Advertisement

The Tragedy of the Commons: A Theoretical Update

  • James M. AchesonEmail author
Chapter
  • 249 Downloads
Part of the Studies in Human Ecology and Adaptation book series (STHE, volume 11)

Abstract

The theory of common property resources traces the overexploitation of natural resources to the absence of ownership rights. Garrett Hardin argues such resources can be managed, if at all, by autocratic government because individuals or local communities cannot cooperate to manage them. In recent decades the theory has undergone substantial elaboration. There are many examples of societies around the world that do manage resources using local level rules, which theorists have described in detail. Another set of theorists using game theory have shown when and where individuals can cooperate to conserve resources. Others have developed a new conception of property rights, noting that different types of property produce several kinds of goods. Still others point out that that both the commons and private property can be traced to differing levels of economic defendability. Recently, analysis of the commons has gone beyond natural resources to other kinds of commons, such as knowledge.

Keywords

Resource management Tragedy of the commons Theory of common property Cooperation Garrett Hardin 

References

  1. Acheson, J. M. (1989). Management of common property resources. In S. Plattner (Ed.), Economic anthropology (pp. 351–378). Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  2. Acheson, J. M. (2003). Capturing the commons: Devising institutions to manage the Maine lobster industry. Hanover, NH: University Press of New England.Google Scholar
  3. Acheson, J. M. (2015). Private land and common oceans: A cross-cultural analysis of the evolution of property rights. Current Anthropology, 56(1), 28–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  4. Acheson, J. M., & Acheson, J. (2010). Maine land: Private property and hunting commons. International Journal of the Commons, 4(1), 552–570.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Acheson, J. M., & Gardner, R. (2010). Evolution of conservation rules and norms in the Maine lobster fishery. Ocean and Coastal Management, 53(9), 524–534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  6. Agrawal, A. (2002). Common resources and institutional sustainability. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 41–85). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  7. Anderson, T., & Hill, P. J. (1998). From free grass to fences: Transforming the commons of the American west. In J. Baden & D. Noonan (Eds.), Managing the commons (2nd ed., pp. 119–134). Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Aswani, S. (2002). Assessing the effects of changing demographic and consumption patterns on sea tenure regimes in Roviana Lagoon, Solomon Islands. Ambio, 31(4), 272–284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Austin, P. (2003). Roxanne Quimby purchases high priority 24,000 acre township east of Baxter park. Maine Environmental News (24 November).Google Scholar
  10. Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  11. Baland, J.-M., & Platteau, J.-P. (1996). Halting degradation of natural resources: Is there a role for rural communities? New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Berkes, F. (1985). Fishermen and the ‘tragedy of the commons’. Environmental Conservation, 12, 199–206.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  13. Berkes, F., & Farver, M. (1989). Introduction and overview of common property resources. In F. Berkes (Ed.), Common property resources: Ecology and community-based sustainable development. London: Belhaven Press.Google Scholar
  14. Camerer, C. F. (2003). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  15. Charness, G., & Rabin, M. (2002). Understanding social preferences with simple tests. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(3), 817–869.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  16. Ciriacy-Wantrup, S. V., & Bishop, R. C. (1975). Common property as a concept. Natural Resources Journal, 15, 713–727.Google Scholar
  17. Cornell Law Review. 2010. Cornell Law Review 95(4). Retrieved September 12, 2017, from http://cornelllawreview.org/issue/volume-95-issue-4/
  18. Dixit, A. K., & Skeath, S. (2004). Games of strategy. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
  19. Dyson-Hudson, R., & Smith, E. A. (1978). Human territoriality: An ecological reassessment. American Anthropologist, 80(1), 21–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  20. Edwards, V. M., & Steins, N. A. (1996). Developing an analytical framework for a multiple use commons. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 10(3), 347–383.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Elster, J. (1989). The cement of society: A survey of social order. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  22. Feeny, D., Berkes, F., McCay, B., & Acheson, J. (1990). The tragedy of the commons 22 years later. Human Ecology, 18(1), 1–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  23. Fehr, E., & Gächter, S. (2000). Cooperation and punishment in public goods experiments. American Economic Review, 90, 980–994.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  24. Hagen, J., Irland, L., & Whitman, A. (2005). Changing timberland ownership in the northern forests and implications for biodiversity (Report #MCCS-FCP2005-1). Brunswick, ME: Manomet Center for Conservation Sciences.Google Scholar
  25. Hardin, G., & Baden, J. (Eds.). (1977). Managing the commons. New York: W.H. Freeman.Google Scholar
  26. Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Henrich, J., Boyd, R., Bowles, S., Camerer, C., Fehr, E., Gintis, H., et al. (2005). ‘Economic Man’ in cross-cultural perspective: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. Behavioral and Brain Sciences, 28, 795–855.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Henrich, J. (2000). Decision making, cultural transmission and adaptation in economic anthropology. In J. Ensminger (Ed.), Theory in economic anthropology (pp. 251–295). Walnut Creek, CA: Altamira Press.Google Scholar
  29. Hess, C. (2012). The unfolding of the knowledge commons. St Antony’s International Review, 1, 13–24.Google Scholar
  30. Hess, C., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (2012). Understanding knowledge as a commons: From theory to practice. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
  31. Kaltenborn, B., Haaland, H., & Sandell, K. (2001). The public right of access: Some challenges to sustainable tourism development in Scandinavia. Journal of Sustainable Tourism, 9(5), 417–433.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  32. Kopelman, S., Weber, M., & Messick, D. (2002). Factors influencing cooperation in commons dilemmas: A review of experimental psychological research. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 113–156). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  33. Lesorogol, C. (2008). Contesting the commons: Privatizing pastoral land in Kenya. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  34. Nowak, M., & Sigmund, K. (2005). Evolution of indirect reciprocity. Nature, 437, 1291–1297.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  35. Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the commons: The evolution of institutions for collective action. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  36. Ostrom, E. (2000). Reformulating the commons. Swiss Political Science Review, 6(1), 29–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  37. Ostrom, E. (2003). How types of goods and property right jointly affect collective action. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 15(3), 239–270.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Rules, games and common-pool resources. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  39. Pinkerton, E., & Weinstein, M. (1995). Fisheries that work: Sustainability through community based management. Vancouver, BC: David Suzuki Foundation.Google Scholar
  40. Poteete, A., Janssen, M., & Ostrom, E. (2010). Working together: Collective action, the commons and multiple methods in practice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  41. Richerson, P., Boyd, R., & Paciotti, B. (2002). An evolutionary theory of commons management. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolsak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. U. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 403–442). Washington, DC: National Academy Press.Google Scholar
  42. Sambides, Jr., N. (2016). Roxanne Quimby transfers 87,000 acres planned for national monument to US government. Bangor Daily News (23 August).Google Scholar
  43. Schlager, E., & Ostrom, E. (1992). Property rights regimes and natural resources: A conceptual analysis. Land Economics, 68(3), 249–262.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  44. Short, C. (2008). The traditional commons of England and Wales in the 21st century: Meeting old and new challenges. International Journal of the Commons, 2(2), 191–221.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  45. Taylor, M. (1990). Cooperation and rationality: Notes on the collective action problem and its solutions. In K. S. Cook & M. Levi (Eds.), The limits of rationality (pp. 222–249). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
  46. von Benda-Beckmann, F., von Benda-Beckmann, K., & Wiber, M. (2006). The properties of property. In F. von Benda-Beckmann, K. von Benda-Beckmann, & M. Wiber (Eds.), Changing properties of property (pp. 1–39). New York: Berghahn Books.Google Scholar
  47. Wolf, E. (1955). Types of Latin American peasantry: A preliminary discussion. American Anthropologist, 57(3), 452–470.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Copyright information

© Springer Nature Switzerland AG 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  1. 1.University of MaineOronoUSA

Personalised recommendations