Keywords

1 Introduction

Social license to operate (SLO) as a term was perceived by a Canadian mining executive during the 1990s (Fraser Institute 2012; Prno 2013), and since then it has become an important requirement for the sustainability of several projects. The main scope of this chapter is to present a model for the evaluation of renewable energy projects from the standpoint of social license to operate and social acceptance using a decision support system (DSS). The model used is based on multi-criteria decision analysis (MCDA) and the multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT). Subject DSS incorporates different sustainability indicators as these could be applied to renewable energy projects (REPs). For the purposes of this chapter, the term SLO will refer to the level of acceptance and/or approval by local communities and stakeholders of REPs and their operations (Kamenopoulos et al. 2015a). Compliance with legal regulations may not be the only precondition in the case of REPs; societies may be very doubtful when dealing with a REP, and the lack of faith to policymakers is continuously under reassessment. Stakeholders grant an SLO to a REP when they feel that their values/preferences and those of the REP’s company are aligned (Govindan et al. 2014). As a result an SLO is not a permanent treaty, but a dynamic social contract which is contingent on the dynamic changes of multiple stakeholders’ preferences; it is dynamic because stakeholders’ perceptions can change over time for different reasons (Nelsen 2006); also it could be revoked, and it should never be taken for granted (Kemp et al. 2006). Adaptability is required to manage the complexity associated with the founding and preserving an SLO and sustainable operations (Prno 2013); the absence of the SLO downgrades the possibility of sustainable REP operations; this is how the SLO is straightforward interconnected/influenced through the current sustainable development practices. As we may see in Fig. 1, sustainable development (SD) practices are the origins of a valid and constant SLO. When a REP is under development, the preferences of involved stakeholders (e.g., local societies, nongovernmental organizations (NGOs), market, government, etc.) are under continuous transformation. Adaptability requires continuous monitoring of stakeholder preferences in every stage of a REP project in order to ensure that the project remains within the sustainable path and the SLO is still valid. Under this continuous “monitoring” process, the decision-makers of a REP may ascertain their decisions on a “GO-NO-GO” frame, adjust policies in accordance with the stakeholders’ preferences, and evaluate the project. The notion behind monitoring of stakeholder preferences shall be in such way that preferences are decoded into measurable components within a holistic tool which is flexible and adaptable and continuously supports decision-making.

Fig. 1
A flow chart on communication between renewable energy companies depicts the good and bad quality. Clear communication, criteria, indicators to R E P, sustainable R E P, and social license to operate. Fuzzy communication, loss of information, renewable energy, difficulty in obtaining, keeping S L O, risk investment, and environment.

The modified process that may approve the sustainable exploitation of renewable energy projects and endorse the social license to operate (based on work by Kamenopoulos et al. 2015a, b)

SLO is straightforward related to the social acceptance of REPs, which is critical for REPs as it could take the form of a risk/uncertainty with severe adverse effects (Lowrance 1976; Kaminaris et al. 2006). These risks may be associated with project delays and/or cancelations due to social turmoil, vandalisms, or increased operational costs (Kamenopoulos and Tsoutsos 2015). These risks may be technological, environmental, social, economic, or geopolitical. As a result, it is very critical to substantiate the reasons why social acceptance comprises a significant risk for which a methodology shall be proposed to address.

The social acceptance is correlated to the global energy market mix of supply and demand through the securing of renewable energy investments: when local societies grant an SLO to a renewable energy company, the probability of social turmoil due to the project is decreased; as a result, the energy demand is satisfied, and the prices may not be affected. The use of land in the case of REPs may become the stake for competition and create potential turmoil among stakeholders (Granoszewski et al. 2011); it might create disagreements and disputes over access similar to those upon the control and use of natural resources (FAO 2000). The social accountability constituted by SLO requires engagement and relationship-building efforts, which are increasingly prescribed to include “meaningful dialogue” as central (Mercer-Mapstone et al. 2017). Competition over natural resources can lead to, intensify, or sustain violence; conflict over natural resources is often part of, and exacerbates, a larger struggle over political, economic, cultural, or religious issues in the society (US Institute of Peace 2007). Managing natural resource systems usually involves conflicts; behaviors of stakeholders, who might be willing to contribute to improvements and reach a win-win situation, sometimes result in worse conditions for all parties (Madani 2010). Especially in the case of REPs, the use of land became the stake of timeless turmoil in the Greek island of Crete and other areas in Greece; in most cases the competition is related to conflict of interests, i.e., the competitive use of land between renewable energy sources (RES) vise the agricultural/livestock breeding or RES vise the touristic sector and the fear of local societies with regard to potential environmental degradation. RES seem to suffer from the “Not in My Back Yard syndrome (NIMBY)” (Smith and Klick 2007) similarly to the mining sector. No man-made project can completely avoid some impact on the environment so neither can REPs (Tsoutsos et al. 2005). A sustainable solution for the exploitation of RES should at least adjust for environmental protection, resource availability, social welfare, and economic viability of the system (Maria and Tsoutsos 2004). Special procedures should be applied prior to the installation of a renewable energy plant especially in countries with a complicated administrative and legislative system (Tsoutsos et al. 2007, 2015; Kokologos et al. 2014). The remainder of the chapter is organized as follows: The methodological framework is presented in Sect. 2. The evaluated hypothetical scenarios and discussion are presented in Sect. 3; the conclusions are presented in Sect. 4.

2 Methodological Framework

Fuzzy communication might create significant negative implications for the acceptance of REPs by stakeholders. If the information is not clearly and transparently shared, the renewable energy firm may be unable to gain an SLO, which refers to the level of acceptance or approval by local communities and stakeholders of renewable energy companies and their operations. This is true regardless of the quality of the renewable energy practices of the firm. The absence of the social license to operate may increase the risks associated with the REP operation. This result is exemplified by the left-hand path of Fig. 1. Effective communication, based on SD’s criteria and indicators, when coupled with best practices can ultimately lead to the SLO. This is demonstrated on the right side of Fig. 1 (based on work by Kamenopoulos et al. (2015a, b) and adapted to fit the purposes of this chapter).

A sustainability assessment of a REP typically may involve multiple stakeholders with distinct objectives, preferences, and potential conflicts. The “GO” or “NO-GO” decision for a REP project may become a challenging task due to the interrelated multiple quantitative and qualitative parameters with different positive or negative impacts as expressed by the different stakeholders.

In the past, several frameworks, including multi-criteria decision analysis (MCDA) frameworks, were applied in the field of REP evaluation; tools such as the Spanish method and PROMETHEE were exploited (Tsoutsos et al. 2009a, b). In addition, several related developments are present in the literature. Indicatively, to name but a few, we refer to REP evaluations using linguistic MCDM, TOPSIS, MAUT, and others (Doukas and Psarras 2009; Doukas et al. 2009, 2010, 2012; Doukas 2013a, b).

The decision support system (DSS) presented in this chapter is based on a multi-criteria decision analysis and on the multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT). The DSS was constructed in the Microsoft Excel™ 2013 environment, and its core is based on criteria and indicators; the DSS may assist decision-makers/stakeholders to better assess the impact of a REP from the sustainability point of view. The proposed DSS shall be integrated into a state-of-the-art sustainable development framework (SDF) (Fig. 2) which was previously developed by Kamenopoulos et al. (2015b).

Fig. 2
A flow chart portrays R E Ps sustainable development framework. Information and data, populate indicators with quantitative, select relevant sustainable development indicators, apply the appropriate weight to each indicator to S D factors, analyze the information using a support system, and project evaluation.

Modified application of the conceptual framework in the case of renewable energy projects (based on Kamenopoulos et al. 2015b)

One of the basic characteristics of the MCDA is the contribution of stakeholders at the decision-making through the negotiation process (trade-offs). In addition, the MCDA integrates unique and personal decision-making practices of individual decision-makers (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018).

The multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT) was created by Keeney and Raiffa (1993). In the MAUT the preferences of the decision-makers are expressed by a utility function which expresses the level of preference that a decision-maker has a set of alternatives; the alternatives are compared under specific criteria (attributes), and every criterion has its own weight (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018). The most common MAUT method is the additive model which is represented by the following equation:

$$ {V}_j=\sum {w}_i{p}_{ij} $$
(1)

where:

  • Vj is the aggregate score of the jth alternative.

  • pij is the score of the jth of the ith criterion.

  • wi is the weight of ith criterion.

A basic constraint of MAUT dictates that the sum of all criteria weights should be equal to one as shown by Eq. (2):

$$ {\sum}_i{W}_i=1 $$
(2)

The strength of multi-attribute utility theory (MAUT) lies on the following (Kumar et al. 2017; Kamenopoulos et al. 2018): (a) it accounts for any difference in any criteria, (b) it simultaneously computes preference order for all alternatives, and (c) it dynamically updates value changes due to any impact. The weakness of MAUT lies on the following: it is difficult to have precise input from the decision-maker, and (b) the outcome of the decision criteria is uncertain. The method which was utilized in order to evaluate the relevant importance of each criterion in terms of weighting factors was the Simple Multi-Attribute Rating Technique (SMART) that was developed by Edwards (1977). The SMART was used in a component part of a hybrid decision support tool for evaluating the sustainability of mining projects, and it was modified for the purposes of this chapter (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018). In that case, the SMART computed the relevant importance of each criterion in two stages (ranking of the criteria and normalization of total score) with the contribution of decision-makers. The modified process allows the formation of a REP’s SD index (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018) that represents the total scoring of decision-maker choices. The following sustainable development index can then be determined (named “ACROPOLIS” index):

$$ {}^{``}{\mathrm{ACROPOLIS}}^{"}=100\ \left(\mathrm{SPA}-\mathrm{SPB}\right)/\left|\mathrm{SPB}\right| $$
(3)

where:

  • The total score of the sustainable path before project start (SPB).

  • The total score of the sustainable path after project end (SPA).

A “sustainable path” was defined as “one that allows every future generation the option of being as well off as its predecessors” (US NRC 1994).

The “GO” or “NO-GO” decision for a REP based on the evaluation of the “ACROPOLIS” index is shown in Table 1.

Table 1 “GO” or “NO-GO” decision based on the evaluation of “ACROPOLIS” index

The decision-making process of the proposed DSS is presented in Fig. 3 (based on work by Kamenopoulos et al. (2018) and adapted to fit the purposes of this chapter).

Fig. 3
A flow chart of the sustainable development assessment of R E P, select criteria and indicators, the establishment of pillar weights, criteria weights, sustainable path before and after R E P, the value of acropolis index, negative category C, on hold category B, positive category A.

“GO-NO-GO” decision-making process for REP assessment from the sustainable development point of view (based on work by Kamenopoulos et al. 2018)

The presented DSS is in a prototype version, and it was designed to include the preferences of five stakeholders, ten quantitative/qualitative indicators, and five sustainable development’s pillars (i.e., economy, environment, geopolitics, society, and technology). The model can be modified to incorporate any number of stakeholders, criteria/indicators, or pillars. The proposed model provides the stakeholders with the opportunity for transparent, free decision-making and democratic negotiations, it may quantify/measure the “sustainable path” as this was defined by the US National Research Council, it complies with the UN’s SD prerequisites for “…effective citizen participation in decision making and by greater democracy in international decision making…” (UN 1987), and it contributes to gaining and retaining social license to operate. Yet there is no sufficient data yet for testing and it is still in prototype stage (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018).

The process allows several levels of trade-offs between the stakeholders. All criteria/indicators are measured in the same scale for homogeneity reasons; for that reason, a qualitative 5-Likert scale was selected (1, low; 2, below average; 3, average; 4, above average; 5, high). The scale and actual values were selected arbitrarily for the purposes of subject chapter. Since there are no actual data available in order to test the proposed decision support system, a number of arbitrary assumptions were made (Table 2).

Table 2 Arbitrary assumptions made for the purposes of this paper

For the purposes of this chapter, ten sustainable development indicators were selected to describe the five pillars of a framework for the evaluation of REPs. The selected indicators and five pillars of sustainability are shown in Table 3.

Table 3 Ten sustainable development indicators for SD pillars (environment, economy, society, technology, and geopolitics)

It should be noted that the proposed model has some advantages as well some disadvantages/limitations that are shown in Table 4 (Kamenopoulos et al. 2018).

Table 4 Advantages and disadvantages of the proposed model

3 The Evaluated Hypothetical Scenarios and Discussion

Tables 5, 6, 7, and 8 represent the hypothetical “NO-GO” (red color) and “GO” (green color) scenarios. They show the values of pillars’ and criteria weights in accordance to five stakeholder ranking preferences and specific values of indicators. They also show the values of sustainable paths (SP), the values of ACROPOLIS index, and the final result in accordance with five stakeholder ranking preferences and specific values of indicators.

Table 5 “NO-GO” (red color) and “GO” (green color) hypothetical scenarios: Pillars’ weights in accordance with five stakeholder ranking preferences and specific values of indicators
Table 6 “NO-GO” (red color) and “GO” (green color) hypothetical scenarios: Average criteria weights in accordance with five ranking stakeholder preferences and specific values of indicators
Table 7 “NO-GO” (red color) and “GO” (green color) hypothetical scenarios: Values of sustainable paths (SP) in accordance with five stakeholder ranking preferences and specific values of indicators
Table 8 “NO-GO” (red color) and “GO” (green color) hypothetical scenarios: Values of evaluation ACROPOLIS index and final result in accordance with five stakeholder ranking preferences and specific values of indicators

In accordance with the stakeholder’s ranking preferences with regard to pillars’ weights (Table 5), stakeholders #1 and #2 seem to be in favor of the environment and society. The preferences of stakeholders #3 and #4 are balanced equally among pillars at the “NO-GO” scenario; stakeholder #5 seems to be in favor of economy, technology, and geopolitics. Table 6 shows that several trade-offs between stakeholders need to be compromised in order to “move” the project from the “NO-GO” status (red) to “GO” status (green): stakeholders #1 and #2 need to compromise and slightly lessen their preferences with regard to the weight of environment. Congruently, stakeholders #3, #4, and #5 need to slightly lessen their preferences with regard to the weights of economy, technology, and geopolitics; respectively, stakeholders #3, #4, and #5 will need to compromise and upsurge their preferences with regard to the weights of environment and society. Equivalent trade-offs need to be compromised on the average criteria weights (Table 6): in accordance with the results of Table 5 when the average weights of environmental and societal criteria increase, then the project may move from “NO-GO” status to “GO” status; this result seems to be reasonable since the society general is willing to provide the social license to operate to REPs when only they fulfill environmental and societal standards. The sustainable path (SP) in the case of “NO-GO” scenario seems to be rationally valued (Table 7): if the SP after a REP (−2.40) has a lower value than the SP before the project (1.01), then the society is not willing to grant the social license to operate (i.e., the social acceptance). This is obvious since no society is willing to abate a good social and environmental condition for a worst one. In that case, the value of ACROPOLIS index (Table 8) has a negative value (−337.62%). Correspondingly, the sustainable path (SP) in the case of “GO” scenario seems to be also rationally valued (Table 6): if the SP after a REP (2.90) has a higher value than the SP before the project (1.14), then the society may grant the social license to operate (i.e., the society is willing to accept the project). This could be obvious since society is probably willing to abate a relatively good social and environmental condition for a better one under specific prerequisites; in that case there may be a bargain/trade-off between stakeholders, and if the economic/technological/geopolitical benefits for the society seem to overcome the expected/future social and environmental returns, then the society may grant the social license to operate and accept the project. In that case, the value of ACROPOLIS index (Table 8) has a positive value (154.38%). Of course, it has to be reminded that each project is unique and the above scenarios are hypothetical.

4 Conclusions

In this chapter, a model was demonstrated for the evaluation of REPs from the perspective of SLO using a decision support system and sustainability criteria. The model can assist decision-makers and stakeholders to evaluate a REP and make “GO-NO-GO” decisions from the sustainable development’s (SD) point of view. The model was based on multi-criteria decision analysis and the multi-attribute utility theory. The model provides the capability to visualize the SD perceptions of citizen participation and greater transparency in a comprehensive mode as recommended in earlier years by the United Nations and quantify the notion of the sustainable path as this was defined by the US National Research Council. The model incorporated criteria and indicators under which two hypothetical scenarios for REPs were evaluated: a “GO” scenario and a “NO-GO” scenario. The two hypothetical scenarios involved personal preferences of five decision-makers (stakeholders). Five sustainability pillars were selected: environment, society, economy, technology, and geopolitics. The hypothetical scenarios were subjective and were built under specific assumptions; in addition, it should be noted that each REP has unique characteristics. Indicative results showed that the presented model may provide outcomes that consist of stakeholder’s preferences and relatively good judgment.