Keywords

1 Introduction

Population growth and economic development constitute the primary factors of the increase in global carbon emissions (Raupach et al. 2007) in the last decades. Anthropogenic greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions have contributed to the increase in annual average global temperature. According to the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, the range of climate change projections for global warming from 1900 to 2100 is from 1.4 °C to 5.8 °C (IPCC 2014). In order to limit GHG emissions, the electricity sector is facing the challenge to undertake a major transformational phase towards a low-carbon system by substituting the existing carbon-intensive technologies with climate-friendly ones. In this regard, energy analysts and policymakers face a future that is technologically, institutionally and politically complex and uncertain (Nikas et al. 2017); furthermore, assessments of the energy transition must take into account different perspectives to reflect the interests of numerous stakeholder groups (Papapostolou et al. 2017). On this matter, portfolio-based approaches are one of the established methods to evaluate national energy strategies and climate policies. They provide an analytical basis to devise generation mixes that take into account security of supply, climate targets, technological progression and costs.

Standard portfolio-based techniques usually provide an optimisation-based model to determine the mix of power generation technologies. To name but a few, McLoughlin and Bazilian (2006) apply a mean-variance portfolio (MVP) optimisation to analyse the Irish electricity generation mix. A similar approach is developed in White (2007) for California’s electric utility resource planning, recommending an optimal generating portfolio for the inclusion of greater shares of renewable technologies. Awerbuch and Berger (2003) apply MVP analysis for the European Union by reflecting the risk of fuel, operation and maintenance, and construction period costs. By applying portfolio theory, Zhu and Fan (2010) evaluate China’s 2020 midterm plans for generating technologies, while reflecting the risk of relevant generating cost streams and including CO2 emission scenarios. Also, Fuss et al. (2012) derive portfolios across various socio-economic scenarios for a range of stabilisation targets by including alternative risk measures.

All in all, uncertainty in portfolio optimisation techniques might be considered in the form of risk. However, another form of uncertainty in the model are its inputs and assumptions, which typically induces the formulation of different cases and scenario analyses. These scenarios are strongly related to different socio-economic, supply and/or stabilisation targets and assumptions. To cope with this kind of uncertainty, it is imperative to stress test the obtained solutions across different scenarios. In this direction, various robust decision support tools have been developed to provide solutions that perform well, independently of any scenario’s realisation. The present study applies the min-max and the min-max regret criteria,Footnote 1 both lying in the core of the so-called robustness analysis, to examine the performance of optimal technology portfolios by considering energy transition scenarios of the power system. The main goal is to identify a solution that performs well against the worst and/or the best case performance. Pure min-max criterion is appropriate for conservative decision makers, since it is associated with the worst-case scenario. Since hedging against uncertainty within energy planning is complex and fraught with multiple forms of uncertainties, robustness approaches have received increasing attention over the last years. For instance, in power systems planning, the uncertainties across the processes of transmission, conversion or distribution are treated with the adoption of interval programming in conjunction with regret analysis (see Dong et al. 2011 and the references therein). Furthermore, we refer to van der Weijde and Hobbs (2012) and Munoz et al. (2014, 2017) concerning transmission planning, and to Fan et al. (2010) and Morris et al. (2018) regarding investment decisions under policy uncertainty, and risk aversion and CO2 regulatory uncertainty in generation investments, respectively.

In this chapter, to analyse the decarbonisation of the EU power system, we apply a stochastic power investment model to determine the optimal technology portfolios under certain scenarios. Namely, we use the EMPIRE (European Model for Power System Investment with Renewable Energy) model, developed by Skar et al. (2016a, b). EMPIRE, formulated as a multi-horizon stochastic programme, incorporates long- and short-term system dynamics while optimising investments under operational uncertainty. It is well known that the consideration of renewable technology in the generation mix, in particular wind and solar power, impacts the supply and demand balance, due to the intermittent and uncontrollable nature of these technologies. EMPIRE is designed to handle these challenges. In contrast to other power sector models, the major contribution of EMPIRE is that it simultaneously incorporates short- and long-term dynamics, in conjunction with short-term uncertainty. Dynamics refer to multiple investment periods coexisting with multiple sequential operational decision periods, while uncertainty is enhanced through multiple input scenarios that describe operating conditions. That is, EMPIRE is a capacity and transmission expansion model, designed to determine optimal capacity investments and system operation over long-term planning horizons, extended in a 40–50-year basis. A central planner’s perspective is adopted, minimising a system’s cost while serving a price inelastic demand. Regarding the effect of short-term uncertainty on investment decisions, the methodology used is based on the principles of multi-horizon stochastic programming, as proposed by Kaut et al. (2014). Related expansion models in the literature are, for example, the DIMENSION (Richter 2011) model used by Jägemann et al. (2013), who analyse the costs for the decarbonisation of the European power sector. Similarly, another dynamic investment model, the LIMES-EU+, was adopted by Haller et al. (2012), where carbon capture and storage (CCS) and nuclear power are excluded. Both optimisation models are deterministic, in contrast to EMPIRE’s stochastic features. In the multi-stage stochastic model E2M2 (Swider and Weber 2007), short-term wind uncertainty is analysed for the German power system. Another similar model is the two-stage stochastic model TIMES (Seljom and Tomasgard 2015), which also includes short-term uncertainty.

In our stress testing framework assessment, EMPIRE determines the optimal portfolio of electricity generation technologies and calculates their respective costs and emissions achieved for the 2015–2050 period. Each long-term strategy obtained by EMPIRE assumes the realisation (model inputs) of a future technological progression or geopolitical scenario assumptions. For instance, technology evolution differentiation represents the variability of the scenarios. To hedge against the possible realisation of certain technological or geopolitical scenarios, we apply robust optimisation through the min-max and min-max regret criteria. In the first case, a safe performance is guaranteed, independently of any selection within the input parameter dataset. In the regret analysis case, the stress test of input data means that the decision maker measures the deviation from optimality as long as input varies within the scenario set, and then the min-max criterion is applied to guarantee a safe “distance” from that optimality.

We chose to implement robust optimisation, since we refer to risk-averse decision makers, either concerning the best or the worst case. The literature with applications of min-max regret analysis in the energy sector is quite extensive. For example, in Dong et al. (2011), min-max regret analysis is incorporated in combination with interval linear programming for the study of power management systems under multiple supply and demand scenarios. In Li et al. (2016), electrical power generation planning is studied while considering discrete scenarios of possible climate change outcomes. In Kazakci et al. (2007), energy crop supply is measured through a linear mathematical programme. In the framework of climate change mitigation policy, we refer to Loulou and Kanudia (1999), where a min-max regret formulation is proposed to determine strategies for GHG emission reduction. In Li et al. (2011), an interval model is developed to support planning of GHG mitigation within an uncertain energy system. In addition, these approaches are also applied to solid waste management by combining tools for interval and robust optimisation (Li and Huang 2006; Chang and Davila 2007). However, we should mention that minimising maximum cost or regret is a rather extreme form of risk aversion and that there exist other alternatives to model it, such as using utility functions (preferred by economists) or Conditional Value at Risk (preferred by engineers). To summarise, the objective of this study is to (1) analyse the robustness of different pathways for the energy transition of the power sector by stress testing their outcomes across individual scenarios and (2) propose a multidisciplinary method to complement a power system capacity expansion model with a robustness-based approach (min-max regret analysis).

The next section presents the main features of the EMPIRE model. This is followed by Sect. 3, which describes the implementation of four distinct cases and their respective results. Then, Sect. 4 presents the two robustness tools that apply the stress test analysis on optimal investment portfolios across the different cases.

2 Modelling Investments in Electricity Generation and Transmission

2.1 Short-Term vs. Long-Term Considerations for Optimal Portfolio

There is a multitude of energy models looking at different dimensions of the power system. Main difference among models is the level of technical detail, representation of uncertainty (e.g. RES or demand variations), temporal considerations, spatial aggregation and planning horizons (for a review, see Crespo del Granado et al. 2018). Typically, the fundamental problem is to decide the short-term scheduling of power plants (e.g. coal, gas, hydro or nuclear) based on generation costs, plants’ operational limitations and RES-load interactions. This model, in the literature, is known as the “unit commitment problem”, the “optimal economic dispatch” or simply the generation dispatch. To decide the power dispatching of a determined number of coal or gas power plants, nuclear reactors or oil generators, the model determines an optimal supply portfolio based on functions representing economic decisions and energy generation physics. While this kind of model represents the supply-demand balance in detail with a high time resolution (hourly decisions), it usually does not consider long-term decisions for capacity planning. In contrast, models for long-term capacity planning leave behind detail engineering aspects of operations. Raising a causality dilemma since the short-term decisions require an adequate generation capacity to satisfy demand, while long-term investment decisions are a consequence on how much adequacy is required in the short term. As both planning horizons are nonmutually exclusive (see Fig. 1), investment models have come up with different assumptions to represent operational decisions and features of the power system. For the EMPIRE model, these assumptions are as follows:

  • Operations and investment horizon: As hourly operations in 1 year compromise 8760 periods, repeating them for multiple years increases the dimensionality of the problem. Long-term planning problems typically analysed years to decades ahead and simulating short-term problems for large time spans might create an intractable problem. A common approach is to sample representative weeks. In EMPIRE, we sample typical weeks per season along with 2 weeks representing extreme cases (e.g. high peak demand and low RES availability). These weeks’ parameters are updated for incoming investment periods. EMPIRE considers a planning horizon from 2015 to 2050. Investment windows are every 5 years in which the representative operational weeks are scaled up to resemble the 5 years in operation. That is, all investment periods are in a single optimisation along with operation snapshots (see similar approach in Haller et al. 2012).

  • Spatial aggregations: EMPIRE model covers the European Economic Area countries (see Fig. 2, 31 European countries along with 55 interconnectors). EMPIRE models each country as a single node together with existing capacity and estimated demand. The net transmission capacity defines the country connection capacity to neighbouring regions. That is, the interconnection among nodes in the model resembles a transportation problem.

  • Technical engineering aspects: EMPIRE short-term operational aspects represent hourly decisions of the generators and transmission exchange between countries. Generators are aggregated by type, for example, nuclear generators have a single variable per country. As an energy system model, EMPIRE does not consider power flows and voltage relationships. As the main interest is the long-term expansion of the system, the model also assumes linear production cost profiles for all generators.

  • Policy and economic perspectives: EMPIRE can set RES targets and calculates CO2 emissions per country. Main model outputs are the usage factor of power plants, load shedding, RES curtailments, transmission infrastructure investments and cooperation among countries to meet policy objectives. Hence various policies can be tested by changing the model parameters (technology costs, demand or RES targets), including the prospects of development of technologies (e.g. CCS) and considering assumptions on transmission expansion possibilities.

Fig. 1
A flowchart of assessment of power systems: energy technical systems, and energy economic systems. It portrays the planning horizon and decisions that include short-term, medium-term, and long-term.

Assessment of power systems portfolios by considering technical and economic perspectives based on the joint representation of short-term to long-term decisions

Fig. 2
A map of Europe marks Portugal, Spain, France, Ireland, Sweden, Poland, Hungary, Norway, German, Greece, and Lithuania. An illustration of investments of 5 years windows in 2015, 2020, 2025, 2030, and 2050. An area graph depicts operations hours in Gigawatt Hours for hydro, other, wind, imports, gas, coal, and nuclear. Gas has the highest operation hours.

EMPIRE model EU spatial coverage combining short (operations)- and long-term (investments) decisions to determine optimal portfolios for the power system

In summary, EMPIRE intends to combine as much as it can from both worlds: short-term (operational) and long-term (strategic) decisions. In addition, the model provides enough rich technological details to provide rational insights for the long-term planning of the power system. Figure 1 epitomises this discussion in which the modelling approach might take a technical engineering perspective or an economic viewpoint mainly focuses on the empirical understandings of impacts in policymaking. The EMPIRE model intends to encompass a compromise of this vision since its formulation convenes as much as it can from different perspectives. For a further discussion on tools for integrated assessments, combining models and strength-weaknesses of different modelling approaches, refer to Crespo del Granado et al. (2018).

2.2 EMPIRE Model Formulation

Modelling a portfolio of energy units, as an hourly coordinated supply-demand system, is typically formulated as a multiperiod optimisation model. This takes into consideration the cost of running the generation units, ramp-up time and the unit input-output capacity (power rates). As a result, the optimisation model objective is to minimise the investment and operational costs. The main decision variables are the investment decisions and which generation units to use and when: peak time, base load, smoothing renewables and the usage of transmission capacity. EMPIRE perspective is an economic social surplus maximisation that assumes perfectly competitive markets under predetermined consumer decisions. As noted earlier, a central feature in EMPIRE is the representation of two timescales, the long term (strategic) and the short term (operational). Operational decisions are associated with a strategic stage in order to co-optimise long-term investment decisions and the short-term operational decisions. That is, strategic decisions face supply-demand balancing decisions under uncertainty. For example, in Fig. 2, observe the structure of the 5-year investment windows subjected to operational uncertainty. Investment variables (generation and transmission expansion) in 2020 have specific hourly load profiles per country and must determine the operations of the units and hence decide the optimal portfolio from 2025 onwards. The model includes a discount rate to calculate the net present value (NPV) of investments. This structure follows a multi-horizon stochastic framework in which the operational uncertainty is in the load profiles and wind and solar power generation. For a more comprehensive discussion on setting up the EMPIRE model, refer to Skar et al. (2016a, b).

EMPIRE Objective Function

As aforementioned, to take into account long-term and short-term decisions, EMPIRE minimises the NPV of investments based on operational decisions. On one hand, the objective function contains the investment decisions for generation (\( {x}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}} \), capacity investment in generator g at year i) and transmission (\( {x}_{lj}^{\mathrm{tran}} \), investing in transmission line l at year i) under costs \( {c}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}} \) and \( {c}_{li}^{\mathrm{tran}} \), respectively. On the other hand, the presentation of the operation decisions comes from the production of generator g and \( {y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}} \) for operational hour h in year i under stochastic scenario ω. In addition, the operations consider load shedding (\( {y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{LL}} \)) at node n (country), under operational hour h in year i and stochastic scenario ω. Both \( {y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}} \) and \( {y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{LL}} \) face costs of producing electricity (\( {q}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}} \)) and the cost of using load shedding (\( {q}_{ni}^{\mathrm{VoLL}} \)). In short, EMPIRE objective function is as follows:

$$ \underset{\mathbf{x},\mathbf{y}}{\min}z=\sum \limits_{i\in \mathcal{I}}{\delta}_i\times \left\{\sum \limits_{g\in \mathcal{G}}{c}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}}{x}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}}+\sum \limits_{l\in \mathcal{L}}{c}_{li}^{\mathrm{tran}}{x}_{li}^{\mathrm{tran}}+\sum \limits_{\omega \in \Omega}{p}_{\omega}\times \sum \limits_{h\in \mathcal{H}}{\alpha}_h\times \sum \limits_{n\in \mathcal{N}}\left(\sum \limits_{g\in {\mathcal{G}}_n}\left[{q}_{gi}^{\mathrm{gen}}{y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}\right]+{q}_{ni}^{\mathrm{VoLL}}{y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{LL}}\right)\right\}. $$
(1)

To compute the NPV in Eq. (1), we set a discount factor δi per year i. For the operations, we apply a factor αh to scale up and match the total number of hours of the investment period. Recall that the time span of the investments is 5 years for which we use representative weeks of the year and hence the scale up factor accounts for the remaining hours. Note that since we consider stochastic scenarios for renewables and demand, we assign the respective probabilities pω for operations of that scenario.

EMPIRE Constraints

Since it would be unrealistic to invest in certain generators for certain countries (e.g. wind offshore for Switzerland) or allow sudden large investments on each period, Eq. (1) is subjected to investment constraints (period-wise and cumulative), that is, a restriction by an upper bound (\( {\overline{x}}_{tn^{\ast}}^{\mathrm{gen}} \)) on investments in new capacity for generator g along with the cumulative installed generation over the planning horizon. This also considers the retirement of power plants based on the retired share (ρgi) of generator g’s initial capacity by year i. These constraints are

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{l}\sum \limits_{g\in {\mathcal{G}}_{nt}}{x}_{gj}^{\mathrm{gen}}\le {\overline{x}}_{nt i}^{\mathrm{gen},\mathrm{Period}},\kern1em n\in \mathcal{N},t\in \mathcal{T},i\in \mathcal{I}.\\ {}\sum \limits_{j=1}^i\sum \limits_{g\in {\mathcal{G}}_{nt}}{x}_{gj}^{\mathrm{gen}}\le {\overline{x}}_{nt}^{\mathrm{gen},\mathrm{Cumulative}}-\left(1-{\rho}_{gi}\right){\overline{x}}_{g0}^{\mathrm{gen}},\kern1em n\in \mathcal{N},t\in \mathcal{T},i\in \mathcal{I}.\end{array}} $$
(2)

Likewise, investment constraints for transmission (exchange) capacity are also set up:

$$ {x}_{li}^{\mathrm{tran}}\le {\overline{x}}_{li}^{\mathrm{tran},\mathrm{Period}},\kern1em l\in \mathcal{L},i\in \mathcal{I}. $$
(3)

As for the equations to represent the operations, these are based on the usage of generators g at node n, the interaction (flow) with neighbouring nodes, the capacity and usage characteristics of the generators, hydro or alike storage technologies and the emission standards per country. The details of these operational constraints are as follows:

  1. 1.

    Supply-demand balance (production + losses*import−exports−pumping + load shedding = load)

$$ \sum \limits_{g\in {\mathcal{G}}_n}{y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}+\sum \limits_{a\in {\mathcal{A}}_n^{\mathrm{in}}}\left(1-{\eta}_a^{\mathrm{line}}\right){y}_{ahi\omega}^{\mathrm{flow}}-\sum \limits_{a\in {\mathcal{A}}_n^{\mathrm{out}}}{y}_{ahi\omega}^{\mathrm{flow}}-{y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{pump}}+{y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{LL}}={\xi}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{load}},n\in \mathcal{N},h\in \mathcal{H},\omega \in \Omega, i\in \mathcal{I}. $$
(4)
  1. 2.

    Generation capacity constraint based on existing a prior capacity plus the invested capacity for year i under

$$ {y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}\le {\xi}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}\times \left(\left(1-{\rho}_{gi}\right){\overline{x}}_{g0}^{\mathrm{gen}}+\sum \limits_{j=1}^i{x}_{gj}^{\mathrm{gen}}\right),\kern1em g\in \mathcal{G},h\in \mathcal{H},i\in \mathcal{I},\omega \in \Omega. $$
(5)
  1. 3.

    Upward ramping constraints to simulate appropriate load following of the generators:

$$ {y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}-{y}_{g\left(h-1\right) i\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}\le {\gamma}_g^{\mathrm{gen}}\times \left(\left(1-{\rho}_{gi}\right){\overline{x}}_{g0}^{\mathrm{gen}}+\sum \limits_{j=1}^i{x}_{gj}^{\mathrm{gen}}\right),\kern1em g\in {\mathcal{G}}^{\mathrm{Thermal}},s\in \mathcal{S},h\in {\mathcal{H}}_s^{-},i\in \mathcal{I},\omega \in \Omega, $$
(6)
  1. 4.

    Flow constraint—limit flow on arcs (directional arcs and lines are symmetric). It also considers a prior line capacity plus the capacity expansion investment for year i:

$$ {y}_{ahi\omega}^{\mathrm{flow}}\le {\overline{x}}_{l0}^{\mathrm{tran}}+\sum \limits_{j=1}^i{x}_{lj}^{\mathrm{tran}},\kern1em l\in {\mathcal{L}}_n,a\in {\mathcal{A}}_l,h\in \mathcal{H},i\in \mathcal{I},\omega \in \Omega. $$
(7)
  1. 5.

    Hydro energy constraint—limit total hydropower production within a season (due to water availability)

$$ \sum \limits_{h\in {\mathcal{H}}_s}{y}_{ghi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen}}\le {\xi}_{gsi\omega}^{\operatorname{Re}\mathrm{gHydroLim}},\kern1em g\in {\mathcal{G}}^{\mathrm{RegHydro}},s\in \mathcal{S},i\in \mathcal{I},\omega \in \Omega. $$
(8)
  1. 6.

    Pump-storage upper reservoir capacity and inter-temporal balance for storage:

$$ {\displaystyle \begin{array}{c}{w}_{n\left(h-1\right) i\omega}^{\mathrm{upper}}+{\eta}_n^{pump}{y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{pump}}-{y}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{gen},\mathrm{pump}}={w}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{upper}}\\ {}{w}_{nhi\omega}^{\mathrm{upper}}\le {\overline{w}}_n^{\mathrm{upper}}\end{array}},n\in \mathcal{N},h\in {\mathcal{H}}_s,i\in \mathcal{I},\omega \in \Omega. $$
(9)

Appendix 1 notes the nomenclature description of the sets, parameters and variables used in the above formulation. Note that EMPIRE has been used in other studies which present a more comprehensive model formulation, data sources and other details (see, for example, Skar et al. (2014, 2016a, b) and ZEP (2013, 2014)). Note that exogenous drivers of investments in the EMPIRE model are changes in demand, retirement of the existing generation fleet, changes in fuel prices and a price of carbon. Technological advancement, such as investment cost reductions and efficiency improvements for thermal generation, plays an important role in the design of the optimal generation portfolio and is included in the model (see Appendix 2 for data inputs). EMPIRE computational dimension includes approximately 15 million variables and 22 million constraints, and it takes from an hour to 5 hours to solve (depending on scenario, technology choice and solver configurations).

3 Energy Transition: Cases and EMPIRE Model Results

3.1 Defining Cases

The EU Energy Roadmap 2050 and various stakeholders’ discussions with the European commission outlined four main decarbonisation routes for the energy sector; these are energy efficiency, RES, nuclear and CCS. These decarbonisation options have the premise that European integration will be one of the driving forces in its success. Cooperation among countries and political determination will generate measures for the integration of European electricity markets, viability of infrastructure projects of common interest (PCI), common climate targets (e.g. the Paris agreement) and joint policies to accommodate higher shares of RES in the system. The cooperation among different EU actors and countries towards 2050 is assumed to be one of the cornerstones of the energy transition. As a result, some scenario-building studies (Bauer et al. 2017) have discussed the degree of cooperation achievable in the long term as a measure to weigh-in and to formulate different scenarios towards 2050.

In this spirit, to understand the consequences of assuming different evolutions of the generation portfolio of the electricity system, we define four casesFootnote 2 that are in line with the scenarios developed by the PRIMES model (National Technical University of Athens 2010) for the EU Low Carbon Roadmap 2050 (European Commission 2011). That is, we use the following two EU scenarios:

  • The “PRIMES Reference scenario” projects energy trends to 2050 based on policies already adopted by March 2010. It includes policies agreed in the EU climate and energy package of 2009.

  • The “PRIMES Decarbonisation scenario”. We use the EUCO 27 variant, which assumes international agreement on an effective global action plan complemented with policies for carbon pricing across all sectors. It positions the adoption of major low-carbon technologies in the energy sector, e.g. energy efficiency and RES, CCS, nuclear and electrification of transport.

Since the energy transition is affected by technological development, climate change commitments, energy security and international agreements, both PRIMES scenarios might evolve differently under different contexts. For example, if cooperation among nations does not occur as expected, this might limit the integration of EU electricity markets and the creation of PCI. We can reflect this hypothetical situation by limiting the expansion of transmission capacity in EMPIRE. Limiting transmission expansion could reflect the view that EU nations find difficult to develop stronger cooperation. In short, this argument defines four cases:

  • PRIMES reference case, transmission options available or optimised (OTR)

  • PRIMES decarbonisation case, transmission options available or optimised (OTD)

  • PRIMES reference case, transmission expansion limited (LTR)

  • PRIMES decarbonisation case, transmission expansion limited (LTD)

The overall results illustrated in Fig. 3 show the developments of the energy mix for these four cases. For the years 2010 and 2015, historic data are used for all generation and transmission capacities; however, the economic dispatch comes from the model. The year 2020 is the first investment period for generation capacities. As for the transmission investment cases (LTR and LTP), this is set to the reference capacities in ENTSO-E’s 10-year network development plan (TYNDP) 2016 (see ENTSO-E (2015) for more information). The major differences between the decarbonisation and the reference cases are as follows: The demand for electricity is higher, and the price of carbon is higher in the decarbonisation cases. The main effect on EMPIRE is that the need for investments is higher and that the generation mix is forced to be cleaner.

Fig. 3
Three illustrations of results of investing in transmission and generation towards 2050. It includes 2010, reference 2050, and decarbonization 2050. 2 graphs of reference and decarbonization for various parameters. 2 graphs of investing in generation under restrictions for transmission.

Reference and decarbonisation cases under transmission capacity available (a) or restricted (b)

3.2 Results for 2020–2030 Period: All Cases

As expected, there are similarities in all scenarios in 2020 and 2030—regardless of input data used (reference or decarbonisation scenario) and whether transmission investments are restricted beyond 2020. This is because all the cases share similar features for these periods since transmission expansion is the same and difference between reference and decarbonisation is not significant for demand projections. The first effect that stands out is the expansion of the share of coal generation in 2020 for all scenarios. On one hand, this is because of the retirement of ageing nuclear power capacity with zero emission that is not replaced by new capacity. On the other hand, due to moderate carbon prices (15 EUR/tCO2) and a high price ratio of gas to coal (at about 3.4), new coal generation is the lowest cost option to replace the retired capacity. Hence, this new coal capacity takes over the share of the existing natural gas installed in the system, leading to a small increase in power sector emissions from 2015 which is not necessarily in line with the European Union’s climate goals set for 2020 (a 20% emission reduction compared to 1990s level). In reality the power sector emissions, subject to the EU Emissions Trading System, would not be allowed to increase, and the economic advantage of coal compared to lower emission technologies such as renewables, natural gas and nuclear would be counteracted by an increase in the ETS price. However, as the ETS price increases in the period beyond 2020, this becomes less of an issue as the emissions reduction from EMPIRE approach levels is in line with EU’s climate policy.

As for renewables, most of the investments in the period until 2030 are in onshore wind power. Only moderate investments are in solar PV—of around 25 GW for the reference cases and 75 GW in the decarbonisation cases.

3.3 Results for Reference Cases 2030–2050

For the reference scenario cases, unabated coal generation remains the main fossil fuel technology in the generation mix until 2040, in both with and without transmission expansion cases. In 2040 coal with CCS is deployed achieving a high share of the generation mix than unabated coal towards 2050. For renewables, mainly onshore wind and solar PV, there is a massive deployment for both technologies in the 2030–2050 period. When allowing for transmission expansion, more than 50% of the electricity produced comes from these sources. One of the most significant effects of not expanding capacity in the transmission system is that less onshore wind generation is deployed. This shows that cost-optimal wind deployment relies heavily on the ability to effectively share wind resources using the grid.

In the case with limited transmission expansion, nuclear power sees reinvestments (at a cost of 4500 EUR/kW), and this capacity is largely what is used to make up the reduction in wind generation compared to the alternative transmission case. As can be seen in the EU grid maps of Fig. 3a, there is a significant increase of capacity on the interconnectors between countries. For example, the cross-border connections between France, Germany, Spain, the UK and neighbouring countries are reinforced heavily.

3.4 Results for Decarbonisation Cases 2030–2050

The main differences between exogenous inputs between the decarbonisation case and the reference case are that the former has a steeper increase of the ETS price and a higher electricity demand. In comparison with the results of the reference cases, there are effects worth mentioning:

  • Deployment of CCS occurs a full decade earlier in the decarbonisation cases than the reference cases, in 2030 rather than 2040.

  • Nuclear power sees reinvestment in both decarbonisation cases.

  • Solar and onshore wind expansion is more aggressive in these cases than the reference case, reaching a level of around 65% of the generation mix in the transmission expansion cases. By 2050 all unabated fossil generation has been completely phased out.

  • As in the reference case, we observe that less wind onshore is installed when there are no investments in the transmission capacity beyond 2020. This is made up by fossil fuel with CCS, most notably gas CCS. But a small amount of offshore wind is deployed in the restricted transmission case.

For the cases with investments in transmission capacity, the overall picture is alike to the reference case, although with a few distinctions. There are significant investments in Central Europe, but some connections see different investments in the decarbonisation case than the reference. For instance, the interconnector between France and Germany has less capacity in the decarbonisation case, whereas the links from France to Switzerland and Switzerland to Germany are reinforced. Another notable difference is the increased investments from the Baltic countries in the north to the Balkans in the south in the decarbonisation case. This is a result of the increased penetration of variable renewable resources in the decarbonisation case, which has a strong effect on the optimal design of the transmission system for balancing supply and demand throughout the continent.

4 Robustness Tool and Stress Testing the Optimal Portfolios

In this section, we present the mathematical formulation and the structure of the min-max and min-max regret criteria. Uncertainty is represented deterministically through the concept of scenario (see also Kouvelis and Yu 1997). Potential future realisation of the model is represented through a particular scenario, which occurs with a positive but unknown probability.

Our aim is to identify robust strategies corresponding to a plausible objective performance, along all scenarios of our decision model. First, we apply the min-max criterion, pointing out that the robust decision is that having the best worst-case performance across all future scenarios. Let us explain this in the discrete scenario case.

Consider the following optimisation problem:

$$ {\min}_{x\in X}f\left(c,x\right), $$
(10)

where x = (x1, …, xN) ∊ X ⊆ N and c = (c1, …, cN) ∊ N. The feasible set X contains the admissible decision variables (x1, …, xN) satisfying some prespecified constraints of the model. The input parameters (c1, …, cN), inserted exogenously, define the uncertainty of the model in the following sense: if S = {s1, …, sp} denotes the finite set of all potentially realisable input data scenarios, then realisation of a certain scenario s ∈ S means that

$$ c={c}^s=\left({c}_1^s,\dots, {c}_N^s\right). $$

While S is not identically a singleton, uncertainty is then inherent. Let X and S be the feasible set and the discrete scenario set, respectively, for the minimisation problem (10). The corresponding min-max decision is exactly

$$ {x}_{minimax}=\mathit{\arg}{\min}_{x\epsilon X}{\max}_{s\epsilon S}f\left({c}^s,x\right). $$

Subsequently, consider the optimal solution for scenario’s s ∈ S realisation, which is

$$ {x}_s^{opt}=\mathit{\arg}{\min}_{x\epsilon X}f\left({c}^s,x\right), $$

and the corresponding optimal performance:

$$ {f}_s^{opt}:= f\left({c}^s,{x}_s^{opt}\right). $$

Given an admissible decision x ∈ X, its regret R(x, s), under scenario’s s ∈ S realisation, is defined as its deviation from scenario’s s ∈ S optimal performance, that is,

$$ R\left(x,s\right):= \left|f\left({c}^s,x\right)-{f}_s^{opt}\right|. $$

For any decision, we are interested in identifying the worst deviation from optimality across the whole range of uncertainty. Therefore, it is reasonable to obtain information on the worst regret. For any decision x ∈ X, its maximum regret is defined as

$$ {R}_{max}:= \underset{s\epsilon S}{\max}R\left(x,s\right). $$

Then, the min-max regret criterion aims at identifying the solution presenting the best worst-case deviation from optimality, independently of the input data realisation. The corresponding min-max regret decision is exactly

$$ {x}_{regret}=\mathit{\arg}{\min}_{x\in X}{\max}_{s\in S}{R}_{max}=\mathit{\arg}{\min}_{x\in X}{\max}_{s\in S}\left|f\left({c}^s,x\right)-{f}_s^{opt}\right|. $$
(11)

Subsequently, we carry out a stress testing for the investments in electricity generation and transmission with respect to their performance across different scenarios. More precisely, we measure the variation of the cumulative 2010–2050 investment costs and cumulative 2010–2050 emissions across different scenarios on transmission and decarbonisation. Regarding scenarios, we apply the four cases previously described: the two PRIMES scenarios (reference and decarbonisation) with assumptions on transmission expansion (either optimised investments or limited to just the 10-year development plan by ENTSO-E).

First, we consider the objective referring to the cumulative 2010–2050 costs in billion € (2010) as they are presented in Table 1. In the first column, we consider the optimal portfolio investments per scenario, and we examine their performance across the remaining investment scenarios. Then, we carry out min-max and min-max regret analysis to obtain the most robust state. According to the min-max criterion, the best worst performance across all scenarios is located at the LTD case. In particular, the cumulative capacity costs do not exceed 2224.7 billion €, for any scenario’s realisation. This is the risk-averse case decision-making.

Table 1 Cumulative 2010–2050 investment capacity costs of the optimal portfolios across different scenarios (in billion € (2010))

To apply the min-max regret criterion, we need the regret values for the costs across all scenarios (Table 2). In this case, the two approaches coincide, i.e. the more robust strategy is still located at the LTD-optimal portfolio.

Table 2 Regret values for the investment costs

Regarding the second objective, that is, the cumulative emissions for the 2010–2050 period, these are presented in Table 3. The corresponding regret values in terms of emissions are presented in Table 4. The min-max strategy corresponds to the LTD case, bounding the total emissions at the level of 30.6 GtCO2, independently of any scenario’s realisation. On the contrary, min-max regret analysis points to the OTD strategy. This is the classical case between the risk-averse and the risk-seeking decision maker. More precisely, the OTD portfolio contains better performances (28.2 GtCO2) from the LTD portfolio. On the other hand, based on the min-max regret criterion, the LTD scenario results in higher emissions (29.9 GtCO2). A visual representation reflecting the robustness structure of the two different objectives (investment costs and emissions) is presented in Fig. 4.

Table 3 Cumulative 2010–2050 emissions (in GtCO2)
Table 4 Emissions regret values
Fig. 4
Two bar graphs of 2010-2050 emissions Gt C O 2 and 2010- 2050 investment cost for O T D and L T D portfolio. The portfolios include O T R, O T D, L T R, and L T D.

Cumulative emissions and investment capacity costs of the optimal portfolios across different scenarios

If we consider simultaneously the two objective functions (costs and emissions), we notice that a conflict occurs. Following the min-max regret analysis, the cost-oriented robust strategy is located in LTD optimality, while in the emissions case, regret robustness corresponds to the OTD-optimal portfolio. Coping with this conflict, we apply the min-max regret criterion for the joint objective \( {E}^s=\left({E}_1^s,{E}_2^s\right) \), where \( {E}_1^s \) and \( {E}_2^s \) represent the cumulative costs and emissions, respectively, across scenarios s ∈ {OTR, OTD, LTR, LTD}. First, we identify the optimal state per scenario, represented by \( \left({E}_{1\ast}^s,{E}_{2\ast}^s\right) \). Next, to avoid the curse of non-homogeneity, we consider the relative performance (RP) per scenario, with respect to the corresponding optimal situation, that is,

$$ RP(s):= \left(\frac{E_1^s}{E_{1\ast}^s},\frac{E_2^s}{E_{2\ast}^s}\right),s\in \left\{\mathrm{OTR},\mathrm{OTD},\mathrm{LTR},\mathrm{LTD}\right\}. $$

Then, we obtain the relative joint performances in Table 5. Note that, in terms of relative performances, optimal situations correspond to the unit values. This means that, for each scenario, the optimal situation corresponds to (1,1). To identify the more robust joint strategy, we will apply the min-max regret criterion for the relative joint objectives. In this case, since the elements belong to \( {\mathbb{R}}_{+}^2 \), we measure the deviation from optimality in terms of the Euclidean norm, that is,

$$ \mathrm{dist}\left(x,y\right)={\left({\left({x}_1-{x}_2\right)}^2+{\left({y}_1-{y}_2\right)}^2\right)}^{1/2}, $$

for any \( \left({x}_1,{y}_1\right),\left({x}_2,{y}_2\right)\in {\mathbb{R}}_{+}^2 \). Then, the min-max regret criterion for the relative case is expressed as follows:

$$ \mathrm{MMR}=\arg\ {\min}_P{\max}_s\ \left(\mathrm{dist}\left(RP(s),\left(1,1\right)\right)\right), $$

where P refers to the set of the four examined optimal investment portfolios. The regret values, in terms of the relative objective functions, are presented in Table 6. Applying the min-max regret criterion to the relative regret values, we conclude that the joint robust strategy is LTD, being in accordance with the distinguished application of the pure min-max criterion.

Table 5 Relative joint objectives
Table 6 Relative regret values

Based on the above analysis, we highlight the following observations:

  • In the min-max setting, the LTD strategy is the optimal, expressing the desire of the conservative decision maker in any of the examined future development.

  • With the min-max regret approach, the LTD strategy for cost and the OTD strategy for emissions create the least regret for the decision maker. If, however, joint relative regret analysis is applied to the future optimal development, then LTD strategy is established to be the robust one.

To provide some policy recommendations emerging from the above analysis, it is observed that:

  • Portfolios for decarbonisation scenarios are more robust. This is due to the fact that nuclear remains in the mix until 2050, while the introduction of CCS technologies in the mix comes much earlier than in the reference scenario.

  • In the optimised transmission portfolios, even though an important priority is considered, if the new generation built is based on this scenario and not realised in terms of infrastructure and investments, then the resulting regret could be enormous. From a technical point of view, this situation is realistic, considering, for example, that balancing issues will be far more challenging.

5 Conclusions

In this study, different emissions reduction technologies are considered for the identification of optimal policy mixes towards mitigating GHG emissions. Optimal electricity generation portfolios are determined through an EU electricity investment model, by considering different scenarios on transmission expansion and decarbonisation. Then, the performance of portfolios’ long-term strategies is stress tested on the basis of investment costs and cumulative emissions. In this regard, we notice that technologies such as nuclear and CCS are found to be crucial, in the sense that forming portfolios with optimised transmission expansion proves to be inconsistent with the stress test analysis results. To this end, robustness tools such as the min-max regret criterion contributed to explore a posteriori more insight into the scenarios’ assumptions, showing that combining modelling approaches provide a new dimension on assessing pathways of the energy transition.

Concluding, we found that decarbonisation scenarios are the preferred strategy for all cases. However, the limited decarbonisation strategy is the more robust, resulting in the least regret.

In this study, the limitations primarily involve the selection of the four scenarios; furthermore, future research may be directed to the investigation of the impact of additional objective functions to apply the min-max and the min-max regret criteria. Also, future research should consider analysing the evolution of CCS technologies and the respective risks of investing in CCS. The technology is still not commercially viable and perhaps does not become a reality. It is thus important to calculate the costs (regret), if pathways consider this development.