Skip to main content

Can Buyer Consortiums Improve Supplier Compliance?

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Revisiting Supply Chain Risk

Part of the book series: Springer Series in Supply Chain Management ((SSSCM,volume 7))

Abstract

When suppliers (i.e., contract manufacturers) fail to comply with environmental or safety regulations, several non-governmental agencies and consumer activists put pressure on the buyers (customers) to take necessary actions to improve supplier compliance. Due to concerns over negative image and public boycotts, many buyers conduct costly audits to improve supplier compliance. By considering a common practice that calls for independent audits (i.e., each buyer performs its own audit) as a benchmark, we examine the implications of joint audit mechanism arising from a buyer consortium. Under this mechanism, buyers conduct joint audits by sharing the joint audit cost and impose a collective penalty on the supplier if the supplier fails their joint audit. We evaluate the efficacy of joint audits against the commonly practiced independent audits. Our analysis reveals that the joint audit mechanism is beneficial in two important ways. First, it can make the supplier increase its compliance level in equilibrium. Second, the joint audit mechanism can increase the supply chain profit when the audit cost is below a certain threshold.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 139.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 179.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    To reduce the exposure to broad legal liability, Walmart, Target, and other US retailers are developing a different accord for improving factory safety.

  2. 2.

    An alternative audit mechanism is the shared audit mechanism in which the buyers conduct their audits independently, but share their audit reports eventually. We omit the discussion of the shared audit mechanism in this chapter due to space considerations. We refer the reader to (Caro et al. 2015) for the analysis of shared audits.

  3. 3.

    Throughout this chapter, we shall use the superscripts I and J to denote the equilibrium outcomes under independent and joint audits, respectively.

  4. 4.

    As defined by Harsanyi (1982b), a “payoff-dominant” equilibrium is Pareto superior to all other equilibria. Therefore, when faced with a choice among equilibria, the payoff-dominance selection rule assumes that all players would agree on the payoff-dominant equilibrium since it offers to each player at least as much payoff as the other equilibria. The rule is also shown to be risk dominant.

  5. 5.

    To maintain the consistency of each buyer’s self-interest, our noncooperative unanimity game enables us to preserve the noncooperative framework throughout this chapter. If we were to adopt the nash bargaining (NB) solution concept in a cooperative framework, then it is easy to observe that this optimization problem will yield the same nash bargaining solution; see Harsanyi (1982b).

References

  • Babich, V., & Tang, C. S. (2012). Managing opportunistic supplier product adulteration: Deferred payments, inspection, and combined mechanisms. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 14(2), 301–314.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Babich, V., Burnetas, A. N., & Ritchken, P. H. (2007). Competition and diversification effects in supply chains with supplier default risk. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 9(2), 123–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caro, F., & Tang, C. S. (2014). Reducing collateral damages by imposing collective penalties. UCLA Anderson School Global Supply Chain Blog.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caro, F., Chintapalli, P., Rajaram, K., & Tang, C. S. (2015). Improving supplier compliance through joint and shared audits. Unpublished manuscript, UCLA Anderson School, available at SSRN 2683515.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caro, F., Chintapalli, P., Rajaram, K., & Tang, C. S. (2018). Improving supplier compliance through joint and shared audits with collective penalty. Manufacturing & Service Operations Management, 20(2), 363–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chopra, S., & Sodhi, M. S. (2004). Managing risk to avoid supply-chain breakdown. MIT Sloan Management Review.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demick, B. (2013). Explosion at chinese auto parts factory kills 68, injured many more. Los Angeles Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Donaldson, T. (2014). Bangladesh resetting the bar on compliance standards. The Sourcing Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fuller, T., & Bradsher, K. (2013). Deadly collapse in cambodia renews safety concerns. New York Times.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1982a). Solutions for some bargaining games under the Harsanyi-Selten solution theory, part I: Theoretical preliminaries. Mathematical Social Sciences, 3(2), 179–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1982b). Solutions for some bargaining games under the Harsanyi-Selten solution theory, part II: Analysis of specific bargaining games. Mathematical Social Sciences, 3(3), 259–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hendricks, K. B., & Singhal, V. R. (2005). An empirical analysis of the effect of supply chain disruptions on longrun stock price performance and equity risk of the firm. Production and Operations Management, 14(1), 35–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kapner, S., & Banjo, S. (2013). U.S. retailers near pact on bangladesh factory safety. The Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kim, S. H. (2015). Time to come clean? disclosure and inspection policies for green production. Operations Research, 63(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Orsdemir, A., Hu, B., & Deshpande, V. (2015). Responsible sourcing via vertical integration and supply chain partnership. Working paper, UNC Chapel Hill Kenan-Flagler Business School, available at SSRN 2630733.

    Google Scholar 

  • Plambeck, E. L., & Taylor, T. (2015). Supplier evasion of a buyer’s audit: Implications for motivating compliance with labor and environmental standards. To appear in Manufacturing & Service Operations Management.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rui, H., & Lai, G. (2015). Sourcing with deferred payment and inspection under supplier product adulteration risk. Production and Operations Management, 24(6), 934–946.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sodhi, M. S., & Tang, C.S. (2012). Managing supply chain risk, (Vol. 172). Springer Science: Business Media.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sodhi, M. S., Son, B.-G., & Tang, C. S. (2012). Researchers’ perspectives on supply chain risk management. Production and Operations Management, 21(1), 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tang, C. S. (2006). Perspectives in supply chain risk management. International Journal of Production Economics, 103(2), 451–488.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tang, C. S. (2013). Helping the poorest link in the chain: Bangladesh’s garment factory workers. UCLA Anderson School Global Supply Chain Blog.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tang, C. S., & Babich, V. (2014). Using social and economic incentives to discourage chinese suppliers from product adulteration. Business Horizons, 57(4), 497–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tomlin, B. (2006). On the value of mitigation and contingency strategies for managing supply chain disruption risks. Management Science, 52(5), 639–657.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Van Mieghem, J. V. (1999). Coordinating investment, production, and subcontracting. Management Science, 45(7), 954–971.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wong, C. H., & Fung, E. (2015). More toxic goods stored near Tianjin homes. The Wall Street Journal.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Professors Gregory Leblanc and Terry Taylor of University of California, Berkeley, for discussing the joint audit mechanism and the notion of collective penalty with one of the authors.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Felipe Caro .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

5 Appendix—Proofs

5 Appendix—Proofs

Proof of Lemma 1. The first statement follows from the fact that \(2 r \ge 1\) and (6). To prove the second statement, first observe that \(z^I = \frac{x^I}{2r}\). Hence, it suffices to show the result for \(z^I\) and when \(\alpha \ge \beta \) (otherwise, \(z^I\) is constant). In preparation, we claim that \(\displaystyle \beta \ge \frac{3 mr^2}{2 (1 + r)}\). To prove this claim, we apply (7) to show this equality holds if and only if \(d(2r^2+r-1)+m(1-2r) \ge 0\). By using the fact that \(2r \ge 1\) and by applying Assumption 2, we prove the claim by showing that \(d(2r^2+r-1)+m(1-2r) \ge (d-m)(2r - 1) \ge 0\). Now we prove \(z^I\) is increasing in d for any \(\alpha \ge \beta \ge \frac{3 mr^2}{2 (1 + r)}\). By differentiating \(z^I\) with respect to d, \(z^I\) is indeed increasing in d because \(\alpha \ge \frac{3 mr^2}{2 (1 + r)}\). This proves the second statement. The third, fourth, and the fifth statements can be proven by direct differentiation with respect to \(\alpha \) and \(\gamma \), respectively. We omit the details.\(\blacksquare \)

Proof of Lemma 2. The proof follows the same approach as the proof for Lemma 1. We omit the details.\(\blacksquare \)

Proof of Proposition 3. Because \(x^I = 2r z^I\) and \(x^J = 2r z^J\), it suffices to show that \(z^J \ge z^I\). From (6) and (13), \(z^J \ge z^I\) if and only if \(\frac{2dr +(d-m)}{\alpha +4r(d-m)} \ge \frac{dr +(d-m)}{2 \alpha +3r(d-m)}\). This inequality holds when \(3dr\alpha +\alpha (d-m) + r(d-m)\big (m + d(2r-1)\big ) \ge 0\). This last inequality holds because \(r \ge 1/2\) due to Assumptions 13.\(\blacksquare \)

Proof of Proposition 4. Observe from (9) and (15) that, after some algebra,

$$\begin{aligned} \pi _s^J(z^J) - \pi _s^I(z^I)&= 2 (g + w) z^I - 4 r (g+w) {z^I}^2 - 2(g+w) z^J \nonumber \\&\quad + 4 r (g+w) {z^J}^2 + 4 r^2 ({z^I}^2 - {z^J}^2) \gamma , \nonumber \\&= 2(g+w) \left[ z^I(1 - r z^I) - z^J( 1 - r z^J) \right] \le 0. \end{aligned}$$
(16)

The last inequality follows immediately by using three facts: (a) the parabola \(y(1-ry)\) attains its maximum when \(y = \frac{1}{2r}\); (b) \(z^I \le z^J\) (Proposition 3); and (c) both \(z^I\) and \(z^J\) are less than \(\frac{1}{2r}\) (c.f. Eqs. (6) and (13)).\(\blacksquare \)

Proof of Proposition 5. By the assumption of individual rationality, the buyers operate under the joint audit mechanism only if \(\Pi ^J(z^J)\ge 0\).

Now, suppose that \(0 \le \Pi ^J(z^J) < \Pi ^J(z^I)\). Then \( \big (\Pi ^J(z^J)-\Pi ^I\big )^2 < \big (\Pi ^J(z^I)-\Pi ^I\big )^2\), where \(\Pi ^I\) are the profits if negotiations fail. But this would be a contradiction because \(z^J\) is the optimal solution to (12). Hence, \( \Pi ^J(z^J) \ge \Pi ^J(z^I) = \Pi ^I(z^I) + \frac{\alpha }{2} (z^I)^2 \ge \Pi ^I(z^I)\) and the proof is complete. \(\blacksquare \)

Proof of Proposition 6. To compare the supply chain profit under both mechanisms, it suffices to examine the supply chain profit gap \(\Delta _{SC}\), where \( \Delta _{SC} \equiv [2 \Pi ^J(z^J) + \pi _s^J(z^J)] - [2 \Pi ^I(z^I) + \pi _s^I(z^I)]\). After some algebra, we have that:

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta _{SC}&= \alpha (z^I)^2 + ( z^J - z^I) \{ 2 (d - m + 2 d r - 2 r \gamma ) \\&\quad - ({ z^J} + { z^I}) \left( \alpha + 4 r (d - m - r \gamma ) \right) \} \\&= \alpha [ \sqrt{2} \cdot z^I - z^J][ \sqrt{2} \cdot z^I + z^J] + ( z^J - z^I) \\&\quad \{ 2 (d - m + 2 d r - 2 r \gamma ) - ({ z^J} + { z^I}) \left( 4 r (d - m - r \gamma ) \right) \}\\&= ( z^J - z^I) \bigg [ \alpha [ \sqrt{2} \cdot z^I + z^J] \left( \frac{\sqrt{2} \cdot z^I - z^J}{z^J - z^I} \right) + 2 (d - m + 2 d r - 2 r \gamma ) \bigg . \\&\quad \bigg . - ({ z^J} + { z^I}) \left( 4 r (d - m - r \gamma ) \right) \bigg ] \end{aligned}$$

Hence, the sign of \(\Delta _{SC}\) depends on the term in squared brackets since from Proposition 3, we know that \(z^J \ge z^I\). It can be shown that

$$\begin{aligned}&\lim _{\alpha \rightarrow \infty } \bigg [ \alpha [ \sqrt{2} \cdot z^I + z^J] \left( \frac{\sqrt{2} \cdot z^I - z^J}{z^J - z^I} \right) + 2 (d - m + 2 d r - 2 r \gamma ) \bigg . \\&\quad \bigg . - ({ z^J} + { z^I}) \left( 4 r (d - m - r \gamma ) \right) \bigg ]\\&= \frac{d^2(1 + 4r + 5 r^2) - 2 d (m + 2 m r + 2 r(1+ 3r) \gamma ) + m(m+ 4 r \gamma ) }{d - m + 3 d r} \\&= \frac{f(d)}{d - m + 3 d r} \end{aligned}$$

where \(f(d) = d^2(1 + 4r + 5 r^2) - 2 d (m + 2 m r + 2 r(1+ 3r) \gamma ) + m(m+ 4 r \gamma )\), a quadratic in d with roots \(\displaystyle \frac{2 r (\gamma +m)+m+6 \gamma r^2 \pm r \sqrt{ -m^2+4 \gamma m (r+1)+4 (\gamma +3 \gamma r)^2 }}{1 + r (5 r+4)}\). The roots are real if and only if, \(g(m) = -m^2 + 4 m (1 + r) \gamma + 4 ( \gamma + 3 r \gamma )^2 > 0\). Note that \(g(0)> 0\), so f has real roots for m sufficiently small. Note also that \(f(m) = m r^2 (5 m - 12 \gamma )\) and \(f^\prime (m) = 2 r (2 m- 2 \gamma + 5 m r - 6 r \gamma )\), so we have that

$$\begin{aligned}&f(m)> 0 \Rightarrow 5 m - 12 \gamma> 0 \Rightarrow 2 m - 2 \gamma + 5 m r - 6 r \gamma> 2 m - 2 \gamma \\&\quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad \quad + 12 r \gamma - 6 r \gamma = 2 m - 2 \gamma + 6 r \gamma \\&= 2 m + 2 \gamma (3 r -1)> 0 \Rightarrow f^\prime (m) > 0, \end{aligned}$$

where we have used the fact that \(2r>1\). This implies that f(d) has at most one root \(d^*\) in the region \(d>m\) because \(f(m) > 0\) and \(f^\prime (m) < 0\) cannot hold simultaneously as shown above. Further, \(d^*\) exists if and only if \(f(m)< 0 \Leftrightarrow m < \frac{12 \gamma }{5}\) (i.e., m is small). Finally, if \(d< d^*\) (i.e., d is small), then \(f(d) < 0\). This proves the result. \(\blacksquare \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2019 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Caro, F., Chintapalli, P., Rajaram, K., Tang, C.S. (2019). Can Buyer Consortiums Improve Supplier Compliance?. In: Zsidisin, G., Henke, M. (eds) Revisiting Supply Chain Risk. Springer Series in Supply Chain Management, vol 7. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03813-7_11

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics