Skip to main content

Inducing Optimal Quality Under Price Caps: Why, How, and Whether

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
New Business and Regulatory Strategies in the Postal Sector

Part of the book series: Topics in Regulatory Economics and Policy ((TREP))

  • 631 Accesses

Abstract

Quality of postal service is of concern around the world, and was a subject of proceedings in the US to assess the performance of price-cap regulation (PCR) of “market-dominant” services. Although PCR does not imply minimizing quality, work by Sappington implies that quality will be below the optimal level at the regulated price. Mechanisms to get regulated firms to internalize this quality externality, consistent with information limitations justifying PCR, provide no benefits to postal customers. Negotiated arrangements between a postal operator and its regulator to set and incentivize quality of service are likely the best available option.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 109.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 139.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Pub. L. 109-435 (2006).

  2. 2.

    39 U.S. Code §3622(d)(1)(A).

  3. 3.

    If demand increases, the regulated firm’s profits will typically increase, as price for regulated firms generally exceeds marginal cost. If increases in demand are expected, the X adjustment could be a way to share those profits with buyers. Brennan and Crew (2016) explored how a regulator could increase a price cap to prevent declining demand from reducing profits; the same adjustment would reduce prices when demand increases, sharing accompanying higher profits with customers.

  4. 4.

    39 U.S. Code §3622(d)(3).

  5. 5.

    39 U.S. Code §3622(b)(3). The §3691 reference is to a part of the statute requiring USPS, with PRC consultation, to institute service standards that “enhance value,” “preserve access,” and “reasonably assure Postal Service customers delivery reliability, speed and frequency.” 39 U.S. Code §3691(b)(1)(A)-(C).

  6. 6.

    Postal Regulatory Commission, Advance Notice of Proposed Rulemaking on the Statutory Review of the System for Regulating Rates and Classes for Market Dominant Products, Order No. 3673, Docket No. RM2017-3 (Dec. 20, 2016) at 5. This is the proceeding in which I filed declarations for the PRC Public Representative on adjusting prices when demand declines, mentioned in the above disclaimer. Prof. John Kwoka of Northeastern University filed declarations for the PRC Public Representative that discussed service quality.

  7. 7.

    Postal Regulatory Commission, Order on the Findings and Determination of the 39 U.S.C. § 3622 Review, Order No. 4257, Docket No. RM2017-3 (Dec. 1, 2017) at 250.

  8. 8.

    Id.

  9. 9.

    Postal Regulatory Commission, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking for the System for Regulating Rates and Classes for Market Dominant Services, Order No. 4258, Docket No. RM2017-3 (Dec. 1, 2017) at 53-56. The PRC did not say how it would ascertain “adherence”.

  10. 10.

    This model presumes that each PCR service has only one quality level. There may be a menu of PCR services each with a different quality level, e.g., first-class mail and second-class or standard mail.

  11. 11.

    Fixed costs, having no effect on decisions, are ignored to simplify the notation. Assume fixed costs are large enough to generate significant natural monopoly conditions to warrant monopoly regulation, but not so high to make provision under PCR unprofitable. A potentially more restrictive assumption is that fixed costs are independent of quality, but I assume that to minimize notation and do not think it materially affects the results.

  12. 12.

    Calculating optimal levels of quality neglects receiver welfare, other than to the extent it would be captured by the sender who pays the postage. I also do not discuss changes in optimal quality over time as demand changes because of the overall economy or continuing diversion to Internet-based communication. For more on this, see Okholm, Basalisco, Boivie, and Gårdebrink (2018).

  13. 13.

    This is not an optimum for quality either globally or subject to a profit or revenue constraint, but optimally only given a price that is set by a regulator.

  14. 14.

    In the simplified models above, this would entail knowing h(q) (=c x) and h′(q)x (=c q).

  15. 15.

    These costs would include time-varying costs, e.g., weather effects on meeting delivery speed targets.

  16. 16.

    “[T[he return to the equity owner should be commensurate with returns on investments in other enterprises having corresponding risks. That return, moreover, should be sufficient to assure confidence in the financial integrity of the enterprise, so as to maintain its credit and to attract capital.” FPC v. Hope Nat. Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 603 (1944).

  17. 17.

    The US approach to postal service quality has this flavor, where USPS proposes standards subject to PRC approval, and with USPS getting a small reward in terms of a higher price if it meets those standards—or, conversely, a penalty for failing to meet those standards. See n. 8 and 9 supra and accompanying text. Ovaere (2017) provides a theoretical examination of such mechanisms.

  18. 18.

    The PRC’s reward of 0.25% of revenues on USPS for meeting its quality standard seems unlikely to equal the consumer surplus at stake. If the negotiated quality level is reasonably close to optimal and if this small penalty succeeds in getting USPS to reach that level, however, the PRC’s policy may be reasonable.

References

  • Brennan, T. (1989). Regulating by ‘capping’ prices. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 1(2), 133–147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, T., & Crew, M. (2014). Gross substitutes vs. marginal substitutes: Implications for market definition in the postal sector. In M. Crew & T. Brennan (Eds.), The role of the postal and delivery sector in a digital age (pp. 1–15). Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brennan, T., & Crew, M. (2016). Price cap regulation and declining demand. In M. Crew & T. Brennan (Eds.), The future of the postal sector in a digital world (pp. 1–17). New York, NY: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Littlechild, S. (1983). Regulation of British telecommunications’ profitability. London, UK: Department of Trade and Industry.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loeb, M., & Magat, W. (1979). A decentralized method for utility regulation. Journal of Law and Economics, 22(2), 399–404.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mankiw, N. G., & Whinston, M. (1986). Free entry and social inefficiency. RAND Journal of Economics, 17(1), 48–58.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okholm, H., Basalisco, B., Boivie, A. M., & Gårdebrink, J. (2018). Challenges of regulating quality of service in the postal industry. In P. L. Parcu, T. Brennan, & V. Glass (Eds.), New business and regulatory strategies in the postal sector. New York, NY: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ovaere, M. (2017). Cost-efficiency and quality regulation of a public utility (Discussion paper series DPS17.21). Leuven, Belgium: KU Leuven, Department of Economics.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pearsall, E. S. (2018). Adjusting rates for quality of service: Have market-dominant mail rates risen faster than the CPI-U? In P. L. Parcu, T. Brennan, & V. Glass (Eds.), The contribution of the postal and delivery sector: Between e-commerce and e-substitution (pp. 271–285). New York, NY: Springer.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Sappington, D. (2005). Regulating service quality: A survey. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 27(2), 123–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sappington, D., & Sibley, D. (1988). Regulating without cost information: The incremental surplus subsidy scheme. International Economic Review, 29(2), 297–306.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spence, A. M. (1975). Monopoly, quality, and regulation. Bell Journal of Economics, 6(2), 417–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weisman, D. L. (2005). Price regulation and quality. Information Economics and Policy, 17(2), 165–174.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Timothy J. Brennan .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Brennan, T.J. (2018). Inducing Optimal Quality Under Price Caps: Why, How, and Whether. In: Parcu, P., Brennan, T., Glass, V. (eds) New Business and Regulatory Strategies in the Postal Sector. Topics in Regulatory Economics and Policy. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-02937-1_2

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics