Advertisement

Value Forms and the Structure of the Capitalist System

  • David Fishman
Chapter

Abstract

The missing time dimension of value, that corresponding to the future, will be established here. The two triads of value and time will then be complete: value linked to the past, exchange-value to the present and use-value that ties to the future. This formulation allows for the understanding and characterization of contemporary capitalism and in turn will show the way to the emancipation from the rule of capital. Further, the nature and origin of profit will be established as a basic corollary of monetary exchange under capitalism; this does not invalidate Marx’s characterization of surplus value and exploitation but is the necessary form of expression of these. The key to all this is in the understanding of the two triads. The total wealth of the system needs to be classified and mapped and this will be seen to be composed of two elements, one representing the past and the other the future.

References

  1. Andrews, P., & Brunner, E. (1975). Studies in Pricing. Macmillan.Google Scholar
  2. Arthur, C. (2005). Value and Money. In F. Moseley (Ed.), Marx’s Theory of Money. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  3. Atkinson, A. (2015). Inequality: What Can Be Done? Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  4. Brealey, R., & Myers, S. (1984). Principles of Corporate Finance (2nd ed.). McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
  5. Credit Suisse. (2016). Global Wealth Report (7th ed). https://www.credit-suisse.com/corporate/en/research/research-institute/global-wealth-report.html. Accessed August 28, 2017.
  6. Cutler, A., Hindess, B., Hirst, P., & Hussein, A. (1977, 1978). Marx’s Capital and Contemporary Capitalism (Vols. 1 & 2). Routledge.Google Scholar
  7. Davies, J. (Ed.). (2008). Personal Wealth from a Global Perspective. Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
  8. Davies, J., Sandström, S., Shorrocks, A., & Wolff, E. (2011). The Level and Distribution of Global Household Wealth. The Economic Journal, 121(551), 223–254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  9. Fishman, L. (1992). Economic Surplus and the Market System. In J. Davis (Ed.), The Economic Surplus in Advanced Economies. Elgar.Google Scholar
  10. Fishman, D. (2017). Energy and Climate and Security. The Political Quarterly, 88(2), 335–337.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  11. Godley, W., & Lavoie, M. (2007). Monetary Economics: An Integrated Approach to Credit, Money, Income, Production and Wealth. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  12. Goldsmith, R. (1962). National Wealth of the United States in the Postwar Period. Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  13. Holloway, J. (2015). Read Capital: The First Sentence or, Capital Starts with Wealth, Not with the Commodity. Historical Materialism, 23(3), 3–26.Google Scholar
  14. Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Macmillan.Google Scholar
  15. Lee, F. (1999). Post Keynesian Price Theory. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  16. Marx, K. (1906, 1909). Capital (Vols. 1 & 3). Kerr.Google Scholar
  17. Murray, P. (2005). Money as Displaced Social Form: Why Value Cannot Be Independent of Price. In F. Moseley (Ed.), Marx’s Theory of Money. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
  18. Paul, C., & Montagu, G. (2014). Banking and Capital Markets Companion. Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
  19. Revell, J. (1967). The Wealth of the Nation. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
  20. Richmond, C. (2007). Patience, Humility, Reticence: Hijacked Virtues. In D. Powell & T. Hickey (Eds.), Democracy: The Long Revolution. Continuum.Google Scholar
  21. Ritter, L. (1963 [1996]). A Framework for Financial Analysis. In J. Dawson (Ed.), Flow-of-Funds Analysis: A Handbook for Practitioners. M.E. Sharpe.Google Scholar
  22. Rose, S. (2003). The Making of Memory. Vintage.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2020

Authors and Affiliations

  • David Fishman
    • 1
  1. 1.AbingdonUK

Personalised recommendations