Skip to main content

The History and Evolution of the Development Doctrine, 1950–2017

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics

Abstract

The chapter examines the history and evolution of development doctrine. It suggests that the selection and adoption of a development strategy depend upon three building blocks: (1) the prevailing development objectives which, in turn, are derived from the prevailing view and definition of the development process; (2) the conceptual state of the art regarding the existing body of development theories, hypotheses, models, techniques, and empirical applications; and (3) the underlying data system available to diagnose the existing situation, measure performance, and test hypotheses. Development doctrine is then defined as the body of principles and knowledge resulting from the interrelated complex of these four elements that is accepted by the Development Community at that time. This analytical framework is applied to describe the state of the art that prevailed in each of the five decades (from the 1950s to the 1990s) and in the most recent period 2000 to 2017 to highlight in a systematic fashion the changing conception of the development process. Over the last 67 years the definition of development and strategies to achieve it, progressed and broadened from the maximization of GDP in the 1950s, to employment creation and the satisfaction of basic needs in the 1970s, to structural adjustment and stabilization in the 1980s and early 1990s, to poverty reduction, followed by sustainable and shared growth that dominated the scene until recently. The evolution in the conception of development culminated with the present broad-based concept of inclusive and sustainable growth. A parallel and similar progression occurred in development theory and in the coverage, comprehensiveness and quality of data and information. While development economics has followed a time path towards more experimental, multidisciplinary and more rigorous and scientific methodology, the present emphasis on microeconomic phenomena and randomized and controlled trials may have detracted researchers from exploring fundamental “big picture” macroeconomic phenomena.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This chapter is a thoroughly revised and greatly expanded version of an earlier paper on ‘The Evolution of the Development, Doctrine, 1950–2005’ in Mavrotas and Shorrocks (2007) Advancing Development Core Themes in Global Economics, published by Palgrave Macmillan. With due acknowledgement of UNU-WIDER in Helsinki which commissioned the earlier study and holds copyright thereon. I am grateful for the valuable comments I received from Kaushik Basu, Alain de Janvry, Ravi Kanbur, Machiko Nissanke and Finn Tarp. I should add the usual disclaimer that the views expressed here are entirely my own.

  2. 2.

    When Robert Solow chaired the American Economic Association’s luncheon in honour of Amartya Sen’s Nobel prize, he mentioned in his introduction that “he did not think that economics had a conscience but that, if it did, Amartya Sen would be its conscience” (my paraphrase).

  3. 3.

    There are two additional reciprocal relationships denoted by arrows in Fig. 3.1. The first one is the interaction between development theories and hypotheses and development models. Models are typically based on theoretical hypotheses, which often are of a partial nature. By integrating various hypotheses into a consistent framework, which the model provides, some new insights may be derived which could lead to a modification of the initial hypotheses. The second bi-directional arrow is the one linking development objectives and data systems. Clearly, the choice of development goals both predetermines the kind of data systems that is required and is affected by it. Many concrete examples of these interrelationships are described and analysed next in the application of the conceptual framework in Fig. 3.1 to the six periods between 1950 and 2017.

  4. 4.

    In particular, certain conceptual and theoretical contributions may have been formulated before they became part of the conventional wisdom. An example of this is the seminal article of W. A. Lewis (1954), which triggered the economic dualism concept which became a major element of the development paradigm of the 1960s rather than of the 1950s.

  5. 5.

    Also, my career as an active development economist spanned the 67 years covered in this evaluation.

  6. 6.

    Far from originating with ILO, the concept of basic needs and planning for poverty alleviation had already been expressed and formulated very clearly by the Indian planner Pitambar Pant as early as 1962 (see Pant 1974).

  7. 7.

    The Demographic and Health Surveys (DHS) initiated in 1984, undertaken in a large number of developing countries and covering multiple years, have been extensively used by researchers.

  8. 8.

    Sustainable development was the solution to the problems of environmental degradation discussed by the Brundtland Commission in the 1987 report Our Common Future.

  9. 9.

    I would be tempted to use the term ‘experimental science’ instead of ‘experimental discipline’, but I realise that at the present time this would be too much of a stretch.

  10. 10.

    Other disciplines, especially in medicine and public health, had long relied on RCTs in their research so that the paradigm shift in development economics consisted of borrowing an existing methodology from another field.

  11. 11.

    As quoted by Deaton (2010).

  12. 12.

    It is noteworthy that Kaushik Basu as senior vice president and chief economist of the World Bank expressed his reservation of the extent to which RCTs could be generalised at a time when the World Bank was the main user of this approach.

  13. 13.

    The latter are respectively the deputy director and executive director of J-PAL.

  14. 14.

    By extension, the preceding discussion of the three critical issues related to RCTs applies equally to natural experiments.

  15. 15.

    There are some excellent studies of the political economy of development at the national and regional levels such as Basu (2015) on India and Ndulu et al. (2008) on sub-Saharan Africa.

  16. 16.

    Another extremely influential body of research documenting the sharply rising income inequality in the last few decades is by Piketty. It is interesting to note that the remedies recommended by Atkinson (labour power and minimum wage legislation) differ from those of Piketty (taxation and redistribution). While these policies might be effective within the setting of a mature economy, other policies might be called for in a poor developing country.

  17. 17.

    Ever since Okun’s so-called law, first expressed in 1974, that there was a trade-off between equality and efficiency, the conventional wisdom among the economics profession has been that a trade-off was inevitable.

  18. 18.

    Some observers would call this the dashboard approach.

  19. 19.

    See Addison et al. (2017) for an overview of aid effectiveness.

References

  • Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity, and poverty. New York: Crown Business.

    Google Scholar 

  • Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2001, December). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation. The American Economic Review, 91(5), 1369–1401.

    Google Scholar 

  • Addison, T., Morrissey, O., & Tarp, F. (2017). The macroeconomics of aid; overview. The Journal of Development Studies, 53(7), 987–997.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I., & Morris, C. (1967). Society, politics and economic development: A quantitative approach. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Adelman, I., & Robinson, S. (1978). Income distribution policy in the developing countries: A case study of Korea. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alesina, A., & Rodrik, D. (1994). Distributive politics and economic growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 109(2), 465–490.

    Google Scholar 

  • Alkire, S., & Foster, J. (2011). Understandings and misunderstandings of multidimensional poverty measurement. The Journal of Economic Inequality, 9(2), 289–314.

    Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson, A. (2015). Inequality. What can be done? Cambridge, MA/London, UK: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Azariadis, C., & Stachurski, J. (2005). Poverty traps. In P. Aghion and S.N. Durlauf eds. Handbook of economic growth. North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, A. V., Duflo, E., Glennester, R., & Kothari, D. (2010). Improving immunization coverage in rural India: Clustered randomized controlled evaluation of immunization campaigns with and without incentives. BMJ. 2010; 340: c2220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. K. (1989). The economic theory of agrarian institutions. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. K. (2005). Institutions matter, but which ones? Economics of Transition and Institutional Change, 13(3), 499–532.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (2013). The method of randomization and the role of reasoned intuition. Policy research working paper (No. WPS 6722). Washington, DC: World Bank Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basu, K. (2015). An economist in the real world. Cambridge, MA: The MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bates M. A., & Glennerster, R. (2017). The generalizability puzzle, Stanford Social Innovation Review. Summer 2017, online journal available at https://ssir.org/articles/entry/the_generalizability_puzzle

  • Bourguignon, F., & Chakravarty, S. R. (2003). The measurement of multidimensional poverty. Journal of Economic Inequality, 1, 25–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burnside, C., & Dollar, D. (2000). Aid, policies, and growth. American Economic Review, 90(4), 847–868.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carter, M. R., & Barrett, C. (2006). The economics of poverty traps and persistent poverty: An asset-based approach. The Journal of Development Studies, 42(2), 178–199.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H. B. (1953). Application of investment criteria. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 67(February), 76–96.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H. B. (1960). Patterns of industrial growth. American Economic Review, 50(4), 624–654.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H. B., & Taylor, L. (1968). Development patterns: Among countries and over time. Review of Economics and Statistics, 50(4), 391–416.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery, H. B., Ahluwalia, M. S., Bell, C. L. G., Duloy, J. H., & Jolly, R. (Eds.). (1974). Redistribution with growth. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornia, G., Jolly, R., & Stewart, F. (1987). Adjustment with a human face: Protecting the vulnerable and promoting growth. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • de Janvry, A., Sadoulet, E., & Thorbecke, E. (1993). Introduction to state, market, and civil organizations: New theories, new practices, and their implications for rural development. World Development, 21(4), 565–575.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A. (2010). Instruments, randomization, and learning about development. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(2), 424–455.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deaton, A., & Cartwright, N. (2016). The limitations of randomized controlled trials. VOX: CPR’s Policy Portal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dervis, K., de Melo, J., & Robinson, S. (1982). General equilibrium models for developing countries. London: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duclos, J.-Y., Sahn, D., & Younger, S. (2006). Robust multidimensional poverty comparisons. Economic Journal. 116(514), 943–968.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duflo, E., & Banerjee, A. (2017). Handbook of field experiments. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Duflo, E., & Kremer, M. (2003). Use of randomization in the evaluation of development effectiveness. Paper prepared for the World Bank operations evaluation department conference, Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein, A. (1957). Investment criteria for economic development and the theory of Intertemporal welfare. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 71(1), 56–85.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fei, J. C. H., & Ranis, G. (1964). Development of the labor surplus economy. Homewood: Irwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Foster, J., Greer, J., & Thorbecke, E. (1984). A class of decomposable poverty measures. Econometrica, 52, 761–766.

    Google Scholar 

  • Galenson, W., & Leibenstein, H. (1955). Investment criteria, productivity and economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(3), 343–370.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guillaumont, P., & Chavet, L. (2001). Aid and performance: A reassessment. Journal of Development Studies, 37(6), 66–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, H., & Tarp, F. (2001). Aid and growth regressions. Journal of Development Economics, 64, 547–570.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J., & Todaro, M. (1970). Migration, unemployment & development: A two-sector analysis. American Economic Review, 60(1), 126–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heckman, J. J. (2010). Building bridges between structural and program evaluation approaches to evaluating policy. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(2), 356–398.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hirschman, A. (1958). The strategy of economic development. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hunt, D. (1989). Economic theories of development: An analysis of comparative paradigms. Hemel Hempstead: Harvester and Wheatsheaf.

    Google Scholar 

  • ILO. (1973). Employment, income and equality: A strategy for increasing productive employment in Kenya. Geneva: International Labor Organization.

    Google Scholar 

  • Imbens, G. (2010). Better late than nothing. Journal of Economic Literature, 48(2), 399–423.

    Google Scholar 

  • Johnston, B. F., & Kilby, P. (1975). Agriculture and structural transformation. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahn, A. E. (1951). Investment criteria in development programs. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 65, 38–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur, R. (Ed.). (2004). Q-Squared: Qualitative and quantitative methods of poverty appraisal. Delhi: Permanent Black.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kanbur R., & Schaeffer, P. (Eds.). (2007). Experiences of combining qualitative and quantitative approaches to poverty analysis. World Development Special Issue, 35(2), 183–354.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, J. I., & Lau, L. J. (1994). The sources of economic growth of east-Asian newly industrialized countries. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 8(3), 235–271.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. R. (1994). The myth of Asia’s miracle. Foreign Affairs, 73(6), 62–78.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets, S. (1966). Modern economic growth. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibenstein, H. (1957). Economic backwardness and economic growth. New York: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labor. The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 22(2), 139–191.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindauer, D. L., & Pritchett, L. (2002). What’s the big idea? The third generation of policies for economic growth. Economia, 3(1), 1–39.

    Google Scholar 

  • Little, I. M. D., & Mirrlees, J. (1974). Project appraisal and planning for developing countries. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3–42.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mookherjee, D. (2005), Is there too Little theory in development economics today? Economic and Political Weekly Vol. 40, No. 40 (Oct. 1–7, 2005), pp. 4328–4333.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myrdal, G. (1968). Asian drama: An inquiry into the poverty of nations. Allen Lane: The Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nabli, M. K., & Nugent, J. B. (1989). The new institutional economics and its applicability to development. World Development, 17(9), 1333–1348.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ndulu, B., O’Connell, S. A., Bates, R. H., Collier, P., & Soludu, C. C. (2008). The political economy of economic growth in Africa, 1960–2000. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nissanke, M., & Thorbecke, E. (2006). Channels and policy debate in the globalization-inequality-poverty Nexus. World Development, 34(8), 1338–1360.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge/New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nurkse, R. (1953). Problems of capital formation in underdeveloped countries. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pant, P. (1974). Perspective of development: 1961–1976. Implications for planning for a minimum level of living. In T. N. Srinivasan & P. K. Bardhan (Eds.), Poverty and income distribution in India. Calcutta: Statistical Publishing Society.

    Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T., & Tabellini, G. (1990). Macroeconomic policy, credibility, and politics. New York/Melbourne: Hardwood Academic Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ravallion, M. (2012). Why don’t we see poverty convergence? American Economic Review, 102(1), 504–523.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, D. (1998). Development economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, D. (2000). What is new in development economics? The American Economist, 44, 3–16.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, P. (1990). Endogenous technological change. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5, part 2), S71–S102

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosenstein-Rodan, P. M. (1943). Problems of industrialization of Eastern and South-Eastern Europe. Economic Journal, 53(210), 202–211.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rostow, W. W. (1956). The take-off into self-sustained growth. Economic Journal, 66(March), 25–48.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ruttan, V. W. (1996). United States development assistance policy: The domestic politics of foreign economic aid. Baltimore/London: Johns Hopkins University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J. D. (2006). The end of poverty. London, England: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sahn, D. E., Dorosh, P., & Younger, S. (1996). Exchange rate, fiscal and agricultural policies in Africa: Does adjustment hurt the poor? World Development, 24(4), 719–747.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. K. (1985). Commodities and capabilities. Amsterdam: North-Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • The Lancet. (2004). The World Bank is finally embracing science: Editorial. The Lancet, 364, 731–732.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorbecke, E. (Ed.). (1969). The role of agriculture in economic development. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorbecke, E. (1991). Adjustment, growth and income distribution in Indonesia. World Development, 19(11), 1595–1614.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorbecke, E. (1993). Impact of state and civil institutions on the operation of rural market and non-market configurations. World Development, 21(4), 591–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorbecke, E. (2006). Economic development, equality, income distribution and ethics. In M. Altmann (Ed.), Handbook of contemporary behavioral economics: Foundations and developments. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorbecke, E., & Charumilind, C. (2002). Economic inequality and its socioeconomic impact. World Development, 39(2), 1477–1495.

    Google Scholar 

  • Timmer, P. C. (2015). Food security and scarcity: Why ending hunger is so hard. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsui, K. Y. (2002). Multidimensional poverty indices. Social Choice and Welfare, 19, 69–93.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1991). Comparative economic organization: The analysis of discreet structural alternatives (Working paper). Washington, DC: Institute for Policy Reform.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (1993). The East Asian miracle. Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank. (2005). World development report: Equity and development. Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. (1995). The tyranny of numbers: Confronting the statistical realities of the East-Asian Growth experience. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 641–680.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Erik Thorbecke .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Thorbecke, E. (2019). The History and Evolution of the Development Doctrine, 1950–2017. In: Nissanke, M., Ocampo, J.A. (eds) The Palgrave Handbook of Development Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-14000-7_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-13999-5

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-14000-7

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics