Skip to main content

Commodities, Consumption and Production

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
  • 385 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter introduces the mathematical foundations for models of economies in which economic wealth is generated through a social division of labour. We introduce the notion of an economic commodity, separating consumables that have use value from intermediary inputs in production processes. All wealth creation processes are performed through consumer-producers, a mathematical representation of a rational decision-maker, who produces as well as consumes economic commodities: consumer-producers form the building blocks of any mathematical theory of the social division of labour. We also consider two mathematical models of the fundamental property of Increasing Returns to Specialisation (IRSpec) in human productive abilities. The chapter concludes with surprising insights from decision-making by consumer-producers in (standard) economic trade environments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution.

Buying options

Chapter
USD   29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD   39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD   54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Learn about institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    The sociality or networking capabilities of an economic agent are very hard to represent through appropriately selected mathematical constructs. The chosen network representation seems to be the most plausible, although it remains less than perfect.

  2. 2.

    This is derived from the introduction of an economic agent as the embodiment of the social brain hypothesis as well as an individualistic bearer of productive and consumptive abilities. We refer to Gilles (2018, Chapter 1) for more details.

  3. 3.

    Yang (2001) formulates the principle of Increasing Returns to Specialisation through his mathematical conception of “inframarginal analysis”. This refers to the determination of optimal production planning through exploration of the corners of the assigned production set.

  4. 4.

    Note here that the definition of an economic commodity implies that the delivery of such goods is explicitly a social task. It is through the prevailing trade infrastructure in the foundation of the socio-economic space that such commodities can be provided. It is not an individual task to make this delivery possible; rather it is communal or social. Of course, such provision can be executed by individual economic agents, but ontologically it is a task of the whole socio-economic trade infrastructure to deliver this commodity.

  5. 5.

    A more general setup is to represent preferences as a mathematical relation on the consumption space \(\mathcal {C}\). This approach lies at the foundation of general equilibrium theory, representing the fundamental theory of the competitive market mechanism. I refer to Debreu (1959), Hildenbrand (1974), and Jehle and Reny (2000) for a complete development of this mathematical theory.

  6. 6.

    For details on this standard analysis of utility functions and representation of preferences, I refer to, e.g., Jehle and Reny (2000, Chapters 1–3).

  7. 7.

    The abbreviation “CES” stands for Constant Elasticity of Substitution. For an elaborate discussion of this property we refer to any textbook on microeconomics, such as Chung (1994, Chapter 5) and Kreps (2013, Chapter Two).

  8. 8.

    The consumer-producer representation of an economic agent describes the variables that are solely under the control of an individual economic agent. In particular, one can view the utility function as a descriptor of the objectives of the individual economic agent and the agent’s production set as a descriptor of the abilities of this agent to meet these objectives. The latter essentially represent the constraints put on the agent’s choice set.

  9. 9.

    We emphasise that the Cobb–Douglas utility function used here does not in principle satisfy the conditions imposed in Axiom 1.5, since the Cobb–Douglas utility function is not strictly monotone on the boundary \(\partial \mathcal {C} = \{ (x,y) \mid x=0\) or y = 0} of the consumption space. The computational advantages of the Cobb–Douglas utility function are rather significant, since its specification affords us simple formulations of solutions to utility maximisation problems.

  10. 10.

    We refer to the discussion in the concluding section of the next chapter for an elaboration of this point.

  11. 11.

    Regarding to the quantities traded in the market we use the convention that x t > 0 is a net quantity demanded, while x t < 0 represents a net quantity supplied.

References

  • Cheng, W., and X. Yang. 2004. Inframarginal Analysis of Division of Labor: A Survey. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 55: 137–174.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chung, J.W. 1994. Utility and Production Functions: Theory and Applications. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Debreu, G. 1959. Theory of Value. New York, NY: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diamantaras, D., and R.P. Gilles. 2004. On the Microeconomics of Specialization. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 55: 223–236.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H., and H. Haller. 2017. Groups and Markets: General Equilibrium with Multi-member Households. Berlin: Springer.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P. 2018. Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour: I-Institutions and Trust. London: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • —. 2019. Market Economies with an Endogenous Social Division of Labour. International Economic Review (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P., and D. Diamantaras. 2003. To Trade or Not to Trade: Economies with a Variable Number of Tradeables. International Economic Review 44: 1173–1204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gilles, R.P., E.A. Lazarova, and P.H.M. Ruys. 2007. Stability, Specialization and Social Recognition. Division of Labour and Transaction Costs 2 (2): 83–109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • —. 2015. Stability in a Network Economy: The Role of Institutions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 119: 375–399.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harari, Y.N. 2014. Sapiens: A Brief History of Humankind. London: Vintage Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hildenbrand, W. 1974. Core and Equilibria of a Large Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ito, Y., and M. Kaneko. 1981. Linearization of Cost Functions in Public Goods Economies. Economic Studies Quarterly 32: 237–246.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jehle, G.A., and P.J. Reny. 2000. Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Boston, MA: Addison Wesley Longman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kreps, D.M. 2013. Microeconomic Foundations I: Choice and Competitive Markets. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lancaster, K.J. 1966. A New Approach to Consumer Theory. Journal of Political Economy 74: 132–157.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. 1867. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy — Volume I: The Process of Production of Capital, 1967 ed. New York, NY: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plato. 380 BCE. Republic, 2007 ed. London: Penguin Classics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rader, J.T. 1964. Edgeworth Exchange and General Economic Equilibrium. Yale Economic Essays 4: 182–180. Reprinted in T. Rader (1996), Economics with No special Technology: Posthumous Essays and Selected Articles. Newcastle-upon-Tyne: Input-Output Publishing Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, A. 1776. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Reprint 1976.

    Google Scholar 

  • von Stackelberg, H. 1934. Marktform und Gleichgewicht. Habilitation, University of Vienna.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wen, M. 1998. An Analytical Framework of Consumer-Producers, Economies of Specialization and Transaction Costs. In Increasing Returns and Economic Analysis, ed. K.J. Arrow, Y.-K. Ng, and X. Yang. New York, NY: St. Martin’s Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yang, X. 1988. A Microeconomic Approach to Modeling the Division of Labor Based on Increasing Returns to Specialization. Ph.D. thesis, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ.

    Google Scholar 

  • —. 2001. Economics: New Classical Versus Neoclassical Frameworks. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • —. 2003. Economic Development and the Division of Labor. Malden, MA: Blackwell Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yao, S. 2002. Walrasian Equilibrium Computation, Network Formation, and the Wen Theorem. Review of Development Economics 6: 415–427.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert P. Gilles .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Gilles, R.P. (2019). Commodities, Consumption and Production. In: Economic Wealth Creation and the Social Division of Labour. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04426-8_1

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-04426-8_1

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-04425-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-04426-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics