Advertisement

Theoretical Framework

  • Farhad Gohardani
  • Zahra Tizro
Chapter
Part of the Political Economy of Islam book series (PEoI)

Abstract

The importance of institutions in the process of socio-economic development is being increasingly acknowledged in the literature on socio-economic development, liberalization, privatization, and the economics of emerging markets. Rodrik (2007), for instance, sees the market systems being embedded in five nonmarket institutions of property rights, regulations, macroeconomic stabilization, social insurance, and conflict resolution. The emergence of institutions is linked to the notion of social capital. With regard to the centrality of the notion of capital in development, the literature on development can be mapped on a conceptual space moving from natural capital, to physical and financial capital, human capital, and ultimately to social capital. The role of social capital and its main component, trust, is highlighted as the key prerequisite for the establishment of a stable institutional path towards sustainable socio-economic development (see Tilly 2005; Platteau and Peccoud 2010; Uslaner 2018, among others).

As a developing country, Iran has benefited from, for example, rich reservoirs of natural resources, strategic geographical positioning, almost uninterrupted stream of oil revenues, and reasonable amount of physical and human capital. Despite starting its leap for development with Japan in the second half of the nineteenth century, the gap in the level of development between the two countries could not be greater, largely due to constant socio-political instability (see Aisen and Veiga 2013) and intermittent episodes of small- and large-scale social upheavals experienced in Iran (Foran 1994; Azimi 2008).

Bibliography

  1. Ackerly, B., & Bajpai, R. (2017). Comparative Political Thought. Methods in Analytical Political Theory. Cambridge: CUP.Google Scholar
  2. Adcock, C. S. (2010). Sacred Cows and Secular History: Cow Protection Debates in Colonial North India. Comparative Studies of South Asia, Africa and the Middle East, 30(2), 297–311.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  3. Adib-Moghaddam, A. (2013). On the Arab Revolts and the Iranian Revolution: Power and Resistance Today. London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
  4. Aisen, A., & Veiga, F. J. (2013). How Does Political Instability Affect Economic Growth? European Journal of Political Economy, 29, 151–167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  5. Ajodani, M. (2008). Masoud Loghman’s Interview with Mashallah Ajodani (in Persian). Retrieved May 17, 2013, from: Part 1: http://news.gooya.com/politics/archives/2008/08/075980.php. Part 2: http://news.gooya.com/politics/archives/2008/09/076661.php.
  6. Alexander, J., Eyerman, R., Giesen, B., Semelser, N., & Sztompka, P. (2004). Cultural Trauma and Collective Identity. Los Angeles: University of California Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  7. Alvesson, M., & Sköldberg, K. (2000/2009). Reflexive Methodology: New Vistas for Qualitative Research. London: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
  8. Arthur, W. B. (2015). Complexity and the Economy. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  9. Austin, J. L. (1962/1975). How to Do Things with Words. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  10. Azimi, H. (2003). Today’s Iran in the Mirror of Ideas About Development (in Persian). Tehran: Daftar-e nashr-e farhang-e Islami.Google Scholar
  11. Azimi, F. (2008). The Quest for Democracy in Iran: A Century of Struggle Against Authoritarian Rule. London: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  12. Babu, P. G., & Mahendra Dev, S. (Eds.). (2016). Development in India: Micro and Macro Perspectives. New York: Springer.Google Scholar
  13. Barthes, R. (1981). Camera Lucida: Reflections on Photography. New York: Hill and Wang.Google Scholar
  14. Bass, A. (2006). Interpretation and Difference: The Strangeness of Care. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
  15. Becker, E. (1973). The Denial of Death. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
  16. Berlin, I. (1990). In H. Hardy (Ed.), The Crooked Timber of Humanity: Chapters in the History of Ideas. London: John Murray.Google Scholar
  17. Bhabha, H. K. (1988). The Commitment to Theory. New Formations, 5, 5–23.Google Scholar
  18. Bhabha, H. K. (1990). The Third Space. In J. Rutherford (Ed.), Identity Community, Culture, Difference. London: Lawrence & Wishart.Google Scholar
  19. Billig, M. (1995). Banal Nationalism. London: Sage.Google Scholar
  20. Billig, M. (1999). Freudian Repression: Conversation Creating the Unconscious. Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  21. Bianchi, A. (Ed.). (2015). On Reference. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  22. Blundell, B. (2010). Paul Ricoeur Between Theology and Philosophy: Detour and Return. Indiana: Indiana University Press.Google Scholar
  23. Boothby, R. (1991). Death and Desire: Psychoanalytic Theory in Lacan’s Return to Freud. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  24. Boothby, R. (2001). Freud as Philosopher: Metapsychology After Lacan. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  25. Brassier, R. (2007). Nihil Unbound: Enlightenment and Extinction. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  26. Brinkmann, S. (2013). Qualitative Interviewing. Oxford: OUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  27. Bryant, L. R. (2011). The Democracy of Objects. Michigan: University of Michigan Library.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  28. Buelens, G., Durrant, S., & Eaglestone, R. (Eds.). (2014). The Future of Trauma Theory: Contemporary Literary and Cultural Criticism. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  29. Burt, R. S. (2004). Structural Holes and Good Ideas. The American Journal of Sociology, 110(2), 349–399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  30. Cavell, S. (1988). In Quest of the Ordinary: Lines of Skepticism and Romanticism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  31. Chakrabarty, D. (2000). Provincializing Europe: Postcolonial Thought and Historical Difference. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  32. Chandler, D. (2007). Semiotics: The Basics. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  33. Chang, H.-J. (1994). The Political Economy of Industrial Policy. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
  34. Chang, R. (Ed.). (1997). Incommensurability, Incomparability, and Practical Reason. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  35. Christoforou, A., & Davis, J. B. (Eds.). (2014). Social Capital and Economics: Social Values, Power, and Social Identity. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  36. Colebrook, C. (2009). Introduction: Post-Structuralism, Postmodernism and Historicism. In J. A. Bell & C. Colebrook (Eds.), Deleuze and History. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  37. Connolly, W. E. (2008a). Capitalism and Christianity, American Style. Durham, NC: Duke University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  38. Dabashi, H. (2011). The Green Movement in Iran. New Jersy: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
  39. Dabashi, H. (2013). Being a Muslim in the World. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  40. David, P. A. (1985). Clio and the Economics of QWERTY. The American Economic Review, 75, 332–337.Google Scholar
  41. David, P. A. (2007). Path Dependence: A Foundational Concept for Historical Social Science. Cliometrica. Journal of Historical Economics and Econometric History, 1(2), 91–114.Google Scholar
  42. Dawkins, R. (1976). The Selfish Gene. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  43. DeLanda, M. (2006). A New Philosophy of Society: Assemblage Theory and Social Complexity. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
  44. DeLanda, M. (2016). Assemblage Theory. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  45. Deleuze, G., & Guattari, F. (1987). A Thousand Plateaus: Capitalism and Schizophrenia. London: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
  46. Derrida, J. (1983). The Principle of Reason: The University in the Eyes of Its Pupils. Diacritics, 13(3), 2–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  47. Dixit, A. (2004). Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  48. Dixit, A. (2016). Corruption: Supply-Side and Demand-Side Solutions. In S. Mahendra Dev & P. G. Babu (Eds.), Development in India: Micro and Macro Perspectives (pp. 57–70). New York: Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  49. Dreyfus, Hubert L. (1972/2011). What Computers Cant Do. New York: BiblioBazaar.Google Scholar
  50. Dreyfus, H. L. (1991). Being-in-the-World: A Commentary on Heidegger’s Being and Time. London: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  51. Dreyfus, H. L. (2001). On the Internet. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  52. Dreyfus, H., & Taylor, C. (2015). Retrieving Realism. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  53. Durlauf, Steven N. (2012). Complexity, Economics, and Public Policy in Politics, Philosophy & Economics, 11(1) 45–75.Google Scholar
  54. Easterly, W. (2001). The Lost Decades: Developing Countries’ Stagnation in Spite of Policy Reform 1980–1998. Journal of Economic Growth, 6(2), 135–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  55. Easterly, W. (2007a). Was Development Assistance a Mistake? AER, 97(2), 328–332.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  56. Easterly, W. (2007b). The Ideology of Development. Foreign Policy, 161, 30–35.Google Scholar
  57. Easterly, W. (2014). The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators, and the Forgotten Rights of the Poor. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  58. Eco, U. (1976). A Theory of Semiotics. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  59. Fafchamps, M. (2017). Formal and Informal Market Institutions: Embeddedness Revisited. Retrieved July 30, 2018, from http://globalpoverty.stanford.edu/sites/default/files/publications/596wp.pdf.
  60. Fine, B. (2010). Theories of Social Capital: Researchers Behaving Badly. London: Pluto. (IIPPE)Google Scholar
  61. Fink, B. (1997). A Clinical Introduction to Lacanian Psychoanalysis: Theory and Technique. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  62. Flynn, T. R. (2005). Sartre, Foucault, and Historical Reason: Poststructuralist Mapping of History (Vol. 2). Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  63. Foran, J. (Ed.). (1994). A Century of Revolution. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
  64. Foster, J., & Hölzl, W. (Eds.). (2004). Applied Evolutionary Economics and Complex Systems. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing.Google Scholar
  65. Foucault, M. (1980). Power/Knowledge: Selected Interviews and Other Writings, 1972–1977. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
  66. Foucault, M. (1981). On Revolution. Philosophy and Social Criticism, 1(1981), 5–9.Google Scholar
  67. Foucault, M. (1984). The Foucault Reader (P. Rabinow, ed.). New York: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
  68. Freud, S. (1922/2010). Beyond the Pleasure Principle. Montana: Kessinger Publishing.Google Scholar
  69. Fukuyama, F. (2000). Social Capital and Civil Society. Washington: International Monetary Fund.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  70. Fukuyama, F. (2018). Identity: The Demand for Dignity and the Politics of Resentment. New York: Farrar Straus and Giroux.Google Scholar
  71. Geary, J. (2011). I Is an Other: The Secret Life of Metaphor and How It Shapes the Way We See the World. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
  72. Geertz, C. (1973). The Interpretation of Cultures: Selected Essays. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
  73. Ghamari-Tabrizi, B. (2016). Foucault in Iran: Islamic Revolution After the Enlightenment. London: University of Minnesota Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  74. Gier, N. F. (1981). Wittgenstein and Phenomenology: A Comparative Study of the Later Wittgenstein, Husserl, Heidegger, and Merleau-Ponty. Albany: Sunny Press.Google Scholar
  75. Gigerenzer, G., & Selten, R. (Eds.). (2002). Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox. London: The MIT Press.Google Scholar
  76. Gohardani, F., & Tizro, Z. (2018). From Where My Vote Is to Where My Bread Is: Why We Need to Make Peace with Our Rulers (in Persian). BBC Persian. http://www.bbc.com/persian/blog-viewpoints-42604270.
  77. Guala, F. (2016). Understanding Institutions: The Science and Philosophy of Living Together. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  78. Hairi Yazdi, M. (1992). The Principles of Epistemology in Islamic Philosophy: Knowledge by Presence. New York: SUNY Press.Google Scholar
  79. Hansen, M. (2000). Becoming as Creative Involution? Contextualizing Deleuze and Guattari’s Biophilosophy. Postmodern Culture, 11(1). https://dx.doi.org/10.1353/pmc.2000.0032.
  80. Hardt, M., & Negri, A. (2001). Empire. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  81. Harris, E. E. (1987). Formal, Transcendental and Dialectical Thinking: Logic and Reality. New York: Sunny Press.Google Scholar
  82. Harrison, N. E. (Ed.). (2006). Complexity in World Politics: Concepts and Methods of a New Paradigm. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
  83. Haynes, P. (2012). Immanent Transcendence: Reconfiguring Materialism in Continental Philosophy. London: Bloomsbury.Google Scholar
  84. Hedlund, S. (2005). Russian Path Dependence: A People with a Troubled History. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  85. Hegel, G. W. F. (2010). The Science of Logic. Cambridge: CUP.Google Scholar
  86. Higgs, R. (1987). Crisis and Leviathan: Critical Episodes in the Growth of American Government. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  87. Highmore, B. (2006). Michel de Certeau: Analysing Culture. London: Continuum.Google Scholar
  88. Hirschman, A. O. (1984). Against Parsimony: Three Easy Ways of Complicating Some Categories of Economic Discourse. The American Economic Review, 74(2), 89–96.Google Scholar
  89. Hodgson, G. M. (2001). How Economics Forgot History: The Problem of Historical Specificity in Social Science. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  90. Hodgson, G. M. (2004). The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure, and Darwinism in American Institutionalism. London: Routledge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  91. Hodgson, G. M. (2013). Understanding Organizational Evolution: Toward a Research Agenda Using Generalized Darwinism. Organization Studies, 34(7), 973–992.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  92. Hodgson, G. M., & Knudsen, T. (2010). Darwin’s Conjecture: The Search for General Principles of Social and Economic Evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  93. Hollway, W., & Jefferson, T. (2013). Doing Qualitative Research Differently: Free Association, Narrative and the Interview Method. London: Sage.Google Scholar
  94. Hooker (Ed.). (2011). Philosophy of Complex Systems. Oxford: North Holland.Google Scholar
  95. Houlgate, S. (1999). Hegel’s Critique of Foundationalism in the Doctrine of Essence. In A. O’Hear (Ed.), German Philosophy Since Kant (pp. 25–46). Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  96. Howarth, D. R. (2010). Pluralizing Methods: Contingency, Ethics, and Critical Explanation. In A. Finlayson (Ed.), Democracy and Pluralism: The Political Thought of William E. Connolly. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  97. Hoy, D. C. (1993). Heidegger and the Hermeneutic Turn. In C. B. Guignon (Ed.), The Cambridge Companion to Heidegger. Cambridge: CUP.Google Scholar
  98. Hunter, S. (2005). Islam, Modernization, and Democratization: The Case of Iran. In S. Hunter & H. Malik (Eds.), Modernization, Democracy, and Islam (pp. 253–276). London: Praeger.Google Scholar
  99. Hurd, E. S. (2010). Iran, in Search of a Nonsecular and Nontheocratic Politics. Public Culture, 22(1), 25–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  100. Inwood, M. (1992). A Hegel Dictionary. Oxford: Blackwell.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  101. Jafarian, R. (2017). The Genealogy of the Idea of Islamic Civilization from the Constitutional Revolution to the Islamic Revolution (in Persian). Khabaronline. Retrieved February 17, 2017, from http://www.khabaronline.ir/detail/637237/weblog/jafarian.
  102. Jamshidian Tehrani, J. (2014). Shu’ubiyya: Independence Movements in Iran (in Persian). Luxembourg: CreateSpace Independent Publishing Platform.Google Scholar
  103. Kalb, D. (2006). Uses of Local Knowledge. In R. E. Goodin & C. Tilly (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Contextual Political Analysis. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  104. Karpik, L. (2010). Valuing the Unique: The Economics of Singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  105. Katsafanas, P. (2005). Nietzsche’s Theory of Mind: Consciousness and Conceptualization. European Journal of Philosophy, 13(1), 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  106. Knack, S., & Keefer, P. (1997). Does Social Capital Have an Economic Pay-Off? A Cross-Country Investigation. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 112(4), 1251–1288.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  107. Kripke, S. A. (1980). Naming and Necessity. London: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
  108. Kuran, T. (2004). Islam and Mammon: The Economic Predicaments of Islamism. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  109. Kuran, T. (2011). The Long Divergence: How Islamic Law Held Back the Middle East. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  110. Lechte, J. (1994). Fifty Key Contemporary Thinkers. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  111. Le Guin, U. K. (2004). The Wave in the Mind: Talks and Essays on the Writer, the Reader, and the Imagination. Boston: Shambhala Publications.Google Scholar
  112. Levitt, S. D., & Dubner, S. J. (2006). Freakonomics: A Rogue Economist Explores the Hidden Side of Everything. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
  113. Lincoln, B. (2007). Religion, Empire, and Torture: The Case of Achaemenian Persia. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  114. Lorraine, T. (1999). Irigaray and Deleuze: Experiments in Visceral Philosophy. New York: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
  115. Lorraine, T. (2010). Lines of Flights. In A. Parr (Ed.), The Deleuze Dictionary. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  116. MacIntyre, A. (1988). Whose Justice? Which Rationality? Notre Dame: University of Notre Dame Press.Google Scholar
  117. Mahmood, S. (2005). Politics of Piety: The Islamic Revival and the Feminist Subject. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  118. Mahoney, James (2001). Path-Dependent Explanations of Regime Change: Central America in Comparative Perspective, in Studies in Comparative International Development, 36(1): 111–141.Google Scholar
  119. Mahoney, J., & Schensul, D. (2006). Historical Context and Path Dependence. In R. E. Goodin & C. Tilly (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Contextual Political Analysis. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  120. Manganaro, M. (2002). Culture, 1922: The Emergence of a Concept. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  121. Matin-Asgari, A. (2004). The Intellectual Best-Sellers of Postrevolutionary Iran: On Backwardness, Elite-Killing, and Western Rationality. Iranian Studies, 37(1), 73–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  122. Mauss, M. (1923/1990). The Gift: The Form and Reason for Exchange in Archaic Societies (W. D. Halls, trans., with foreword by Mary Douglas). London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  123. Moris, Z. (2003/2012). Revelation, Intellectual Intuition and Reason in the Philosophy of Mulla Sadra: An Analysis of the al-hikmah al-‘arshiyyah. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  124. Morag, T. (2012). Doing Without Ontology: A Quinean Pragmatist Approach to Badiou. In S. Bowden & S. Duffy (Eds.), Badiou and Philosophy (pp. 132–156). Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  125. Mosekilde, E., Maistrenko, Y., & Postnov, D. (2002). Chaotic Synchronization: Applications to Living Systems. London: World Scientific Publishing.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  126. Munkler, H. (2007). Empires: The Logic of World Domination from Ancient Rome to the United States. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  127. Myers, T. (2003). Slavoj Zizek. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  128. Nasr, S. H. (1996). Mulla Ṣadra: His Teachings. In History of Islamic Philosophy, I–II (pp. 1139–1174). London and New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  129. North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  130. North, D. (2005). Understanding the Process of Economic Change. Princeton: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  131. Ogden, T. H. (1994). Subjects of Analysis. London: Karnac Books.Google Scholar
  132. Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding Institutional Diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  133. Ostrom, E. (2013). Do Institutions for Collective Action Evolve? Journal of Bioeconomics, 16(1), 3–30.  https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-013-9154-8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  134. Ostrom, E., & Basurto, X. (2011). Crafting Analytical Tools to Study Institutional Change. Journal of Institutional Economics, 7(3), 317–343.  https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137410000305.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  135. Parker, I. (2008). Japan in Analysis: Cultures of the Unconscious. London: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  136. Parr, A. (Ed.). (2010). The Deleuze Dictionary (revised ed.). Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  137. Patton, P. (2000). Deleuze and the Political. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  138. Pick, D. (2012). The Pursuit of the Nazi Mind: Hitler, Hess, and the Analysts. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  139. Pierson, P. (2000). Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics. The American Political Science Review, 94(2), 251–267.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  140. Pierson, P. (2004). Politics in Time. History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton: University Presses of California.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  141. Platteau, J.-P., & Peccoud, R. (Eds.). (2010). Culture, Institutions, and Development: New Insights Into an Old Debate. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
  142. Putnam, R. D. (2002). Democracies in Flux: The Evolution of Social Capital in Contemporary Society. Oxford: OUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  143. Rajaee, F. (2006). The Problematic of Iranian Contemporary Identity: Participation in the World of One Civilization and Many Cultures (in Persian). Tehran: Nashr-e Ney.Google Scholar
  144. Rajaee, F. (2007). Islamism and Modernism: The Changing Discourse in Iran. Austin: University of Texas Press.Google Scholar
  145. Ricoeur, P. (1981). Hermeneutics and the Human Sciences. Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  146. Rodgers, D. T., Raman, B., & Reimitz, H. (Eds.). (2014). Cultures in Motion. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  147. Rodrik, D. (2007). One Economics, Many Recipes: Globalization, Institutions, and Economic Growth. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  148. Rodrik, D. (2015). Economics Rules: Why Economics Works, When It Fails, and How to Tell the Difference. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  149. Rorty, R. (1979). Philosophy and the Mirror of Nature. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  150. Rose, J., & Shulman, G. (2016). The Non-Linear Mind: Psychoanalysis of Complexity in Psychic Life. London: Karnac Books.Google Scholar
  151. Rothenberg, M. A. (2010). The Excessive Subject: A New Theory of Social Change. Cambridge: Polity Press.Google Scholar
  152. Sandel, M. J. (2012). What Money Can’t Buy: The Moral Limits of Markets. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
  153. Sawyer, R. K. (2005). Social Emergence: Societies as Complex Systems. Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  154. Schear, J. K. (Ed.). (2013). Mind, Reason, and Being-in-the-World: The McDowell-Dreyfus Debate. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  155. Schmid, H. B., Schulte-Ostermann, K., & Psarros, N. (2008). Concepts of Sharedness. Frankfurt: Ontos.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  156. Schwab, G. (2010). Haunting Legacies: Violent Histories and Transgenerational Trauma. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  157. Schwab, G. (2012). Imaginary Ethnographies: Literature, Culture, and Subjectivity. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
  158. Scruton, R. (1996/2016). Philosophy: Principles and Problems. London: Bloomsbury Academic.Google Scholar
  159. Sepehri, S. (1976/2010). Eight Books (in Persian). Tehran: Sa’ye-ye Nima.Google Scholar
  160. Shayegan, D. (1997). Cultural Schizophrenia: Islamic Societies Confronting the West. London: Syracuse University Press.Google Scholar
  161. Shayegan, D. (2012). La Conscience métisse (Bibliothèque Idées). Paris: Albin Michel.Google Scholar
  162. Spinks, L. (2010). Nietzsche, Friedrich (1844–1900). In A. Parr (Ed.), The Deleuze Dictionary. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  163. Stavrakakis, Y. (1999). Lacan and the Political. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  164. Stavrakakis, Y. (2007). The Lacanian Left: Psychoanalysis, Theory, Politics. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  165. Stiglitz, J. E. (1996). Some Lessons from the East Asian Miracle. The World Bank Research Observer, 11(2), 151–177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  166. Surin, K. (2010). Materialism + Philosophy. In A. Parr (Ed.), The Deleuze Dictionary Revised Edition. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
  167. Tavakoli-Targhi, M. (2001). Refashioning Iran: Orientalism, Occidentalism, and Historiography. Basingstoke: Palgrave.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  168. Taylor, C. (2001). Two Theories of Modernity. In D. Gaonkar (Ed.), Alternative Modernities. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
  169. Taylor, C. (2016). The Language Animal: The Full Shape of the Human Linguistic Capacity. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  170. Thurow, L. C. (1993). Head to Head. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
  171. Tilly, C. (2005). Trust and Rule. Cambridge: CUP.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  172. Tilly, C. (2006). Why and How History Matters. In R. E. Goodin & C. Tilly (Eds.), The Oxford Handbook of Contextual Political Analysis. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  173. Tizro, Z. (2012). Domestic Violence in Iran: Women, Marriage and Islam. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  174. Tønder, L., & Thomassen, L. (2005). Radical Democracy: Politics Between Abundance and Lack. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
  175. Uslaner, E. M. (Ed.). (2018). The Oxford Handbook of Social and Political Trust. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
  176. Wade, R. (1990). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
  177. Williamson, O. E. (2000). The New Institutional Economics: Taking Stock, Looking Ahead. Journal of Economic Literature, 38(3), 595–613.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  178. Williamson, O. E. (2005). The Economics of Governance. The American Economic Review, 95(2), 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  179. Williamson, O. E. (2010). Transaction Cost Economics: The Natural Progression. American Economic Review, 100, 673–690.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  180. Wittgenstein, L. (1953/2009). Philosophical Investigations. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
  181. World Bank. (2005). Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  182. World Bank. (2015). World Development Report 2015: Mind, Society, and Behavior. Washington, DC: World Bank.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  183. Zizek, S. (1989/2008). The Sublime Object of Ideology. London: Verso.Google Scholar
  184. Zizek, S. (1997/2007). Against the Politics of Jouissance. http://www.lacan.com/zizliberal.htm.
  185. Zizek, S. (2001). On Belief. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
  186. Zizek, S. (2006). The Parallax View. London: The MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
  187. Zizek, S. (2011). Year of Distraction. Retrieved May 18, 2013, from http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=ChWXYNxUFdc&list=PL72E4D1A96C77C76E.
  188. Zizek, S. (2012). Less than Nothing: Hegel and the Shadow of Dialectical Materialism. London: Verso.Google Scholar

Copyright information

© The Author(s) 2019

Authors and Affiliations

  • Farhad Gohardani
    • 1
  • Zahra Tizro
    • 2
  1. 1.Independent EconomistYorkUK
  2. 2.University of East London (UEL)LondonUK

Personalised recommendations