Skip to main content

The Relevance of Richard A. Easterlin’s Groundbreaking Work. A Historical Perspective

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Economics of Happiness

Abstract

The Easterlin Paradox emerged within a particular historical context; economics moved from an early interest in happiness during the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries to its complete neglect during the first decades of the twentieth century. Due to this neglect economics faced serious limitations to address well-being issues and to contribute to happiness in societies. The chapter presents the evolution of economics in order to show why Richard A. Easterlin’s pioneer work in happiness and economics is groundbreaking; in fact, it constitutes the foundation of a new area in economics: Happiness economics. The chapter analyzes the emergence of happiness economics as well as its consequences and contributions to economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

General References

  • Abramovitz, M. (1959). The welfare interpretation of secular trends in national income and product. In The allocation of economic resources: Essays in honor of Bernard Francis Haley (pp. 1–22). Stanford: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. G. D. (1933). On the marginal utility of money and its application. Economica, 40(May), 186–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Allen, R. G. D. (1935). A note on the determinateness of the utility function. Review of Economic Studies, 2, 155–158.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aristotle. (2009). The Nichomachean ethics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentham, J. (1780). An introduction to the principles of morals and legislation. Mineola: Dover Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bharadwaj, K. (1972). Marshall on Pigou’s wealth and welfare. Economica, 39(153), 32–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruni, L. (2006). Civil happiness, economics and human flourishing in historical perspective. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bruni, L., & Guala, F. (2001). Vilfredo Pareto and the epistemological foundations of choice theory. History of Political Economy, 33, 21–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collard, D. (2003). Research on well-being: Some advice from Jeremy Bentham (WeD Working paper 02). University of Bath, United Kingdom.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coyle, D. (2015). GDP. A brief but affectionate history. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. A. (1973). Does money buy happiness? The Public Interest, 30, 3–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (1974). Does economic growth improve the human lot? Some empirical evidence. In P. A. David & M. W. Reder (Eds.), Nations and households in economic growth (pp. 89–125). New York: Academic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2001). Income and happiness: Towards a unified theory. Economic Journal, 111(473), 465.484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2004). The reluctant economist: Perspectives on economics, economic history, and demography. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Easterlin, R. (2010). Happiness, growth, and the life cycle. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edgeworth, F. Y. (1881). Mathematical psychics: An essay on the application of mathematics to the moral sciences. London: C. Kegan Paul & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards, J. M. (2009). Joyful economists: Remarks on the history of economics and psychology from the happiness studies perspective. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 32(4), 611–613.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1892). Mathematical investigations in the theory of value and prices. Transaction of the Connecticut Academy, 9, 1–124.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, I. (1911). The purchasing power of money: Its determination and relation to credit interest and crises. New York: MacMillan Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman, M. (1953). The methodology of positive economics. In Essays in positive economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fromm, E. (1976). To have or to be. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heilbroner, R. L. (1977, March 3). The false promise of growth. New York review of books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R. (1939). The foundations of welfare economics. The Economic Journal, 49(196), 696–712.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hicks, J. R., & Allen, R. G. D. (1934). A reconsideration of the theory of value. Parts I & II. Economica, 1, 52–76; 2: 196–219.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hirsch, F. (1976). Social limits to growth. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hobson, J. A. (1929). Wealth and life: A study in values. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jevons, W. S. (1871). The theory of political economy. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1939). Welfare propositions of economics and inter-personal comparisons of utility. Economic Journal, 49(195), 549–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Keynes, J. M. (1931). Essays in persuasion. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, F. H. (1944). Realism and relevance in the theory of demand. Journal of Political Economy, 52, 289–318.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1948). National income: A new version. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 30(3), 151–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lange, O. (1934). The determinateness of the utility function. Review of Economic Studies, 1, 218–225.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Malthus, T. (1798). An essay on the principle of population. London: J. Johnson.

    Google Scholar 

  • McMahon, D. (2006). Happiness: A history. New York: Grove Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pareto, V. [1909] (1971). Manual of political economy. New York: Kelley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. (2005). Paradoxes of happiness in economics. In L. Bruni & P. L. Porta (Eds.), Economics & happiness: Framing the analysis (pp. 336–343). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1912). Wealth and welfare. London: MacMillan & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pigou, A. C. (1920). The economics of welfare. London: MacMillan and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Robbins, L. (1932). An essay on the nature and significance of economic science. London: MacMillan & Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rojas, M. (2017). The subjective object of well-being studies. In G. Brulé & F. Maggino (Eds.), Metrics of subjective well-being: Limits and improvements (pp. 43–62). Cham: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rojas, M., & Veenhoven, R. (2013). Contentment and affect in the estimation of happiness. Social Indicators Research, 110(2), 415–431.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1937). A note on measurement of utility. Review of Economic Studies, 4, 155–161.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1938a). The empirical implications of utility analysis. Econometrica, 6, 344–356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1938b). The numerical representation of ordered classifications and the concept of utility. Review of Economic Studies, 6, 65–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1947). Foundations of economic analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, P. A. (1950). Probability and the attempts to measure utility. Economic Review, 1, 167–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmidt, T., & Weber, C. E. (2008). On the origins of ordinal utility: Andreas Heinrich Voigt and the mathematicians. History of Political Economy, 40, 481–510.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scitovsky, T. (1976). The joyless economy: An inquiry into human satisfaction and consumer dissatisfaction. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sim, B., & Diener, E. (2018). Accounts of psychological and emotional well-being for policy purposes. In E. Diener, S. Oishi, & L. Tay (Eds.), Handbook of well-being. Salt Lake City: DEF Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. [1759] (1767). The theory of moral sentiments. Edinburgh: A. Miller/A. Kincaid/J. Bell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. [1776] (1937). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of Nations. New York: Modern Library.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1950). The development of utility theory I. The Journal of Political Economy, 58(4), 307–327.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J., & Becker, G. S. (1977). De Gustibus non est Disputandum. The American Economic Review, 67(2), 76–90.

    Google Scholar 

  • van Praag, B. M. S., & Frijters, P. (1999). The measurement of welfare and well-being; the Leyden approach. In D. Kahneman, E. Diener, & N. Schwarz (Eds.), Foundations of hedonic psychology: Scientific perspectives on enjoyment and suffering (pp. 413–433). New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. (1925). The utility concept in value theory and its critics. The Journal of Political Economy, 33(6), 638–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Voigt, A. [1893] (2008). Number and measure in economics. In T. Schmidt, & C. E. Weber (Eds.), On the origins of ordinal utility: Andreas Heinrich Voigt and the Mathematicians, History of Political Economy, 40, 502–504.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walsh, C. M. (1901). The measurement of general exchange-value. New York: MacMillan Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wolfe, A. (1931). On the content of welfare. American Economic Review, 21(2), 207–221.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zeuthen, F. (1937). On the determinateness of the utility function. Review of Economic Studies, 4, 236–239.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I would like to acknowledge the assistance of Humberto Charles Leija in reviewing and editing all chapters in the book.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Rojas, M. (2019). The Relevance of Richard A. Easterlin’s Groundbreaking Work. A Historical Perspective. In: Rojas, M. (eds) The Economics of Happiness. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-15835-4_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics