Skip to main content

Economics as Concentrated Politics

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Ajit Singh of Cambridge and Chandigarh

Part of the book series: Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought ((PHET))

  • 258 Accesses

Abstract

Ajit’s economics was theoretically and methodologically rigorous, evidence-based and policy-relevant. Initially, his research developed an empirical refutation of key tenets of the neoclassical theory of the firm, mergers, takeovers and the stock market. Subsequently, his paradigmatic research on deindustrialisation in the UK simultaneously provided a framework emphasising the vital role of manufacturing in development. His consistent advocacy of state-enabled Kaldorian industrialisation, exemplified by South Korea, brought him into regular confrontation with the uniform structural adjustment and free-market mainstream package applied on developing economies by the Bretton Woods institutions, prominently in Tanzania and Mexico; in opposition, he argued for a strategically selective rather than a close and all-embracing integration with globalisation processes. Later, he began to investigate the limits of export-led industrialisation and recalibrate the Kaldorian template with possibly a lead role for the services sector. He would reject claims that his industrialisation strategy risked mutation into an ideology of industrialism.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    From the obituary in The Times (2015), rephrasing words of Irfan ul Haq (see ul Haq et al. 2015).

  2. 2.

    In this work, Ajit constructs a general analytical framework that provides the scaffolding for a set of case studies, including one on Punjab in 1983.

  3. 3.

    In her obituary, Sunanda Sen (2015, p. 75) states that “Ajit also had been engaged in what he could witness as ‘ecological destructions ’, putting forth his plea for remedial measures to save the present and future generations of humanity”. However, apart from one late joint paper (co-authored with Shachi Amdekar, a doctoral researcher at Queens’ College ), there really is no serious evidence of Ajit propounding extensively on this theme, important as he might have regarded it. This paper, Amdekar and Singh (2014), which does not appear in Ajit’s curriculum vitae updated only in June 2014, is a commentary on Stephen Marglin’s (2013) article calling for a fundamental rethink of economics and policy in view of the ecological factor.

  4. 4.

    In a comment all the more significant for its rarity, Ajit writing on Punjab remarks: “I … suggest that accelerated industrialisation and a substantially redistributive fiscal policy (i.e., a more equitable distribution of gains from economic growth by fiscal means) must be the two pillars of any well conceived basic needs programme” (Singh 1983a, p. 3).

  5. 5.

    “Sanjaya Lall , one of the most brilliant development economists of his generation, was not merely an apostle of third world industrialization but provided an intellectual and theoretical rationale for it, as well as a strategic policy design to achieve it” (Singh 2009b, p. 1). “He seemed to have been much influenced by the leading legendary Cambridge economist, Nicholas Kaldor . Like Kaldor, Lall believed that manufacturing was the engine of growth and developing countries in general should follow the model of export led growth. For Lall, development economics was less a study of poverty but more one of how to develop capabilities for industrial, technical and organizational development, so that third world corporations could effectively compete in the global economy” (ibid., p. 2). Ajit could well have been describing himself, though the scope of his own work was far more extensive in coverage than the deeply specialised and sharply focussed research of Sanjaya, which was almost exclusively devoted to the issues of technological development and multinational behaviour.

  6. 6.

    The reference is to Ajit’s empirical refutation of the neoclassical theory of the firm in the mid-1960s. Amartya also recollects when Ajit offered to drive him to the airport; the two got into an argument over social justice; they had to stop for a coffee to complete the discussion; Ajit wouldn’t let go—almost literally—and the flight to Delhi was missed, the only time that has happened to him, Amartya tells us.

  7. 7.

    Incidentally, both books were published by Cambridge University Press and edited by Jo Bradley , later married to Ajit. She recalls that book manuscripts submitted by DAE authors were routinely nodded on by the CUP Syndics, in view of the prior intensive technical vetting and peer review they had been subjected to within the DAE. In Ajit’s case, however, the proposal came under attack from two Syndics apparently casting aspersions on the leftist politics and activism of the author. Jo was present the meeting in her capacity as editor, but not mandated to intervene in the meeting; she did immediately after, however, in a sharp letter of complaint to (not about) Brian Reddaway, also a Syndic, who retired that year from his position of Director of DAE: “the Chairman abused his position to make gratuitous personal remarks which may do Ajit harm academically”, using the privileged position of the Syndics’ proceedings where Ajit “would have no opportunity to defend himself against such an attack on his character”. The two erring Syndics were named as Sir Frank Lee, long term civil servant, and Professor Geoffrey Elton, a constitutional historian of Tudor times specialising in Oliver Cromwell; neither could have had a serious inkling about the subject matter of the book in question—an econometric analysis of takeovers. It is not known precisely how it came to pass, but this impropriety was apparently remedied with an apology tendered in the following meeting, and the manuscript duly went on to make the waves and splash it did. (Cf: Letter by Jo Bradley to Professor W.B. Reddaway, dated 31 July; 1970, personal communication, quoted with permission.)

  8. 8.

    There are a couple of curiosities in the references to this article: one is a reference to an unpublished paper of his, also from 1975, on “Monopoly Capital Revisited: The Role of Centralization by Merger”, clearly here engaging with Marxian discourse and Marxist audiences. The other is not an entry but an absence, there being no reference to Robin Marris’s The Economic Theory of ‘ Managerial’ Capitalism published in 1964.

  9. 9.

    Ajit had a penchant for challenging orthodoxy and mainstream positions by using the words of some of their own sages. Paul Samuelson would have agreed with Ajit on the dysfunctionality of managerial incentive systems in large corporations and also with Ajit’s long-term perspective on the investment process. In Samuelson’s words: “Investing should be more like watching paint dry or watching grass grow. If you want excitement, take $800 and go to Las Vegas”, or “Investing should be dull. It shouldn’t be exciting”. Ajit would have agreed with the emphasis on the long term without compromising the “animal spirits” of productive entrepreneurs or the role of the state in providing a facilitative framework. See www.brainyquote.com/quotes/quotes/p/paulsamuel205549.html.

  10. 10.

    There are nine (mostly joint) papers in this category, including Glen et al. (2003), Glen et al. (1999), and Singh (2003). Also relevant here is the joint work with Candace Howes at the University of Notre Dame (Howes and Singh 2000).

  11. 11.

    Quoted in the Chandigarh Tribune, 7 April 2004, www.tribuneindia.com/2004/20040407/cth1.htm-4. See also Singh (2007c).

  12. 12.

    See the tribute by Professor Datuk Dr. Rujhan Mustafa of the International Economics Universiti Malaysia (19 July 2015): “Prof Rajah Rasiah often told me of the profound respect Ajit Singh had for Dr Mahathir’s courage in fearlessly standing up against the imperial powers”: www.thestar.com.my/News/Education/2015/07/19/Tribute-to-revered-economists/. See also Asia Samachar, 13 July 2015, http://asiasamachar.com/2015/07/13/prof-ajit-singh-great-mind-courageous/, and the obituary by Professor Rajah Rasiah (2015).

  13. 13.

    Ajit Singh “India Arising: Myth or Reality”, www.griffith.edu.au/__data/assets/pdf_file/0018/18216/newsletter-volume-7-2.pdf.

  14. 14.

    The allusion here is to the sub-continental “traditions” of inter-community cultural rivalries and deprecation through (seriously politically incorrect) humour, and Sikhs, or sardars, have more than their fair share of being at the butt end of it; typically jestful put-downs would vest the Sikh community with an endearingly high degree of gullibility and misreading of situations; here, Ajit turns the tables on his Pakistani brethren!

  15. 15.

    There are other significant antecedents in the deindustrialisation debate and an early root is again in Cambridge itself in the work of D. R. Gadgil , who came to Cambridge in 1918, took a Pt. I in the History Tripos and then switched to Economics for the Pt. II, subsequently going on to an M. Litt (1921–1923) with his dissertation being published in 1924 by Oxford University Press as the little classic, The Industrial Evolution of India in Recent Times (Gadgil 1924); much later he wrote on the origins of the modern business class in India (Gadgil 1959) and served in many senior capacities including as Deputy Chair of the Planning Commission (see Dandekar 1971). Between Gadgil and Bagchi is the productive debate on “The Indian Economy in the 19th Century”, carried in the Indian Economic and Social History Review in 1968, including significant contributions by Morris D. Morris whose revisionist thesis on the colonial impact is countered by Tapan Raychaudhuri , Toru Matsui , Irfan Habib , Bipin Chandra and Amiya Bagchi among others. There are interesting comparisons to be made between the two debates: the impact of imperial Britain on Indian indigenous industry and then the deindustrialisation in the UK in the face of competition from other advanced countries in the modern period covered by Ajit and others.

  16. 16.

    Wynne Godley , a Fellow at King’s, called Kaldor “a Falstaffian intellect who thought with his gut; he emanated genius, was very persuasive and would never give up” (Godley 2008). Rowthorn (2008) agrees: “Kaldor was a brilliant economist and not in this school at all, not defensive, too interested in creating new ideas; a jolly person, full of life, a wonderful man”. Godley says that Kaldor “loved laughter, usually at his own jokes” and “used to sleep at meetings”. Bernal, another King’s Fellow, chimes in: “for some reason, I often found myself sitting next to him at feasts. When not dozing, he could be delightfully friendly and indiscreet ” (Bernal 2012, p. 277).

  17. 17.

    Kaldor’s contributions are finely and succinctly addressed by Geoff Harcourt in his obituary (Harcourt 1988) and in his review (Harcourt 1997) of Kaldor’s Raffaele Mattioli Lectures, delivered in 1984 but published in 1996 (Kaldor 1996); see also Thirlwall (1987) and Targetti (2005) which deals with the interface of Kaldor’s ideas with economic development, and his earlier treatment of Kaldor’s analysis of capitalism as a dynamic system (Targetti 1992).

  18. 18.

    Of pertinence here is Thorstein Veblen’s work linking economics and Darwinism using the notion of cumulative causation (Veblen 1898, 1904). However, Hodgson (2004) cautions that behind the similarity of terms, there is a difference in meaning: “while Veblen coined the term ‘cumulative’ causation, he used it primarily to refer to cumulative sequences of cause and effect. With other authors, the term ‘cumulative causation ’ took on the different meaning (in modern parlance) of non-linear processes of positive feedback. For instance, in his classic article on ‘increasing returns ’ Allyn Young wrote that: ‘change becomes progressive and propagates itself in a cumulative way’. One of his students was Nicholas Kaldor, who made extensive use of Young’s positive feedback notion of ‘cumulative causation’. Gunnar Myrdal independently took the idea of cumulative causation from the positive feedback mechanisms in the monetary economics of fellow Swedish economist Knut Wicksell ” (Hodgson 2004, p. 347).

  19. 19.

    See especially Young (1928, pp. 533–535) on the inherent tendencies towards “disequilibrium”, and the role of historical time in the realisation of processes of increasing returns as part of economic progress.

  20. 20.

    Sraffa (1926, p. 537) refers to “the position occupied in classical economics by the law of increasing returns … as an important aspect of the division of labour, and thus rather as a result of general economic progress than of an increase in the scale of production”.

  21. 21.

    In this connection, see also the one-sided attack by Bela Balassa, the World Bank consultant, on the Cambridge School (Balassa 1989a).

  22. 22.

    In this Tanzania paper (Singh 1986), Ajit refers to two unpublished background papers written by him at the Department of Applied Economics (Singh 1982, 1983b).

  23. 23.

    For contemporary and subsequent writings that deal specifically with this period and/or episode, see Barker and Brailovsky (1982); Eatwell and Singh (1982); Kandell (2004); Looney (1985); Maddison (1992); Moreno-Brid and Ros (2007); Rattner (1982); Solis (1981).

  24. 24.

    One of these was Brian Van Arkadie himself and for his own reasons, he stood closer to the other side: “My own view on Tanzanian devaluation , of course, differs from Ajit’s. My support of devaluation was based on two things. One, cynically I was seeking a compromise between donors and Mwalimu — in order to defend Mwalimu’s great achievements — and I felt that Ajit’s argument, that the exchange rate really could make no difference, could also be used to support a cynical adjustment. Secondly, the rather weak bureaucracy could not longer manipulate internal prices and manage exchange control effectively” (personal communication, email dated 11 December 2017). Typically, Ajit’s arguments always opposed the ideas, not the person holding them. In a personal communication, Brian wrote: “the difference in view did not result in an estrangement between us — we remained friends; a few years later I delivered an address on his behalf at the anniversary celebrations for the economics faculty of the University of Malaya ; I saw him often in Cambridge; indeed, he had promised to come to my 80th birthday party and a lunch at Queen’s — sadly he was in no shape to do so and died soon after” (Brian Van Arkadie , personal communication, 21 October 2015).

  25. 25.

    “A Primer in Culinary Economics, or How to Maximize the Culinary Utility of the Dollar in Paris”, of which the 8th edition appeared in 1987. See, https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/B%E2%88%9A%C2%A9la_Balassa.

  26. 26.

    In fact, Ajit, in arguing “the Cambridge position”, was anything but doctrinaire. He explicitly accepted the wisdom of devaluation when the circumstances require it: “whether or not a change in the exchange rate is required — and more importantly the extent of the change and its timing — should rest on an empirical examination of the following kinds of questions …”, and then he set out precisely the preconditions that would justify devaluation (Singh 1986, p. 434).

  27. 27.

    Much later, in 2002, Ajit returned to the issue of aid and associated conditionality. Development and Change hosted a symposium centred on Jan Pronk’s position paper, “Aid as a Catalyst”, with invited reactions from a range of experts. While recognising the generally progressive stance of Jan Pronk and the Netherlands with regard to international assistance, Ajit took issue with Pronk (2001), arguing that he “looks at the problem essentially from the standpoint of aid-providing nations … [and] by and large, omits the concerns of aid-receivers — the developing countries” (Singh 2002, p. 295), and set about correcting this imbalance. “From the perspective of developing countries, aid should be based on need and be free of intrusive conditionalities, particularly with respect to policies and governance …. It is useful to consider an analogy with the request of an individual economic agent for a home purchase loan or one for other family expenditures. The lender may ask the agent to provide guarantees or collateral and may fix payment terms considering the borrower’s financial situation. This kind of conditionality is generally regarded as legitimate. But, if the lender were to insist on divorce of the borrower from the spouse, or even a laudable thing such as equal rights for all family members, this would be regarded as unacceptable interference. Similarly, developing countries feel that intrusive conditionalities, particularly those relating to a country’s economic and political institutions, are illegitimate” (ibid., p. 303). For Jan Pronk’s response, see Pronk (2003).

  28. 28.

    Messkoub (1996) provides a careful review of the social impact of adjustment programmes in Tanzania . For a sanitised IMF grand narrative, see Nord et al. (2009). This version fails to mention at all any of the policy dialogue between the World Bank and IMF on the one side and the different positions on the Tanzanian side, and neither the role of the Cambridge advisors, nor any of their names appears in this book—a case of shabby ideological cleansing.

  29. 29.

    See Cripps et al. (2011); Izurieta and Singh (2010). See also Singh (1996a, 1999b).

  30. 30.

    See Ajit Singh’s jointly authored papers with Hamid Tabatabai at the ILO: Singh and Tabatabai (1990, 1992 and—especially—1993).

  31. 31.

    Here the reader is directed especially to the papers co-authored with Ann Zammit . Ajit’s curriculum vitae (updated to June 2014) lists 11 papers jointly authored with Ann Zammit between 1995 and 2011 dealing directly with issues pertaining to labour, gender and finance within a global analytical and policy framework. Ann became Ajit’s second wife days before his demise.

  32. 32.

    Another trenchant example comes from Ajit in his obituary address for Alice Amsden (Singh 2012). For Ajit, the long-term path to high labour standards lay through the highway of rapid, high-quality industrialisation; but you had to traverse from “the low road” to “the high road”, and the successful development of manufacturing industries held the key.

  33. 33.

    Their joint paper is dated July 1988, but it never saw the full light of day, and only remains in draft form, no doubt due to Sukhamoy’s progressive illness and then his tragically premature demise in August 1990. It is visibly a two-part product both in form and in content: the first twenty-eight pages (Times New Roman, inkjet) are clearly Sukhamoy’s and provide a sweep of the theoretical terrain sifting critically through complex and varied inherited positions making the case for full openness, and precisely identifying the weak spots and holes in these generalised recipes used to provide theoretical justifications for globalisation à la Bretton Woods. Then follow pages 29–53 (Arial, dot-matrix) which are obviously Ajit’s, providing an equally fluent and focussed empirical analogue that complements Sukhamoy’s theoretical take, using the ESEA, especially South Korea , as empirical cases to support their shared argument.

    The paper calls itself a “first draft”; at some points in Ajit’s section, there are handwritten corrections and references to “sections which will be added to the paper at the next stage”, or in “subsequent work”. Clearly, this significant intervention was prescient when it was written in 1988, but time turned against its completion with Sukhamoy’s demise before they could finalise it. In Singh (1996b)— his paper on China for the Rehman Sobhan festschrift —he cites an “unpublished paper” from 1993 titled “‘Close’ vs. ‘Strategic’ Integration with the World Economy and the ‘Market-Friendly Approach to Development’ vs. an ‘Industrial Policy’: A Critique of the World Development Report 1991 and an Alternative Policy Perspective”; this paper subsequently becomes available on line in the Munich online archive as Singh (1995a). Singh (1995a) carries a reference to Chakravarty and Singh 1988, as a WIDER paper; but apparently, it never went beyond the “first draft” stage discussed here.

  34. 34.

    An unpublished cyclostyled version of the paper exists in the Joan Robinson Archives held at King’s College , Cambridge: The Papers of Professor Joan Violet Robinson; JVR/vii/420/1; May. I am grateful to Dr. Maha Abdelrahman for extracting a copy of this document.

  35. 35.

    Singh (1973), this is a revised version of two lectures delivered at the Studium Generale, University of Heidelberg in June 1972, wherein the author acknowledges valuable comments from Jo Bradley and Suzy Paine.

  36. 36.

    The role of interactions with his close Cambridge colleague and friend Peter Nolan , a leading China specialist, as interlocutor is apparent in Ajit’s line of argumentation; both converged on the raw economic dynamism unleashed by the reforms and the strong role of the state in harnessing this power.

  37. 37.

    The curriculum vitae is reproduced in full, with permission, as Appendix C.

  38. 38.

    Ajit was not unmindful of the existence and intensification of deep inequalities through a purely market-driven process of technological change, as illustrated by his critical observations on the immediate social and economic disparities on display in Silicon Valley and Palo Alto (Singh et al. 2000, p. 30). Quoting in his own favour typically from an adversarial source: “The Economist notes ‘it would be hard to find a better real-life symbol for the digital divide than the gulf between Silicon Valley’s leafy Palo Alto, home to dot.com millionaires where the average house sells for nearly $700,000, and East Palo Alto, the desperate little town on the other side of Highway 101 that not long ago claimed America’s highest murder rate’”. These disparities can only be addressed by the government (ibid.). See also Singh (1995b, 2001), Singh and Dhumale (2004), and Ajit Singh and Gurmail Singh (2013) for work on inequalities.

  39. 39.

    Quoted in report on the Conference by Kevin P. Gallagher (2012); cf. Singh (2012).

  40. 40.

    Fanon (1965); the quotations in this section are drawn from Chapter 3, “The Pitfalls of National Consciousness”.

  41. 41.

    “Kaldor also had, similarly to Keynes, an unsurpassable tendency to over-estimate the possibilities of intellect to overcome and limit diffused stupidity. He was indeed a great believer in the role of intellectuals and scornful of what he thought to be a widespread mediocrity of the ruling classes” (Pasinetti 2007, p. 130).

  42. 42.

    In his 1994 paper, Ajit perhaps did not sufficiently acknowledge the sharp differences between the capitalists, capitalist houses and capitalist classes in South Korea (and more widely in East Asian countries including China), and those in India.

  43. 43.

    Arguably the two finest, free-thinking, radical female economists of our times, they come together in Joan’s Introduction for the first English edition of Rosa’s study.

  44. 44.

    The quotations from Rosa Luxemburg used in this section are drawn from the first chapter of the online edition of her Anti-Critique (Luxemburg 1921/1972) which is not paginated.

  45. 45.

    See his Raffaele Mattioli Lectures, especially the 4th lecture on “the effects of interregional and international competition” and the 5th lecture on “policy implications of current world situation” (Kaldor 1996).

  46. 46.

    “We can substitute for a supposed logical necessity a plausible hypothesis about the nature of the real case, and so rescue the succeeding argument ” (Joan Robinson in Luxemburg [1951, pp. 25–26]); elsewhere, she finds that one argument is “over-determined” (ibid., p. 25), while another “over-reaches itself” (ibid., p. 27), and that with regard to the resilience of capitalism, “her analysis is incomplete” (ibid., p. 28).

  47. 47.

    Francis Cripps , personal communication, email dated 10 February 2018. Francis drew attention to the early work of Dudley Seers on the development contradiction between “big companies and small countries” (Seers 1963).

  48. 48.

    For instance, Godbout and Langcake (2013, p. 24) estimate that in China, the elasticity of manufacturing imports with respect to manufacturing exports was as high as 0.49 in the period after 2005, rising from 0.32 for the period before then.

  49. 49.

    Simultaneous export-led industrialisation becomes impossible at a global level and also raises issues about cross-sectional methods for validating Kaldorian laws: notionally dividing the world into two groups, if one enjoyed an export-led boom, the other would face a balance-of-payments crisis, implying that the cross-sectional observations would not be independent. For an analysis counterposing the two paths, one export-led and the other balance-of-payments constrained, see Blecker (2013).

  50. 50.

    There Is No Alternative.

  51. 51.

    Given its provenance, the study would not conventionally qualify as independent research, as the preface (Dharmadhikari n.d., p. xiii) records that the novelist-activist Arundhati Roy —among other commitments an anti-high dam campaigner (Roy 1999)—had unstintingly resourced the setting up of Manthan as well as this research study. This should not matter, so long as the research process, the data and the interpretations are not influenced or prejudged by the motivations of the researchers. In general, doing otherwise would imply the silencing of activists on precisely the issues that made them activists; of course, as a general rule, in cases of declared interest, the evidence, methods and inferences would need to be closely scrutinised and undergo additional checks.

  52. 52.

    Kosambi had espoused the same argument in 1957, before the construction of Bhakra began: “In a country that has a monsoon, the essential is to hold the rain-water back as long as possible, to prevent quick erosion of valuable top-soil. That is, flood control and efficient food production in India would be far better served by a hundred thousand, properly coordinated, small dams rather than a few big ones costing more. The Chinese have their own schemes for atomic energy research, but for use, not empty prestige. In India, the money poured out could have been much better utilized in harnessing the decidedly more abundant solar energy which only blasts the country over eight months or more of the year. All we have achieved so far is a remarkably useless sun-cooker” (Kosambi 1957). With respect specifically to the Bhakra Nangal Project, Kosambi’s caption on the illustration of its hydel channel in his book reads: “another of the state-planned national projects. Such multi-purpose schemes are needed in far larger number to control floods, provide water for irrigation, and produce electric power for home and factory use. Their most attractive function for the ruling class is to provide new opportunities for investment” (Kosambi 1956, n.p.).

  53. 53.

    It was Baker, a close friend of K. N. Raj , who ushered in this paradigm with his mould-breaking design of the campus of the Centre for Development Studies in Kerala , which was almost the Indian home of Joan Robinson ; where Nicky Kaldor delivered the inaugural Joan Robinson memorial lecture; and to whose remarkable library building, Kaldor’s books were later bequeathed.

  54. 54.

    Aditya Prakash produced the basic designs for some of the Le Corbusier landmark buildings in Chandigarh, including KC Theatre, Neelam Theatre, Jagat Cinema and later the Tagore Theatre—places that Ajit’s family would surely have visited. A cultural polymath, he was accomplished as an architect, academic, painter and published author; at the age of 84, he was on a train to Bombay to perform in a play “Zindagi Retire Nahi Hoti” (Life does not Retire); he died en route at Ratlam, halfway to his destination, his mission accomplished.

  55. 55.

    Post-modernist criticism had always opposed the traditions and signature landmarks of the high modernism represented by Le Corbusier , suggesting that his “monastic architecture with … a spirit of power and rough simplicity”, made of naked, bare concrete, had “never really been in tune with the soul of India”. Nevertheless, it was good enough for all kinds of original artefacts, “everything from furniture to manhole covers to show up on the international high-design auction circuit” (Culture Monster 2011), unfortunately too literally pointing to its lack of valuation and sustainability in the urban environment it was designed to rejuvenate.

  56. 56.

    Personal communication, email dated 30 January 2018.

  57. 57.

    Ajit pointed out that much of the “standard” econometric model was devised at the DAE by Durbin , Watson , Cochrane and Orcutt , working under Stone (Singh 2008, p. 3, n. 2).

  58. 58.

    Ajit went on to register another of Reddaway’s qualities, which was fully manifest in Ajit himself: “What was remarkable about this exchange was that it took place between a graduate student and a highly distinguished economist for whom academic hierarchy seemed to have no relevance. Indeed one of Reddaway’s characteristic traits throughout his professional life was that he was interested only in the validity or otherwise of the argument being made, rather than the formal status of the person making it” (Singh 2008, p. 3). Geoff Harcourt recalls that “Richard Goodwin thought this a typical Cambridge practice which he enthusiastically applauded and adopted”; this would show, at least, how generous he was (personal communication, email dated 16 January 2018).

  59. 59.

    Eatwell is quoting from the published version of Ajit’s piece on Brian Reddaway , “Better to be Rough and Relevant…” in Cambridge Journal of Economics (Singh 2008, 2009a).

  60. 60.

    Singh quotes Reddaway’s “favourite slogan for pupils and research colleagues: ‘It is better to be roughly right than to be precisely wrong (or irrelevant)’” (Singh 2008, p. 6). See also the entry for Reddaway in Blaug (1999, p. 932). Keynes used it, and so the quote is sometimes wrongly ascribed to him. Geoff Harcourt (who else?) provides the lineage: Gerald Shove (1942, p. 323) cites it, opining that Marshall could well have adopted this, quoting the British philosopher Herbert Wildon Carr (1857–1931) from whom it originated. Reddaway, incidentally, was supervised by Shove and probably picked it up from there, and Sen, who used it later in 1989, picked it up presumably from the rich Cambridge cosmos.

  61. 61.

    Personal communication, email dated 10 February 2018.

  62. 62.

    Ajit Singh interview in the Chandigarh Tribune, 7 April 2004, http://www.tribuneindia.com/2004/20040407/cth1.htm-4.

  63. 63.

    Ajit would have been the first to mention many other accomplished and thoroughly deserving colleagues, led by Luigi Pasinetti , overlooked in earlier rounds of appointments to professorships, and Geoff Harcourt , whose candidature was thought to have been deviously undermined by the opposition camp.

References

  • Alier, J. M. (1993). Ecological economics: Energy, environment and society. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amdekar, S., & Singh, A. (2014). Climate change and the premises for a new society. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 25(4), 563–573.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amsden, A. (2008). Epilogue. In P. Arestis & J. Eatwell (Eds.), Essays in honour of Ajit Singh: Volume 2—Issues in economic development and globalization (pp. 239–240). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amsden, A., & Singh, A. (1994a). The optimal degree of competition and dynamic efficiency in Japan and Korea. European Economic Review, 38(3–4), 940–951.

    Google Scholar 

  • Amsden, A., & Singh, A. (1994b). Concurrence dirigee et efficacite dynamique en Asie: Japon, Koree du Sud, Taiwan. Revue Tiers-Monde, 139 (July–September), 643–657.

    Google Scholar 

  • Arestis, P., & Eatwell, J. (Eds.). (2008). Essays in honour of Ajit Singh: Volume 1—Issues in finance and industry. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armour, J., Deakin, S., Fagermas, S., Sarkar, P., Siems, M., & Singh, A. (2009). Shareholder protection and stock market development: An empirical test of the legal origins hypothesis. Journal of Empirical Legal Studies, 6(2), 343–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagchi, A. K. (1976). Deindustrialization in India in the nineteenth century: Some theoretical implications. Journal of Development Studies, 12(2), 135–164.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balassa, B. (1989a). The Cambridge group and the developing countries. In B. Balassa, New directions in the world economy (pp. 65–85, Essay 4). Basingstoke and London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Balassa, B. (1989b). New directions in the world economy. Basingstoke and London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Barker, T., & Brailovsky, V. (Eds.). (1982). Oil or industry. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernal, M. (2012). Geography of a life. Bloomington, IN: Xlibris Corporation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blaug, M. (Ed.). (1999). Brian Reddaway. In Who’s Who in Economics (3rd ed.). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blecker, R. (2013). Long-run growth in open economies: Export-led cumulative causation or a balance-of-payments constraint? In G. C. Harcourt & P. Kriesler (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of post-Keynesian Economics. Volume 1: Theory and origins (Paper 16). Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buffie, E. F. (1990). Economic policy and Foreign Debt in Mexico. In J. D. Sachs (Ed.), Developing country debt and economic performance. Volume 2: Country studies—Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Mexico (pp. 393–551). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chakravarty, S., & Singh, A. (1988). The desirable forms of economic openness in the South (Unpublished paper). First Draft. July, 53 pp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J., & Singh, A. (1993, September). Public enterprises in developing countries and economic efficiency: Analytical, empirical and policy issues. UNCTAD Review, 91–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J., & Singh, A. (1997). Can large firms be run efficiently without being bureaucratic? Some critical comments on bureaucrats in business. Journal of International Development, 9(6), 865–875.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chang, H.-J., & Singh, A. (1999). Lessons from the Asian crisis. South Letter, 1 and 2(33), 5–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cripps, F., Izurieta, A., & Singh, A. (2011). Global imbalances, under-consumption and over-borrowing: The state of the world economy and future policies. Development and Change, 42(1), 228–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Culture Monster (2011, March 10). Is the Indian city of Chandigarh, designed by Le Corbusier, being ‘stripped for parts’? Lost Angeles Times. Retrieved from https://latimesblogs.latimes.com/culturemonster/2011/03/is-chandigarh-le-corbusiers-indian-masterpiece-being-stripped-for-parts.html.

  • Dandekar, V. M. (1971). D. R. Gadgil. Economic and Political Weekly, 6(19), 938–942.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P. (2010). Interview with Partha Dasgupta 6th April 2010. In S. Harrison & A. Macfarlane, Encounter with economics. Interviews filmed by A. Macfarlane and edited by S. Harrison. University of Cambridge. Retrieved from http://sms.cam.ac.uk/collection/1092396.

  • Dasgupta, S., & Singh, A. (2005). Will services be the new engine of Indian economic growth? Development and Change, 36(6), 1035–1057.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, S., & Singh, A. (2006). Manufacturing, services and premature deindustrialization in developing countries: A Kaldorian analysis (Research Paper No. 2006/49). Helsinki: UNU-WIDER.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deakin, S., Sarkar, P., & Singh, A. (2011). An end to consensus? Legal origins theory and the selective impact of corporate law reform on financial development (CBR Working Paper No. 423). Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deakin, S., & Singh, A. (2009). The stock market, the market for corporate control and the theory of the firm: Legal and economic perspectives and implications for public policy. In P. Bjuggren & D. C. Mueller (Eds.), The modern firm, corporate governance and investment (pp. 185–222). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deane, P. (1991). Joan Robinson (1903–1983): A biographical memoir. In I. Rima (Ed.), The Joan Robinson legacy (pp. 15–19). Armonk, NY: M. E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Earl, P. (2016). Pluralistic teaching: A student’s memoir. In G. C. Harcourt, The legacy of Ajit Singh (11 September 1940–23 June 2015): Memories and tributes from former pupils, colleagues and friends. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 27(3), 304–306.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J. (2016). Tribute to Ajit Singh. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 40(2), 365–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eatwell, J., & Singh, A. (1982, November 28). On Mexico. Letter to the Business Editor. The New York Times. Retrieved from www.nytimes.com/1982/11/28/business/l-on-mexico-063071.html?mcubz=3.

  • Evans, P. (1995). Embedded autonomy: States and industrial transformation. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Fanon, F. (1965). The wretched of the earth. London: MacGibbon and Kee.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gadgil, D. R. (1924). The industrial evolution of India in recent times. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gadgil, D. R. (1959). Origins of the modern business class. New York: Institute of Pacific Relations.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gallagher, K. P. (2012). Development’s last giant? Remembering Alice Amsden. Triple Crisis (online). Retrieved from http://triplecrisis.com/developments-last-giant-remembering-alice-amsden/.

  • George, S. (1976). How the other half dies: The real reasons for world hunger. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glen, J., Lee, K., & Singh, A. (2003). Corporate profitability and the dynamics of competition in emerging markets: A time series analysis. Economic Journal, 113, F465–F484.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glen, J., Singh, A., & Matthais, R. (1999). How intensive is competition in emerging markets? An analysis of corporate rates of return from nine emerging markets (IMF Working Paper No. WP/pp/32). Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glyn, A., Hughes, A., Lipietz, A., & Singh, A. (1988). The rise and fall of the golden age (UNU-WIDER Working Paper No. 43). Helsinki: United Nations University, World Institute for Development Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glyn, A., Hughes, A., Lipietz, A., & Singh, A. (1990). The rise and fall of the golden age. In S. A. Marglin & J. B. Schor (Eds.), The golden age of capitalism: Reinterpreting the postwar experience (pp. 39–125). Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godbout, C., & Langcake, S. (2013, June Quarter). Demand for manufacturing imports in China. RBA Bulletin, pp. 21–28.

    Google Scholar 

  • Godley, W. (2008). Interview with Wynne Godley 16 May 2008. In S. Harrison & A. Macfarlane, Encounter with economics. Interviews filmed by A. Macfarlane and edited by S. Harrison. University of Cambridge. Retrieved from http://sms.cam.ac.uk/collection/1092396.

  • Guha, R. (2006). How much should a person consume? Environmentalism in India and the United States. Berkeley and Los Angeles, CA: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harcourt, G. C. (1988). Nicholas Kaldor, 12 May 1908–30 September 1986. Economica, 55, 159–170.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harcourt, G. C. (1993, June 4). E. A. G. Robinson—Obituary. The Independent.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harcourt, G. C. (1997). The Kaldor legacy: Reviewing Nicholas Kaldor. In Causes of growth and stagnation in the world economy. Cambridge University Press, 1996. Journal of International and Comparative Economics, 5, 341–357.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harris, D. J. (2016). In memory of my friend Ajit Singh: Berkeley and beyond. In G. C. Harcourt. The legacy of Ajit Singh (11 September 1940–23 June 2015): Memories and tributes from former pupils, colleagues and friends. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 27(3), 300–302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hein, E. (2014). Distribution and growth after Keynes: A post-Keynesian guide. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2004). Veblen and Darwinism. International Review of Sociology, 14(3), 343–361.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Howes, C., & Singh, A. (2000). Competitiveness matters: Industry and economic performance in the US. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hughes, A. (2015, November 7). Eulogy read at the memorial service for Ajit Singh. Queens’ College Chapel.

    Google Scholar 

  • ILO. (1979). The basic needs approach to development and the New International Economic Order. Geneva: International Labour Organisation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Izurieta, A., & Singh, A. (2008). Does fast growth in China and India harm US workers? Insights from simulation evidence (CBR Working Paper No. 378). Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Izurieta, A., & Singh, A. (2010). Does fast growth in India and China help or harm US workers? Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 11(1), 115–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1966). Causes of the slow rate of economic growth of the United Kingdom. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1971). Conflicts in national economic objectives. Economic Journal, 81(321), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1983). Devaluation and adjustment in developing countries. Finance and Development, 20(2), 35–37.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kaldor, N. (1996). Causes of growth and stagnation in the world economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kandell, J. (2004, February 18). Jose Lopez Portillo, president when Mexico’s default set off debt crisis, dies at 83. The New York Times. Retrieved from www.nytimes.com/2004/02/18/business/jose-lopez-portillo-president-when-mexico-s-default-set-off-debt-crisis-dies-83.html?mcubz=3.

  • Kapur, D., Lewis, J. P., & Webb, R. C. (1997). The world bank history. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopman, R., Wang, Z., & Wei, S.-J. (2008). How much of Chinese exports is really made in China? Assessing foreign and domestic value-added in gross exports (Office of Economics Working Paper No. 2008-03-B). Washington, DC: US International Trade Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosambi, D. D. (1956). An introduction to the study of Indian history. Bombay: Popular Book Depot.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kosambi, D. D. (1957). On the revolution in China. In D. D. Kosambi, Exasperating essays. New Delhi: People’s Publishing House. Retrieved from https://www.marxists.org/archive/kosambi/exasperating-essays/x01/1957.htm.

  • Kosambi, D. D. (1960). Atomic energy in India. Text of a talk by Professor D. D. Kosambi to the Rotary Club of Poona, July 25. Retrieved from https://archive.org/stream/AtomicEnergyInIndia-D.D.Kosambi/DDK_djvu.txt.

  • Looney, R. E. (1985). Economic policy making in Mexico: Factors underlying the 1982 crisis. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luxemburg, R. (1913/1951). The accumulation of capital. With an introduction by Joan Robinson. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luxemburg, R. (1921/1972). The accumulation of capital: An anti-critique. Retrieved from https://www.marxists.org/archive/luxemburg/1915/anti-critique/index.htm.

  • Maddison, A. (1992). Brazil and Mexico: The political economy of poverty, equity and growth. New York: Oxford University Press for the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marglin, S. A. (2013). Premises for a new economy. Development, 56(2), 149–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCloskey, D. N., & Ziliak, S. T. (1996). The standard error of regressions. Journal of Economic Literature, 34(1), 97–114.

    Google Scholar 

  • Messkoub, M. (1996). The social impact of adjustment in Tanzania in the 1980s: Economic crisis and household survival strategies. Rome: FAO. Retrieved from www.bradford.ac.uk/research-old/ijas/tazadj2.htm.

  • Moreno-Brid, J. C., & Ros, J. (2007). Mexico’s economic development in historical perspective. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nord, R., Soboley, Y. V., Dunn, D., Hajdenberg, A., Hobdari, N., Maziad, S., et al. (2009). Tanzania: The story of an African transition. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nyerere, J. (1986). External finance and policy adjustment in Africa: An address. In B. Van Arkadie (Ed.), External finance and policy adjustment in Africa [Special Issue]. Development and Change, 17(3), 387–397.

    Google Scholar 

  • Paine, S., & Singh, A. (1973). The Shanghai diesel engine factory. The Cambridge Review, 94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Palma, J. G. (2015). Why corporations in developing countries are likely to be even more susceptible to the vicissitudes of international finance than their counterparts in the developed world: A tribute to Ajit Singh (CWPE Working Paper No. 1539). Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pasinetti, L. L. (2007). Keynes and the Cambridge Keynesians. A ‘revolution in economics’ to be accomplished. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patnaik, P. (2006). The diffusion of development. Economic & Political Weekly, XLI(18), 1766–1772.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patnaik, P. (2008). The accumulation process in the period of globalisation. Economic & Political Weekly, XLIII(26–27), 108–113.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patnaik, P. (2010). The diffusion of activities. Economic & Political Weekly, XLV(10), 40–45.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patnaik, P. (2015). Ajit Singh (1940–2015): A formidable economist. Economic & Political Weekly, 50(30), 32–34.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pronk, J. P. (2001). Aid as a catalyst. Development and Change, 32(4), 611–629.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pronk, J. P. (2003). Aid as a catalyst: A rejoinder. Development and Change, 34(3), 383–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Raj, K. N. (1960). Some economic aspects of the Bhakra Nangal project: A preliminary analysis of selected investment criteria. London: Asia Publishing House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rasiah, R. (2015, July 12). Passing of a great mind. The Star (Online). Retrieved from http://www.thestar.com.my/News/Education/2015/07/12/Passing-of-a-great-mind/.

  • Rattner, S. (1982, October 24). Mexico’s Cambridge connection. The New York Times. Retrieved from https://www.nytimes.com/1982/10/24/business/mexico-s-cambridge-connection.html.

  • Robinson, J. (1956). The accumulation of capital. London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rowthorn, R. (2008). Interview with Bob Rowthorn 13th June 2008. In S. Harrison and A. Macfarlane, Encounter with economics. Interviews filmed by A. Macfarlane and edited by S. Harrison. University of Cambridge. Available from http://sms.cam.ac.uk/collection/1092396.

  • Rowthorn, R. E., & Wells, J. R. (1987). De-industrialisation and foreign trade. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roy, A. (1999). The greater common good. Bombay: India Book Distributor Ltd.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seers, D. (1963). Big companies and small countries: A practical proposal. Kyklos, 16(4), 599–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A. (2007). Letter to Ajit Singh, 13 September. Reproduced in P. Arestis & J. Eatwell (Eds.), Essays in honour of Ajit Singh. Volume 2: Issues in economic development and globalization (2008) (p. xi). Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, S. (2015). Obituary: Ajit Singh. Social Scientist, 43(7/8), 73–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sen, A., & Ghosh, J. (2016). Ajit Singh’s contributions to the economics of development. In G. C. Harcourt, The legacy of Ajit Singh (11 September 1940 – 23 June 2015): Memories and tributes from former pupils, colleagues and friends. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 27(3), 308–310.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, A., & Singh, A. (2012a, April 17). The challenge of Islamic finance. Financial Times Deutschland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, A., & Singh, A. (2012b). Islamic finance: Conceptual and analytical issues from the perspective of conventional economics (Cambridge CBR Working Paper No. 435). Cambridge: Cambridge University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, A., & Singh, A. (2013a). Islamic finance: Conceptual and analytical issues from the perspective of conventional economics. In Z. Iqbal & A. Mirakhor (Eds.), Economic development and Islamic finance (pp. 67–92). Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sheng, A., & Singh, A. (2013b). Islamic stock markets in a global context. In Z. Iqbal & A. Mirakhor (Eds.), Economic development and Islamic finance (pp. 275–296). Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shove, G. F. (1942). The place of Marshall’s Principles in the development of economic theory. Economic Journal, 52(208), 294–329.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1971). Take-overs: Their relevance to the stock market and the theory of the firm. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1973). Political economy of socialist development in China since 1949. Economic & Political Weekly, 8(47), 2097–2111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1975a). Takeovers, economic natural selection and the theory of the firm: Evidence from the post-war UK experience. Economic Journal, 85(339), 497–515.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1975b). An essay on the political economy of Chinese development. Thames Papers in Political Economy. London: Thames Polytechnic.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1977). UK industry and the world economy: A case of de-industrialisation? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1, 113–136.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1982). The structural disequilibrium of the Tanzanian economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University, Department of Applied Economics (unpublished).

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1983a). Industrialisation, employment and basic needs in a fast-growing agrarian state: A study of the Indian Punjab (Basic Needs and Development Programme Working Paper WEP 2-32/WP4). Geneva: International Labour Organisation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1983b). The present crisis of the Tanzanian economy: Notes on the economics and politics of devaluation. Cambridge: Cambridge University, Department of Applied Economics (unpublished).

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1986). Tanzania and the IMF: The analytics of alternative adjustment programmes. In B. Van Arkadie (Ed.), External finance and policy adjustment in Africa [Special issue]. Development and Change, 17(3), 425–454.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1990a). The institution of a stock market in a socialist economy: Notes on the Chinese economic reform programme. In D. Fureng & P. Nolan (Eds.), The Chinese economy and its future: Achievements and problems of post-Mao reforms (pp. 162–178). Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., (1990b.) Global rules and a new golden age: Southern competition, labour standards and industrial development in the North and the South. In US Dept of Labor (Ed.), Labor standards, development and the global economy. Washington, DC: US Department of Labor.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1991). The stock market and economic development: Should developing countries encourage stock markets? Cambridge: Faculty of Economics, University of Cambridge. Retrieved from http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/54927/.

  • Singh, A. (1993). The stock market and economic development: Should developing countries encourage stock markets? UNCTAD Review, 4(1), 1–74.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1994). The state and industrialisation in India: Successes and failure and the lessons for the future. University of Cambridge. Retrieved from https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/54986/1/MPRA_paper_54986.pdf.

  • Singh, A. (1995a). ‘Close’ vs. ‘strategic’ integration with the world economy and the ‘market-friendly approach to development’ vs. an ‘industrial policy’: A critique of the World Development Report 1991 and an alternative policy perspective (MPRA Paper No. 53562). Retrieved from http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/53562/.

  • Singh, A. (1995b). Review of Adrian Wood, North–South trade employment and inequality. Economic Journal, 105(432), 1287–1289.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1996a). The world economy under the market supremacy model and third world industrialisation. Indian Economic Journal, 44(1), 1–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1996b). The plan, the market and evolutionary economic reform in China. In A. Abdullah & A. R. Khan (Eds.), State, market and development: Essays in honour of Rehman Sobhan (pp. 193–230). Dhaka: Dhaka University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1996c). The stock market, the financing of corporate growth and Indian industrial development. Journal of International Finance, 4(2), 1–17.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1998). Liberalisation, the stock market and the market for corporate control: A bridge too far for the Indian economy? In I. J. Ahulwalia & I. M. D. Little (Eds.), India’s economic reform and development (pp. 169–196). New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1999a). Book review of M. Aoki, H. K. Kim, & M. Okuno-Fujiwara (Eds.), The role of government in East Asian economic development. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1997. Journal of Development Economics, 59(2), 565–572.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1999b). Global unemployment, long-run economic growth and labour market rigidities: A commentary. Special contribution in B. Debroy (Ed.), Perspectives on globalization and employment (pp. 50–69). Office of Development Studies Discussion Paper Series. New York: UNDP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (1999c). Should Africa promote stock market capitalism? Journal of International Development, 11(3), 343–367.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2000). Ajit Singh 1940–. In P. Arestis & M. C. Sawyer (Eds.), A biographical dictionary of dissenting economists (2nd ed., pp. 612–616). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2001). Income inequality in advanced economies: A critical examination of the trade and technology theories and an alternative perspective (Working Paper No. 219). Cambridge: University of Cambridge Centre for Business Research. Subsequently published in J. Ghosh & C. P. Chandrasekhar (Eds.), Work and well-being in the age of finance (pp. 349–363). New Delhi: Tulika Books (2003).

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2002). Aid, conditionality and development. Development and Change, 33(2), 295–305.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2003). Competition, corporate governance and selection in emerging markets. Economic Journal, 113, F443–F464.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2006). Stock markets and economic development. In D. A. Clark (Ed.), The Elgar companion to development studies (pp. 584–590). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2007a). Does integration of India and China with the world economy harm the US workers? A commentary on the Freeman thesis. Indian Journal of Labour Economics, 50(3), 457–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2007b). Globalisation, industrial revolutions in India and China and labour markets in advanced countries: Implications for advanced and developing economies and for national and international policies (Working Paper No. 81). Geneva: Policy Integration Department, International Labour Organisation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2007c). Capital account liberalisation, free long-term capital flows, financial crises and economic development. In A. Shaikh (Ed.), Globalization and the myths of free trade (pp. 259–287). Abingdon: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2008). Better to be rough and relevant than to be precise and irrelevant: Reddaway’s legacy to economics (Working Paper No. 379). Cambridge: Cambridge University Centre for Business Research. Retrieved from www.cbr.cam.ac.uk/fileadmin/user_upload/centre-for-business-research/downloads/working-papers/wp379.pdf.

  • Singh, A. (2009a). Better to be rough and relevant than to be precise and irrelevant: Reddaway’s legacy to economics. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33(3), 363–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A. (2009b). Tribute to Sanjaya Lall. Retrieved from https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/53365/1/MPRA_paper_53365.pdf.

  • Singh, A. (2012, October 19). Alice Amsden: An outstanding American political economist. Paper presented at the Alice Amsden Symposium, MIT.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Dhumale, R. (2004). Globalisation, technology, and income inequality: A critical analysis. In G. A. Cornia (Ed.), Inequality, growth, and poverty in an era of liberalization and globalization (pp. 145–165). Oxford: Oxford University Press for UNU-WIDER.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Ghosh, J. (1988). Import liberalisation and the new industrial strategy: An analysis of their impact on output and employment in the Indian economy. Economic & Political Weekly, XXIII(45–47), Special Number.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Hamid, J. (1992). Corporate financial structures in developing countries (IFC Technical Paper No. 1). Washington, DC: World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Singh, G. (2013). Almost steady East Asian rise: Implications for labour markets and income distribution (MPRA Paper 53028). Retrieved from https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/53028/1/MPRA_paper_53028.pdf.

  • Singh, A., Singh, A., & Weisse, B. (2000). Information technology, venture capital and the stock market (Discussion Paper in Accounting and Finance, No. AF47). Cambridge: Cambridge University Department of Applied Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Tabatabai, H. (1990). Facing the crisis: Third world agriculture in the 1980s. International Labour Review, 129(4), 479–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Tabatabai, H. (1992). Agriculture and economic development in the 1990s: A new analytical and policy agenda. International Labour Review, 131(4–5), 405–430.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Tabatabai, H. (Eds.). (1993). Economic crisis and third world agriculture. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Weisse, B. (1998). Emerging stock markets, portfolio capital flows and long-term economic growth: Micro and macroeconomic perspectives. World Development, 26(4), 607–622.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Weisse, B. (1999). The Asian model: A crisis foretold? International Social Science Journal, 51(160), 203–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Whittington, G. (1968). Growth, profitability and valuation: A study of United Kingdom quoted companies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Zammit, A. (2000). The global labour standards controversy: Critical issues for developing countries. Geneva: South Centre.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Zammit, J. A. (2003). Globalisation, labour standards and economic development (CBR Working Paper 257). Cambridge: Cambridge Centre for Business Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Singh, A., & Zammit, J. A. (2004). Labour standards and the ‘race to the bottom’: Re-thinking globalization and workers’ rights from developmental and solidaristic perspectives (CBR Working Paper 279). Cambridge: Cambridge Centre for Business Research.

    Google Scholar 

  • Solis, L. (1981). Economic policy reform in Mexico: A case study for developing countries. New York: Pergamon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sraffa, P. (1926). The laws of returns under competitive conditions. Economic Journal, 36(144), 535–550.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Targetti, F. (1992). Nicholas Kaldor: The economics and politics of capitalism as a dynamic system. Oxford: Clarendon Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Targetti, F. (2005). Nicholas Kaldor: Key contributions to development economics. Development and Change, 36(6), 1185–1200.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • The Times (2015, July 14). Obituary: Ajit Singh. The Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thirlwall, A. (1987). Nicholas Kaldor. New York: New York University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsuru, S. (1993). Japan’s capitalism: Creative defeat and beyond. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ul Haq, I., Amjad, R., & Mahmood, M. (2015, June 26). In memoriam: Professor Ajit Singh. Friday Times. www.thefridaytimes.com/tft/in-memoriam-professor-ajit-singh/.

  • Van Arkadie, B. (Ed.). (1986). External finance and policy adjustment in Africa [Special issue]. Development and Change, 17(3).

    Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1898). Why is economics not an evolutionary science? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 12(3), 373–397.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Veblen, T. (1904). The theory of business enterprise. New York: Charles Scribners.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whittington, G. (2016). Wit and empirical rigour in pursuing debate. In G. C. Harcourt, The legacy of Ajit Singh (11 September 1940–23 June 2015): Memories and tributes from former pupils, colleagues and friends. The Economic and Labour Relations Review, 27(3), 302–303.

    Google Scholar 

  • Young, A. A. (1928). Increasing returns and economic progress. Economic Journal, 38(152), 527–542.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Saith, A. (2019). Economics as Concentrated Politics. In: Ajit Singh of Cambridge and Chandigarh. Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-12422-9_7

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-12422-9_7

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-12421-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-12422-9

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics