). Inheritance in public policy: Change without choice in Britain. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rose, R. & Karran, T. (1987). Taxation by political inertia. London: Allen and Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Silberman, B.S. (1993). Cages of reason: The rise of the rational state in France, Japan, the United States and Great Britain. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sulitzeanu-Kenan, R. (2007). Scything the grass: Agenda setting consequences of appointing public inquiries in the UK. A longitudinal analysis. Policy and Politics, 35(4), 629–650.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weaver, K. (1986). The politics of blame avoidance. Journal of Public Policy, 6(4), 371–398.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weaver, R.K. (1988). Automatic government: The politics of indexation. Washington, DC: Brookings.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wildavsky, A. (1964). The politics of the budgetary process. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, P. (1984). ‘A Bankers’ Ramp’? Financiers and the British political crisis of August 1931. English Historical Review, 99(393), 770–806.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiseman, E. (2017, 8 June). ‘Disgusting’: Outrage as parking wardens issue £130 fines to cars caught up in London Bridge attack. The Telegraph. Retrieved July, 2017, from http://www.telegraph.co.uk/cars/news/traffic-wardens-issue-terror-tickets-motorists-whose-cars-stranded/.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Christopher Hood .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2020 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hood, C. (2020). Discretion and Blame Avoidance. In: Evans, T., Hupe, P. (eds) Discretion and the Quest for Controlled Freedom. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-19566-3_3

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics