Skip to main content

The Emergence of the Patronage State in Central Europe: The Case of FDI-Related Policies in Hungary Since 2010

  • Chapter
  • First Online:

Part of the book series: International Political Economy Series ((IPES))

Abstract

Hungary was regarded a success story of FDI-led development model in Central and Eastern Europe during the 1990s. The country underwent fundamental economic changes which resulted in sound macroeconomic performance. Neighbouring countries could caught-up in FDI attraction instead of FDI transfers from the EU-fuelled economic growth. Critiques-dominated communication and support of selected local companies and clients increased. The capital attraction policy changed from normative to selective measures. Moreover, multinational businesses in trade, communication, and financial services were levied with various surcharges. The chapter analyses the new FDI management toolkit of the Hungarian government. The main conclusion is that the new policy is not a form of economic patriotism but rather a form of patronage in crony capitalism.

The chapter was developed within the framework of a research project supported by the Hungarian National Research, Development and Innovation Office (Grant No. 112069).

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD   139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Poland, the Czech Republic, Slovakia, and Hungary.

  2. 2.

    The term competition state is taken from Drahokoupil (2008) and refers to liberal state policies which allow global competition to penetrate domestic markets fully. I follow Schoenman (2014) in my use of the term “patronage state”, which refers to the importance of personal business–government linkages in shaping economic policies and a strong, general curtailment of competition on local markets, with the government asserting dominance over business by means of selective-advantage measures (business capture).

  3. 3.

    Some of this work has already been done and published in the literature that I will also cite in this chapter.

  4. 4.

    Drahokoupil (2008) characterises the FDI-related elite—the “comprador service sector”—and its reproduction as follows: “I characterize the domestic actors linked to FDI as the comprador service sector… (It) comprises various groups providing service for foreign investors. It includes local branches of global consulting and legal advisory firms and their local competitors, companies providing other services to foreign investors and officials from FDI-related state bodies. This group is comprador as it is structurally dependent on transnational capital, whose interests it represents. Structurally, this sector is not a bourgeoisie, as it constitutes neither a propertied class nor a professional managerial class….(Its) links to foreign capital can be characterized mainly by the Weberian notions of ‘market capacity’ and ‘income class’….the comprador service sector helps to translate the structural power of transnational capital into tactical forms of power within the states…The structural power of capital is derived from the dependency of the state and society at large on the investment decisions” (pp. 366–7) This type of dependency is also fundamental to Nölke and Vliegenthart’s (2009) DME model.

  5. 5.

    The career of Gábor Széles is a good example of this. Until 1990, he was the president of Műszertechnika Coop, a small firm producing electronic devices for the Hungarian market. His firm was one of the two lucky Hungarian companies which formed a winning coalition with the Swedish company Ericsson for a tender to produce electronic switching centres for the Hungarian wired telephone network in 1992—that is, before the appearance of cellular services. Despite this opportunity, Műszertechnika could not establish itself as a significant player in electronics. Széles then lobbied for another, less technology-intensive opportunity; he ended up participating in the privatisation of the large Hungarian bus producer Ikarus. He also acquired the large Hungarian electronics firm Videoton. Neither of these projects turned out to be successful, insofar as these firms’ original industrial activities could not be maintained. Today, both companies operate primarily as real-estate development agencies and component producers. Széles used to be a high-ranking official in the MDF (Hungarian Democratic Forum), the larger party in the right-wing coalition which formed Hungary’s first post-communist government in 1990. These days, Széles is the owner of a right-wing-oriented media network.

  6. 6.

    The most striking action was the introduction of the “Lex MOL”, an amendment to the commercial code which changed corporate-governance regulations so as to help the Hungarian oil company repel a takeover bid by its Austrian competitor ÖMW. These legal changes were passed—barely—with the mutual agreement of the government and the opposition.

  7. 7.

    The other main source of investment financing was EU transfers. Hungarian national sources’ share was rather small.

  8. 8.

    Documents related to various government officials’ media communications about the ideological differentiation between “good, productive” and “bad, speculative” business have been analysed by Mihályi (2015) and TIH (2014).

  9. 9.

    The Magyar Külkereskedelmi Bank Rt. (Hungarian Foreign-Trade Bank Co.) was owned by the Hungarian affiliate of Bayerische Landesbank until 2014.

  10. 10.

    The government explained this measure by suggesting the company was guilty of tax evasion. However, it was never explained whether there was anything illegal about RTL’s tax returns; even if there was, why would such irregularities not have been addressed by the appropriate state authority, the tax office?

  11. 11.

    It is of course another question whether today’s sales revenues are sufficiently high for the necessary investments. Observers have suggested that public utility companies are still in extremely bad financial condition and do not invest anymore, which may compromise the quality of their services.

  12. 12.

    A full transcript of these interviews was published in Szanyi (2016b).

References

  • Antalóczy, K., & Sass, M. (2015). Through Glass Darkly: The Content of Statistical Data on Foreign Direct Investment. Studies in International Economics, 1(1), 34–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Antalóczy, K., Sass, M., & Szanyi, M. (2011). Policies for Attracting Foreign Direct Investment and Enhancing Its Spillovers to Indigenous Firms: The Case of Hungary. In E. Rugraff & M. W. Hansen (Eds.), Multinational Corporations and Local Firms in Emerging Economies (pp. 181–210). Amsterdam: University Press.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Boycko, M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. (1996). A Theory of Privatization. The Economic Journal, 106(3), 309–319.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clift, B., & Woll, C. (2012). Economic Patriotism: Reinventing Control Over Open Markets. Journal of European Public Policy, 19(3), 307–323.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drahokoupil, J. (2008). Who Won the Contest for a New Property Class? Structural Transformation of Elites in the Visegrád Four Region. Journal for East European Management Studies, 13(4), 360–377.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Drahokoupil, J., Van Apeldorn, B., & Horn, L. (2008). Introduction. In B. Van Apeldorn, J. Drahokoupil, & L. Horn (Eds.), Contradictions and Limits of Neoliberal European Governance: From Lisbon to Lisbon. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. (1988). The Eclectic Paradigm if International Production – A Restatement and Some Possible Extensions. Journal of International Business Studies, 19(1), 1–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. (2001). The Eclectic (OLI) Paradigm of International Production: Past, Present and Future. International Journal of the Economics of Business, 8(2), 173–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frydman, R., & Rapaczynski, A. (1994). Privatization in Eastern Europe: Is the State Withering Away? Budapest: Central European University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Helleiner, E., & Pickel, A. (Eds.). (2005). Economic Nationalism in a Globalizing World. Itacha: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iwasaki, I., & Tokunaga, M. (2014). Macroeconomic Impacts of FDI in Transition Economies: A Meta-Analysis. World Development, 61(9), 53–69.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kalotay, K., & Sass, M. (2012, October 18). Inward FDI in Hungary and Its Policy Context. Columbia FDI Profiles. Vale Columbia Center on Sustainable International Investment.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kozarzewski, P., & Baltowski, M. (2016). Change in Economic Policy Paradigm: Privatization and State Capture in Poland. CASE Research Paper No. 3, p. 127.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laki, M. (2002). A nagyvállalkozók tulajdonszerzési esélyeiről a szocializmus után (About Chances of Obtaining Property by Entrepreneurs After Socialism). Közgazdasági Szemle (Economic Review-Monthly of the Hungarian Academy of Sciences), 49.1(2002), 45–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laki, M., & Szalai, J. (2013). Tíz évvel később – a magyar nagyvállalkozók európai környezetben [Ten Years After: Hungarian Entrepreneurs in European Environment]. Budapest: Közgazdasági Szemle Alapítvány.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levy, J. (Ed.). (2006). The State After Statism: New State Activities in the Age of Liberalization. Oxford: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McDermott, G. A. (2002). Embedded Politics: Industrial Networks and Institutional Change in Post-Communism. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Mihályi, P. (2010). A Magyar privatizáció enciklopédiája [Encyclopedia of Hungarian Privatization]. Budapest: Pannon Egyetemi Könyvkiadó – MTA KTI, 1–2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mihályi, P. (2015). A privatizált vagyon visszaállamosítása Magyarországon 2010–2014 [Re-nationalization of Privatized Property in Hungary 2010–2014]. KTI Discussion Paper, MTDP 2015/7.

    Google Scholar 

  • Naczyk, M. (2014, July 15). Budapest in Warsaw: Central European Business Elites and the Rise of Economic Patriotism Since the Crisis. Sciences Po Paris. http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2550496

  • Nölke, A., & Vliegenthart, A. (2009). Enlarging the Varieties of Capitalism: The Emergence of Dependent Market Economies in East Central Europe. World Politics, 61(4), 670–702.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapaczynski, A. (1996). The Roles of State Property and the Market in Establishing Property Rights. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 10(2), 87–103.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schoenman, R. (2014). Networks and Institutions in Europe’s Emerging Markets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D. (1996). Recombinant Property in East European Capitalism. American Journal of Sociology, 101(4), 492–504.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stark, D., & Bruszt, L. (1998). Postsocialist Pathways: Transforming Politics and Property in East Central Europe. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szanyi, M. (1996). Adaptive Steps by Hungary’s Industries During the Transition Crisis. Eastern European Economics, 34(5), 59–77.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szanyi, M. (2002, May). Spillover Effects and Business Linkages of Foreign-Owned Firms in Hungary. IWE Working Paper No. 126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szanyi, M. (2003, December). An FDI-Based Development Model for Hungary – New Challenges? IWE Working Paper No. 141.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szanyi, M. (2016a). The Reversal of the Privatization Logic in Central European Transition Economies: An Essay. Acta Oeconomica, 66(1), 33–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Szanyi, M. (2016b). The FDI-led Development Model Revisited? IWE Working Paper No. 220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Szentes, T. (Ed.) (2005–2006). Fejlődés, versenyképesség, globalizáció [Development, Competitiveness, Globalization]. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó.

    Google Scholar 

  • TIH. (2014). Lifting the Lid on Lobbying. Strategic Partnership Agreements in an Uncertain Business and Regulatory Environment. National Report of Hungary, Transparency International Hungary.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yakovlev, A. (2006). The Evolution of Business – State Interaction in Russia: From State Capture to Business Capture? Europe-Asia Studies, 58(07), 1033–1056.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Miklós Szanyi .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Szanyi, M. (2019). The Emergence of the Patronage State in Central Europe: The Case of FDI-Related Policies in Hungary Since 2010. In: Gerőcs, T., Szanyi, M. (eds) Market Liberalism and Economic Patriotism in the Capitalist World-System. International Political Economy Series. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-05186-0_6

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics