Skip to main content

Financialization, Fields, and Change

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Book cover Financialization as Welfare
  • 309 Accesses

Abstract

In this chapter, Golka develops his theoretical argument on the use of field theory for the study of financialization processes. Golka compares the explanatory horizon of prominent sociological field theories, particularly neo-institutional theories and Fligstein and McAdam’s strategic action fields theory, for the case of financialization. His analysis reveals the merits of strategic action fields theory over other field theories, but also shows how its lack of a mechanism to explain the emergence of cooperative ties as a result of skilled social action severely constrains the theory’s explanatory potential. To address this void, Golka draws on recent theorizing of pragmatist mechanisms.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    I understand financial actors as those engaged in investment and speculation, in the sense of Knorr-Cetina (2009). Empirically, these are most frequently financial intermediaries.

  2. 2.

    There are two important strands in the literature that I will ignore. First, issue fields (Hoffman 1999) which provide a more discursive and thus less functionalist definition of fields in comparison to DiMaggio and Powell (1983) and Scott (1987). This way, field dynamics can be understood as closely linked to membership dynamics. Nevertheless, issue field theory relies on a similarly problematic conception of agency as much of neo-institutional theory (see below). These problems are equally prominent in institutional logics theory (Reay and Hinings 2005; Thornton et al. 2012) albeit in a slightly different coloring. Assuming relatively homogenous field-level logics that are in coherence with the rationality criteria posed by the “society as an inter-institutional system” perspective and stabilized through individual-level cognitive scripts and schemas, the theory under-estimates the continuous creative capacities of human agency (Joas 1996) and resulting conflict in favor of a rather consensualist (albeit dynamic) view of institutions and fields (Fligstein and McAdam 2012, pp. 10–12).

  3. 3.

    There are more reasons why these theories are not suitable for our endeavor. One is that, being located in organizational theory, most scholarship uses these theories to explain organizational outcomes, e.g. as changes in “templates” (Battilana et al. 2009). However, my interest is more broadly located on the field level and includes positions, relations, and resources in addition to forms of organizing.

  4. 4.

    I consider the conception of IGUs as one of the weaker parts of SAF theory, both theoretically and empirically. Theoretically, this somewhat functionalist construction partially contradicts the strict emphasis on social construction that prevails in the theory. If stable periods are achieved through mobilization and frame resonance, while at the same time all actors possess social skill, why would we then expect a norm-following organization such as IGUs constitutive of fields? Empirically, it has, for example in the case of intra-organizational equal opportunities officers, been shown how IGUs that were initially created by incumbent actors to maintain their rules in the face of growing criticism may develop an organizational interest in their own right that eventually alters the rules of the field contrary to incumbents’ interest (Dobbin 2009). Ultimately, upholding such a theoretically defined conception of IGUs would thus require us to ex ante define those as low skilled, interest-less, non-strategic actors, contradicting the theory’s assumption on the existential role of the social. For these reasons, as well as the fact that in the case of SII, trade associations can rather be considered as the very competing actors, I will disregard such a conception of IGUs for the remainder of this book.

  5. 5.

    I have two concerns with their perspective. First, assuming that we “seek out instrumental gain, social status, and power […] because we want to prove to ourselves and others that we are worthy as people” (p. 46) fails to acknowledge that the construction of worth is socially contingent (Boltanski and Thévenot 2006; Stark 2011) and thus can hardly be assumed as a motivational force. As Beckert (2003) and Joas (1996) have shown, and as the authors themselves frequently point out, ends are constructed in social processes. It thus seems incorrect and contradictory to assume the cause of these different actions in their common motivational dimension. Second, noting that “by ‘winning,’ we confirm to ourselves and others that life is not meaningless” (p. 46) incorrectly assumes a motivational basis for winning. As my previous work has shown, faced with a situation where winning coincides with losing money, the “value of winning” is highly dependent upon an individual’s hormonal testosterone levels (Van Den Bos et al. 2013).

  6. 6.

    Note that this does not imply that financializing state actions are always the result of financial actors’ strategic efforts vis-à-vis the state. Sometimes these actions are intended to achieve different goals but have led to increased financialization in markets (e.g. Krippner 2011, or Fligstein 1990, Chap. 5). That said, it seems to be the case that in the past decades, in many cases, state actions appear to be directed towards and lobbied for by financial actors (e.g. Langenohl and Wetzel 2011). As I will show in the longitudinal chapter, the growth of impact investing in the UK serves as a case in point here.

  7. 7.

    Of course, changes in nonfinancial actors’ action patterns are not based on cooperation alone: unilateral dependencies exist. My point here is twofold: first, I am only interested in situations where such unilateral dependencies do not (yet) exist, as is for example the case in field emergence or invasion by outside actors. Second, I argue that even where nonfinancial actors are critically dependent on financial actors’ resources, they do not necessarily fully subjugate to financial actors’ interests. Thus, there is room for nonfinancial actors’ agency here, which needs to be understood in more detail.

  8. 8.

    This creates the contradiction that entrepreneurship is and is not an ability of the individual. This may be resolved by assuming entrepreneurship to be an individual ability conditioned by situations on the field level. I suspect that this is what the authors had in mind here.

  9. 9.

    Tilly’s work was highly influential for the work of McAdam, particularly through his contributions to episodes of contention, the development of the challenger/incumbent model from Gamson (1975), as well as the introduction of Harrison White’s network-theoretical concept of “catnets” (White 1970).

  10. 10.

    Although the ability to learn empathy appears to be bound by biological factors such as prenatal testosterone levels: individuals with higher prenatal testosterone levels appear to be less empathetic, more motivated by money, and more successful in competitive financial professions (Baron-Cohen 2002; Coates and Herbert 2008; Eisenegger et al. 2011).

References

  • Fligstein, N., & McAdam, D. (2011). Toward a general theory of strategic action fields. Sociological Theory, 29(1), 1–26.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ansell, C. K. (2001). Schism and solidarity in social movements: The politics of labor in the French third republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Aoki, M. (2001). Towards a comparative institutional analysis. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Baron-Cohen, S. (2002). The extreme male brain theory of autism. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 6(6), 248–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battilana, J., & Dorado, S. (2010). Building sustainable hybrid organizations: The case of commercial microfinance organizations. Academy of Management Journal, 53(6), 1419–1440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battilana, J., & Lee, M. (2014). Advancing research on hybrid organizing: Insights from the study of social enterprises. Academy of Management Annals, 8(1), 397–441.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Battilana, J., Leca, B., & Boxenbaum, E. (2009). How actors change institutions: Towards a theory of institutional entrepreneurship. Academy of Management Annals, 3(1), 65–107.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (1996). What is sociological about economic sociology? Uncertainty and the embeddedness of economic action. Theory and Society, 25(6), 803–840.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2003). Economic sociology and embeddedness: How shall we conceptualize economic action? Journal of Economic Issues, 37(3), 769–787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2010). How do fields change? The interrelations of institutions, networks, and cognition in the dynamics of markets. Organization Studies, 31(5), 605–627.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2011). Die sittliche Einbettung der Wirtschaft. Von der Effizienz-und Differenzierungstheorie zu einer Theorie wirtschaftlicher Felder. Berliner Journal für Soziologie, 22(2), 247–266.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beckert, J. (2016). Imagined futures. Fictional expectations and capitalist dynamics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Benford, R. D., & Snow, D. A. (2000). Framing processes and social movements: An overview and assessment. Annual Review of Sociology, 26(1), 611–639.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, P. L., & Luckmann, T. (1966). The social construction of reality: A treatise in the sociology of knowledge. London: Penguin Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blyth, M. (2010). On setting and upsetting agendas. In A. Gofas & C. Hay (Eds.), The role of ideas in political analysis: A portrait of contemporary debates (pp. 167–186). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boltanski, L., & Thévenot, L. (2006). On justification: Economies of worth. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Botzem, S., & Dobusch, L. (2017). Financialization as strategy: Accounting for inter-organizational value creation in the European real estate industry. Accounting, Organizations and Society, 59, 31–43.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P. (1998). The state nobility: Elite schools in the field of power. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourdieu, P., & Wacquant, L. J. (1992). An invitation to reflexive sociology. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coates, J. M., & Herbert, J. (2008). Endogenous steroids and financial risk taking on a London trading floor. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 105(16), 6167–6172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crouch, C. (2011). The strange non-death of neo-liberalism. Cambridge: Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • De Tocqueville, A. (1856). L’ancien Régime et la Révolution. Paris: Michel Lévy.

    Google Scholar 

  • Deeg, R., & Jackson, G. (2007). Towards a more dynamic theory of capitalist variety. Socio-Economic Review, 5(1), 149–179.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dewey, J. (1922). Human nature and conduct: An introduction to social psychology. New York: Henry Holt and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diaz-Bone, R. (2015). Die “Economie des conventions”: Grundlagen und Entwicklungen in der neuen französischen Wirtschaftssoziologie. Wiesbaden: Springer VS.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. (1988). Interest and agency in institutional theory. In L. G. Zucker (Ed.), Institutional patterns and organizations (pp. 1–21). Cambridge, MA: Ballinger.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. (1991). Constructing an organizational field as a professional project: U.S. art museums, 1920-1940. In M. Powell & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P., & Powell, W. (1983). The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48, 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dobbin, F. (2009). Inventing equal opportunity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Dowling, E., & Harvie, D. (2014). Harnessing the social: State, crisis and (big) society. Sociology, 48(5), 869–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Edelman, L. B. (1992). Legal ambiguity and symbolic structures: Organizational mediation of civil rights law. American Journal of Sociology, 97(6), 1531–1576.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenegger, C., Haushofer, J., & Fehr, E. (2011). The role of testosterone in social interaction. Trends in Cognitive Sciences, 15(6), 263–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisenstadt, S. N. (1980). Cultural orientations, institutional entrepreneurs, and social change: Comparative analysis of traditional civilizations. American Journal of Sociology, 85(4), 840–869.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eisinger, P. K. (1973). The conditions of protest behavior in American cities. American Political Science Review, 67(1), 11–28.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emirbayer, M., & Mische, A. (1998). What is agency? American Journal of Sociology, 103(4), 962–1023.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feist, M., & Fuchs, D. (2014). Was heißt hier nachhaltig? In M. Heires & A. Nölke (Eds.), Politische Ökonomie der Finanzialisierung (pp. 225–240). Wiesbaden: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Fiss, P. C., & Zajac, E. J. (2004). The diffusion of ideas over contested terrain: The (non) adoption of a shareholder value orientation among German firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 49(4), 501–534.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (1990). The transformation of corporate control. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2001a). The architecture of markets: An economic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2001b). Social skill and the theory of fields. Sociological Theory, 19(2), 105–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2008). Fields, power and social skill: A critical analysis of the new institutionalisms. International Public Management Review, 9(1), 227–253.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N. (2013). Understanding stability and change in fields. Research in Organizational Behavior, 33, 39–51.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fligstein, N., & McAdam, D. (2012). A theory of fields. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Forst, R. (2015b). Noumenal power. The Journal of Political Philosophy, 23(2), 111–127.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fourcade, M. (2007). Theories of markets and theories of society. American Behavioral Scientist, 50(8), 1015–1034.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedland, R., & Alford, R. R. (1991). Bringing society back in: Symbols, practices and institutional contradictions. In W. Powell & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 232–263). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gamson, W. A. (1975). The strategy of social protest. Homewood, IL: Dorsey Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Giddens, A. (1984). The constitution of society: Outline of the theory of structuration. Cambridge: Blackwell, Polity Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goffman, E. (1959). The presentation of self in everyday life. Garden City, NY: Doubleday.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goffman, E. (1973). Frame analysis: An essay on the organization of experience. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldstone, J. A. (2004). More social movements or fewer? Beyond political opportunity structures to relational fields. Theory and Society, 33(3), 333–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin, J., & Jasper, J. M. (1999). Caught in a winding, snarling vine: The structural bias of political process theory. Paper presented at the Sociological forum.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, R., & Hinings, C. R. (1996). Understanding radical organizational change: Bringing together the old and the new institutionalism. Academy of Management Review, 21(4), 1022–1054.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gross, N. (2009). A pragmatist theory of social mechanisms. American Sociological Review, 74(3), 358–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Habermas, J. (1981). Theorie des kommunikativen Handelns band 1: Handlungsrationalität und gesellchaftliche Rationalisierung. Frankfurt am Main: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, P. A., & Soskice, D. (2001). Varieties of capitalism: The institutional foundations of comparative advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hardy, C., & Maguire, S. (2010). Discourse, field-configuring events, and change in organizations and institutional fields: Narratives of DDT and the Stockholm convention. Academy of Management Journal, 53(6), 1365–1392.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, D. (2005). A brief history of neoliberalism. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hedström, P., & Swedberg, R. (1998). Social mechanisms: An analytical approach to social theory. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hiß, S. (2006). Warum übernehmen Unternehmen gesellschaftliche Verantwortung? Frankfurt am Main: Campus.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hiß, S. (2013). The politics of the financialization of sustainability. Competition & Change, 17(3), 234–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, A. J. (1999). Institutional evolution and change: Environmentalism and the US chemical industry. Academy of Management Journal, 42(4), 351–371.

    Google Scholar 

  • James, W. (1907/1975). Pragmatism: A new name for some old ways of thinking. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Joas, H. (1996). The creativity of action (J. Gaines & P. Keast, Trans.). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kingdon, J. (1995). Agendas, alternatives, and public policies. New York: HarperCollins College Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kluttz, D. N., & Fligstein, N. (2016). Varieties of sociological field theory. In S. Abrutyn (Ed.), Handbook of contemporary sociological theory (pp. 185–204). Cham: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Knoll, L. (2012). Über die Rechtfertigung wirtschaftlichen Handelns: CO2-Handel in der kommunalen Energiewirtschaft. Wiesbaden: Springer VS.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Knorr-Cetina, K. (2009). What is a financial market? In J. Beckert & C. Deutschmann (Eds.), Wirtschaftssoziologie (Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 49) (pp. 326–342). Wiesbaden: VS-Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krippner, G. R. (2011). Capitalizing on crisis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kurzman, C. (1996). Structural opportunity and perceived opportunity in social-movement theory: The Iranian revolution of 1979. American Sociological Review, 61(1), 153–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Langenohl, A., & Wetzel, D. (2011). Finanzmärkte und ihre Sinnformen: Handlungskoordination und Signalkommunikation. Berliner Journal für Soziologie, 21(4), 539–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, T. B., Suddaby, R., & Leca, B. (Eds.). (2009). Institutional work: Actors and agency in institutional studies of organization. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lawrence, T. B., Suddaby, R., & Leca, B. (2011). Institutional work: Refocusing institutional studies of organization. Journal of Management Inquiry, 20(1), 52–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazonick, W., & O’Sullivan, M. (2000). Maximizing shareholder value: A new ideology for corporate governance. Economy and Society, 29(1), 13–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leifer, E. M. (1995). Making the majors: The transformation of team sports in America. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • MacKenzie, D. (2016). A material political economy: Automated trading desk and price prediction in high-frequency trading. Social Studies of Science, 47(2), 172–194.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maguire, S., Hardy, C., & Lawrence, T. B. (2004). Institutional entrepreneurship in emerging fields: HIV/AIDS treatment advocacy in Canada. Academy of Management Journal, 47(5), 657–679.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mair, J., & Marti, I. (2009). Entrepreneurship in and around institutional voids: A case study from Bangladesh. Journal of Business Venturing, 24(5), 419–435.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. L. (2003). What is field theory? American Journal of Sociology, 109(1), 1–49.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martin, J. L. (2011). The explanation of social action. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D. (1982). Political process and the development of black insurgency. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McAdam, D., Tarrow, S., & Tilly, C. (2001). Dynamics of contention. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mead, G. H. (1934). Mind, self, society. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, A. D. (1982). Adapting to environmental jolts. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27, 515–537.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W., & Rowan, B. (1977). Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony. American Journal of Sociology, 83, 340–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, J. W., & Scott, W. R. (1991). The organization of societal sectors: Propositions and early evidence. In M. Powell & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 108–140). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mische, A. (2009). Projects and possibilities: Researching futures in action. Sociological Forum, 24(3), 694–704.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pacewicz, J. (2012). Tax increment financing, economic development professionals and the financialization of urban politics. Socio-Economic Review, 11(3), 413–440.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Podolny, J. M. (1993). A status-based model of market competition. American Journal of Sociology, 98(4), 829–872.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quinn, S. L. (2010). Government policy, housing, and the origins of securitization, 1780–1968. (PhD), Berkeley, CA: University of California.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reay, T., & Hinings, C. R. (2005). The recomposition of an organizational field: Health care in Alberta. Organization Studies, 26(3), 351–384.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rule, J., & Tilly, C. (1975). Political process in revolutionary France: 1830-1832. In J. M. Merriman (Ed.), 1830 France (pp. 41–85). New York: New Viewpoints.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1987). The adolescence of institutional theory. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(4), 493–511.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1991). Unpacking institutional arguments. In W. Powell & P. DiMaggio (Eds.), The new institutionalism in organizational analysis (pp. 164–182). Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (1995). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Scott, W. R. (2001). Institutions and organizations. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Seabrooke, L. (2010). Everyday legitimacy and institutional change. In A. Gofas & C. Hay (Eds.), The role of ideas in political analysis: A portrait of contemporary debates (pp. 78–93). New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Snow, D. A., & Benford, R. D. (1988). Ideology, frame resonance, and participant mobilization. International Social Movement Research, 1, 197–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sparsam, J. (2014). Wirtschaft in der new economic sociology: Eine Systematisierung und Kritik. Wiesbaden: Springer VS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (2011). The sense of dissonance: Accounts of worth in economic life. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stinchcombe, A. L. (1998). Monopolistic competition as a mechanism: Corporations, universities, and nation-states in competitive fields. In P. Hedström & R. Swedberg (Eds.), Social mechanisms: An analytical approach to social theory (pp. 267–305). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Streeck, W. (2013). Gekaufte Zeit. Die vertagte Krise des demokratischen Kapitalismus. Frankfurt/Main: Suhrkamp.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swartz, D. (1997). Culture and power: The sociology of Pierre Bourdieu. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tarrow, S. (2011). Power in movement: Social movements and contentious politics (3rd ed.). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tavory, I., & Timmermans, S. (2014). Abductive analysis: Theorizing qualitative research. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Thornton, P. H., Ocasio, W., & Lounsbury, M. (2012). The institutional logics perspective: A new approach to culture, structure, and process. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (1978). From mobilization to revolution. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. (2001). Mechanisms in political processes. Annual Review of Political Science, 4(1), 21–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tolbert, P. S., & Zucker, L. G. (1983). Institutional sources of change in the formal structure of organizations: The diffusion of civil service reform, 1880-1935. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28, 22–39.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turk, H. (1977). Organizations in modern life. San Francisco, CA: Jossey-Bass.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Den Bos, W., Golka, P. J., Effelsberg, D., & McClure, S. M. (2013). Pyrrhic victories: The need for social status drives costly competitive behavior. Frontiers in Neuroscience, 7, 1–11.

    Google Scholar 

  • Van der Zwan, N. (2014). Making sense of financialization. Socio-Economic Review, 12(1), 99–129.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vedres, B., & Stark, D. (2010). Structural folds: Generative disruption in overlapping groups. American Journal of Sociology, 115(4), 1150–1190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vitols, S. (2002). Shareholder value, management culture and production regimes in the transformation of the German chemical-pharmaceutical industry. Competition and Change, 6(3), 309–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Warren, R. L. (1967). The interorganizational field as a focus for investigation. Administrative Science Quarterly, 12, 397–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weber, M. (1921/2002). Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft: Grundriss der verstehenden Soziologie. Tübingen: Mohr Siebeck.

    Google Scholar 

  • White, H. C. (1970). Chains of opportunity: System models of mobility in organizations. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Wooten, M., & Hoffman, A. J. (2017). Organizational fields: Past, present and future. In R. Greenwood, C. Oliver, T. Lawrence, & R. Meyer (Eds.), The Sage handbook of organizational institutionalism (pp. 55–76). Thousand Oakes, CA: Sage.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Zucker, L. G. (1977). The role of institutionalization in cultural persistence. American Sociological Review, 42(5), 726–743.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Golka, P. (2019). Financialization, Fields, and Change. In: Financialization as Welfare. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-06100-5_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-06100-5_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-06099-2

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-06100-5

  • eBook Packages: Social SciencesSocial Sciences (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics