The Tragedy of the Commons: A Theoretical Update
- 249 Downloads
Abstract
The theory of common property resources traces the overexploitation of natural resources to the absence of ownership rights. Garrett Hardin argues such resources can be managed, if at all, by autocratic government because individuals or local communities cannot cooperate to manage them. In recent decades the theory has undergone substantial elaboration. There are many examples of societies around the world that do manage resources using local level rules, which theorists have described in detail. Another set of theorists using game theory have shown when and where individuals can cooperate to conserve resources. Others have developed a new conception of property rights, noting that different types of property produce several kinds of goods. Still others point out that that both the commons and private property can be traced to differing levels of economic defendability. Recently, analysis of the commons has gone beyond natural resources to other kinds of commons, such as knowledge.
Keywords
Resource management Tragedy of the commons Theory of common property Cooperation Garrett HardinReferences
- Acheson, J. M. (1989). Management of common property resources. In S. Plattner (Ed.), Economic anthropology (pp. 351–378). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
- Acheson, J. M. (2003). Capturing the commons: Devising institutions to manage the Maine lobster industry. Hanover, NH: University Press of New England.Google Scholar
- Acheson, J. M. (2015). Private land and common oceans: A cross-cultural analysis of the evolution of property rights. Current Anthropology, 56(1), 28–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Acheson, J. M., & Acheson, J. (2010). Maine land: Private property and hunting commons. International Journal of the Commons, 4(1), 552–570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Acheson, J. M., & Gardner, R. (2010). Evolution of conservation rules and norms in the Maine lobster fishery. Ocean and Coastal Management, 53(9), 524–534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Agrawal, A. (2002). Common resources and institutional sustainability. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 41–85). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
- Anderson, T., & Hill, P. J. (1998). From free grass to fences: Transforming the commons of the American west. In J. Baden & D. Noonan (Eds.), Managing the commons (2nd ed., pp. 119–134). Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
- Aswani, S. (2002). Assessing the effects of changing demographic and consumption patterns on sea tenure regimes in Roviana Lagoon, Solomon Islands. Ambio, 31(4), 272–284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Austin, P. (2003). Roxanne Quimby purchases high priority 24,000 acre township east of Baxter park. Maine Environmental News (24 November).Google Scholar
- Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
- Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1996). Halting degradation of natural resources: Is there a role for rural communities? New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
- Berkes, F. (1985). Fishermen and the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Environmental Conservation, 12, 199–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Berkes, F., & Farver, M. (1989). Introduction and overview of common property resources. In F. Berkes (Ed.), Common property resources: Ecology and community-based sustainable development. London: Belhaven Press.Google Scholar
- Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
- Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V., & Bishop, R. C. (1975). Common property as a concept. Natural Resources Journal, 15, 713–727.Google Scholar
- Cornell Law Review. 2010. Cornell Law Review 95(4). Retrieved September 12, 2017, from http://cornelllawreview.org/issue/volume-95-issue-4/
- Dixit, A. K., & Skeath, S. (2004). Games of strategy. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
- Dyson-Hudson, R., & Smith, E. A. (1978). Human territoriality: An ecological reassessment. American Anthropologist, 80(1), 21–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Edwards, V. M., & Steins, N. A. (1996). Developing an analytical framework for a multiple use commons. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 10(3), 347–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Elster, J. (1989). The cement of society: A survey of social order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Feeny, D., Berkes, F., McCay, B., & Acheson, J. (1990). The tragedy of the commons 22 years later. Human Ecology, 18(1), 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90, 980–994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Hagen, J., Irland, L., & Whitman, A. (2005). Changing timberland ownership in the northern forests and implications for biodiversity (Report #MCCS-FCP2005-1). Brunswick, ME: Manomet Center for Conservation Sciences.Google Scholar
- Hardin, G., & Baden, J. (Eds.). (1977). Managing the commons. New York: W.H. Freeman.Google Scholar
- Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. (2005). ‘Economic Man’ in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28, 795–855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Henrich, J. (2000). Decision making, cultural transmission and adaptation in economic anthropology. In J. Ensminger (Ed.), Theory in economic anthropology (pp. 251–295). Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press.Google Scholar
- Hess, C. (2012). The unfolding of the knowledge commons. St Antony’s International Review, 1, 13–24.Google Scholar
- Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (2012). Understanding knowledge as a commons: From theory to practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
- Kaltenborn, B., Haaland, H., & Sandell, K. (2001). The public right of access: Some challenges to sustainable tourism development in Scandinavia. Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 9(5), 417–433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Kopelman, S., Weber, M., & Messick, D. (2002). Factors influencing cooperation in commons dilemmas: A review of experimental psychological research. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 113–156). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
- Lesorogol, C. (2008). Contesting the commons: Privatizing pastoral land in Kenya. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Nowak, M., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, 1291–1297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ostrom, E. (2000). Reformulating the commons. Swiss Political Science Review, 6(1), 29–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ostrom, E. (2003). How types of goods and property right jointly affect collective action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15(3), 239–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Rules, games and common-pool resources. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Pinkerton, E., & Weinstein, M. (1995). Fisheries that work: Sustainability through community based management. Vancouver, BC: David Suzuki Foundation.Google Scholar
- Poteete, A., Janssen, M., & Ostrom, E. (2010). Working together: Collective action, the commons and multiple methods in practice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Richerson, P., Boyd, R., & Paciotti, B. (2002). An evolutionary theory of commons management. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 403–442). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
- Sambides, Jr., N. (2016). Roxanne Quimby transfers 87,000 acres planned for national monument to US government. Bangor Daily News (23 August).Google Scholar
- Schlager, E., & Ostrom, E. (1992). Property rights regimes and natural resources: A conceptual analysis. Land Economics, 68(3), 249–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Short, C. (2008). The traditional commons of England and Wales in the 21st century: Meeting old and new challenges. International Journal of the Commons, 2(2), 191–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- Taylor, M. (1990). Cooperation and rationality: Notes on the collective action problem and its solutions. In K. S. Cook & M. Levi (Eds.), The limits of rationality (pp. 222–249). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
- von Benda-Beckmann, F., von Benda-Beckmann, K., & Wiber, M. (2006). The properties of property. In F. von Benda-Beckmann, K. von Benda-Beckmann, & M. Wiber (Eds.), Changing properties of property (pp. 1–39). New York: Berghahn Books.Google Scholar
- Wolf, E. (1955). Types of Latin American peasantry: A preliminary discussion. American Anthropologist, 57(3), 452–470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar